When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 CHAPTER.
Advertisements

8 CHAPTER Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley CHAPTER 1. © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You buy your music online and play it on an iPod. As the prices of a music download and an iPod have tumbled, the volume.
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
© 2013 Pearson. How much would you pay for a song?
CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES
14 Perfect Competition CHAPTER Notes and teaching tips: 4, 7, 8, 9, 25, 26, 27, and 28. To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand”
Budget Constraint –Budget constraints limit an individual’s ability to consume in light of the prices they must pay for various goods and services. The.
11 PART 4 Consumer Choice and Demand A CLOSER LOOK AT DECISION MAKERS
UTILITY AND DEMAND 7 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Describe preferences using the concept of utility and distinguish.
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
9 POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES © 2012 Pearson Education.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
CHAPTER 3 Utility Theory.
7 UTILITY AND DEMAND CHAPTER.
7 CHAPTER Utility and Demand
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You want Coldplay’s latest hit album, Viva la Vida, and you want the Justin Timberlake and Madonna single, Four Minutes.
Chapter 7: Consumer choice
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND. 8 UTILITY AND DEMAND Notes and teaching tips: 6, 12, 26, 27, 28, 29, 37, and 58. To view a full-screen figure during a class,
8 Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.1 Chapter 7: The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Prepared by: Kevin.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: How consumers choose to spend their income on goods and services Why consumers.
CHAPTERS 8 Utility and Demand
Utility and Demand Michael Parkin ECONOMICS 5e. TM 8-2 Copyright © 1998 Addison Wesley Longman, Inc. Learning Objectives Explain the household’s budget.
POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES 8 CHAPTER.
Utility and Demand CHAPTER 7. 2 After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain what limits a household’s consumption choices Describe preferences.
13 PART 5 Perfect Competition
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Chapter 8.
The Theory of Consumer Choice
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 8: Households’ Choices.
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
© 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley. Preferences A household’s preferences determine the benefits or satisfaction a person receives consuming a good or service.
The Theory of Demand Lecture 7: The Theory of Demand Readings: Chapter 9.
The Rational Consumer. The income and substitution effects have been sacrificed… Their definitions are straight forward and in your book.
n Individual’s demand curve: Why does it slopes downward? Why does it slopes downward? n Why do people demand goods and services? Receive satisfaction.
Objectives:  Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services.  Use the concept of utility to explain how the law.
Chapter 21: Consumer Choice
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 10 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain a perfectly.
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization 19 C H A P T E R.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Utility and Demand PART 3Households’ Choices 8 CHAPTER.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 10-1 CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all rights.
What does the economic term “Utility” mean? Utility means “satisfaction.”
CHAPTER 10 The Rational Consumer.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
Utility- is the satisfaction you receive from consuming a good or service Total utility is the number of units of utility that a consumer gains from consuming.
Chapter Five The Demand Curve and the Behavior of Consumers.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain a perfectly.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
S PP 2 T OPIC 1 I SSUE 2: C HANGE IN PRICES AFFECT CONSUMER ’ S CHOICES T HE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE Xiaozhen Chen Hai Tran.
Farid Abolhassani A Simple Model of Demand 3. Learning Objectives After working through this chapter, you will be able to: Define the term ‘quantity demanded’
8 Utility and Demand After studying this chapter you will be able to  Explain the limits to consumption and describe preferences using the concept of.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Possibilities, Preferences and Choice ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Chapter 9: Going from Possibilities (Budget Constraint) and Preferences (Preference Function) to understanding Price and Income Effects.
8 UTILITY AND DEMAND. © 2012 Pearson Education © 2010 Pearson Education The choices you make as a buyer of goods and services is influenced by many factors,
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to Calculate and graph a budget line that shows.
A2 Economics Mr. Durham
Maximizing Utility Preferences
DEV 501: THE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE
Presentation transcript:

When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the limits to a person’s consumption possibilities. 1 Explain the marginal utility theory and use it to derive a consumer’s demand curve. 2 Use marginal productivity theory to explain the paradox of value: Why water is vital but cheap while diamonds are relatively useless and expensive. 3

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES  The Budget Line A budget line describes the limits to consumption choices and depends on a consumer’s budget and the prices of goods and services.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES Figure 11.1 shows consumption possibilities. The figure graphs Tina’s budget line. Points A through E on the graph represent the rows of the table.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES The budget line separates combinations that are affordable from combinations that are unaffordable.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES  Changes in Prices If the price of one good rises when the prices of other goods and the budget remain the same, consumption possibilities shrink. If the price of one good falls when the prices of other goods and the budget remain the same, consumption possibilities expand.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES On the initial budget line, the price of water is $1 a bottle (and gum is 50 cents a pack), as before. Figure 11.2 shows the effect of a fall in the price of water.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES When the price of water falls from $1 a bottle to 50¢ a bottle, the budget line rotates outward and becomes less steep.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES Figure 11.3 shows the effect of a rise in the price of water. Again, on the initial budget line, the price of water is $1 a bottle (and gum is 50 cents a pack), as before.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES When the price of water rises from $1 a bottle to $2 a bottle, the budget line rotates inward and becomes steeper.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES  Prices and the Slope of the Budget Line You’ve just seen that when the price of one good changes and the price of the other good remains the same, the slope of the budget line changes. In Figure 11.2, when the price of water falls, the budget line becomes less steep. In Figure 11.3, when the price of water rises, the budget line becomes steeper. Recall that slope equals rise over run.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES Let’s calculate the slope of the initial budget line. When the price of water is $1 a bottle, the slope of the budget line is 8 packs of gum divided by 4 bottles of water, which equals 2 packs of gum per bottle.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES When the price of water is 50 cents a bottle, the slope of the budget line is 8 packs of gum divided by 8 bottles of water, which equals 1 pack of gum per bottle. Next, calculate the slope of the budget line when water costs 50 cents a bottle.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES When the price of water is $2, a bottle, the slope of the budget line is 8 packs of gum divided by 2 bottles of water, which equals 4 packs of gum per bottle. Finally, calculate the slope of the budget line when water costs $2 a bottle.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES You can think of the slope of the budget line as an opportunity cost. The slope tells us how many packs of gum a bottle of water costs. Another name for opportunity cost is relative price, which is the price of one good in terms of another good. A relative price equals the price of one good divided by the price of another good, and equals the slope of the budget line.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES  A Change in the Budget When a consumer’s budget increases, consumption possibilities expand. When a consumer’s budget decreases, consumption possibilities shrink.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES An decrease in the budget shifts the budget line leftward. Figure 11.4 shows the effects of changes in a consumer’s budget. The slope of the budget line doesn’t change because prices have not changed.

11.1 CONSUMPTION POSSIBILITIES An increase in the budget shifts the budget line rightward. Again, the slope of the budget line doesn’t change because prices have not changed.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY  Utility Utility is the benefit or satisfaction that a person gets from the consumption of a good or service. Temperature: An Analogy The concept of utility helps us make predictions about consumption choices in much the same way that the concept of temperature helps us make predictions about physical phenomena.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY  Total Utility Total utility is the total benefit that a person gets from the consumption of a good or service. Total utility generally increases as the quantity consumed of a good increases. Table 11.1 shows an example of total utility from bottled water and chewing gum.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY

 Marginal Utility Marginal utility is the change in total utility that results from a one-unit increase in the quantity of a good consumed. To calculate marginal utility, we use the total utility numbers in Table 11.1.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY

The marginal utility of the 3rd bottle of water = 36 units – 27 units = 9 units.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY The marginal utility of the 3rd bottle of water = 36 units – 27 units = 9 units.

Diminishing marginal utility We call the general tendency for marginal utility to decrease as the quantity of a good consumed increases the principle of diminishing marginal utility. Think about your own marginal utility from the things that you consume. The numbers in Table 11.1 display diminishing marginal utility MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY

Part (a) graphs Tina’s total utility from bottled water. Figure 11.5 shows total utility and marginal utility MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Each bar shows the extra total utility she gains from each additional bottle of water—her marginal utility. The blue line is Tina’s total utility curve.

Part (b) shows how Tina’s marginal utility from bottled water diminishes by placing the bars shown in part (a) side by side as a series of declining steps. The downward sloping blue line is Tina’s marginal utility curve MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY

 Maximizing Total Utility The goal of a consumer is to allocate the available budget in a way that maximizes total utility. The consumer achieves this goal by choosing the point on the budget line at which the sum of the utilities obtained from all goods is as large as possible.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY This outcome occurs when a person follows the utility- maximizing rule : 1. Allocate the entire available budget. 2. Make the marginal utility per dollar spent the same for all goods.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Allocate the Available Budget The available budget is the amount available after choosing how much to save and how much to spend on other items. The saving decision and all other spending decisions are based on the same utility maximizing rule that you are learning here and applying to Tina’s decision about how to allocate a given budget to water and gum.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Equalize the Marginal Utility Per Dollar Spent Spending the entire available budget doesn’t automatically maximize utility. Dollars might be misallocated—spend in ways that don’t maximize utility. Making the marginal utility per dollar spent the same for all goods gets the most out of a budget.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Step 1: Make a table that shows the quantities of the two goods that just use all the budget.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Step 2: Calculate the marginal utility per dollar spent on the two goods. Marginal utility per dollar spent The increase in total utility that comes from the last dollar spent on a good.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Step 3: Make a table that shows the marginal utility per dollar spent on the two goods for each affordable combination.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Row C maximizes utility. The marginal utility per dollar spent is equal for the two goods.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY Units of Utility In calculating Tina’s utility-maximizing choice in Table 11.3, we have not used the concept of total utility. All our calculations use marginal utility and price. Changing the units of utility doesn’t affect our prediction about the consumption choice that maximizes total utility.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY  Finding the Demand Curve We can use marginal utility theory to find a consumer’s demand curve. Figure 11.6 shows Tina’s demand curve for bottled water.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY When the price of water is $1 a bottle, Tina buys 2 bottles of water a day. She is at point A on her demand curve for water. When the price of water falls to 50¢, Tina buys 4 bottles of water a day and moves to point B on her demand curve for bottled water.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY  Marginal Utility and the Elasticity of Demand If, as the quantity consumed of a good increases, marginal utility decreases quickly, the demand for the good is inelastic. The reason is that for a given change in the price, only a small change in the quantity consumed of the good is needed to bring its marginal utility per dollar spent back to equality with that on all the other items in the consumer’s budget.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY But if, as the quantity consumed of a good increases, marginal utility decreases slowly, the demand for that good is elastic. In this case, for a given change in the price, a large change in the quantity consumed of the good is needed to bring its marginal utility per dollar spent back to equality with that on all the other items in the consumer’s budget.

11.2 MARGINAL UTILITY THEORY  The Power of Marginal Analysis The rule to follow is simple: If the marginal utility per dollar spent on water exceeds the marginal utility per dollar spent on gum, buy more water and less gum. If the marginal utility per dollar spent on gum exceeds the marginal utility per dollar spent on water, buy more gum and less water. More generally, if the marginal gain from an action exceeds the marginal loss, take the action.

11.3 EFFICIENCY, PRICE, AND VALUE  Consumer Efficiency When a consumer maximizes utility, the consumer is using her or his resources efficiently. Using what you’ve learned, you can now give the concept of marginal benefit a deeper meaning. Marginal benefit is the maximum price a consumer is willing to pay for an extra unit of a good or service when total utility is maximized.

11.3 EFFICIENCY, PRICE, AND VALUE  The Paradox of Value For centuries, philosophers have been puzzled by the fact that water is vital for life but cheap while diamonds are used only for decoration yet are very expensive. You can solve this puzzle by distinguishing between total utility and marginal utility. Total utility tells us about relative value; marginal utility tells us about relative price.

When the high marginal utility of diamonds is divided by the high price of a diamond, the result is a number that equals the low marginal utility of water divided by the low price of water. The marginal utility per dollar spent is the same for diamonds as for water. Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus measures value in excess of the amount paid EFFICIENCY, PRICE, AND VALUE

Figure 11.7 shows the paradox of value. The demand curve D shows the demand for water. The demand curve and the supply curve S determine the price of water at P W and the quantity at Q W. The consumer surplus from water is the large green triangle EFFICIENCY, PRICE, AND VALUE

In this figure, the demand curve D is the demand for diamonds. The demand curve and the supply curve S determine the price of a diamond at P D and the quantity at Q D. The consumer surplus from diamonds is the small green triangle EFFICIENCY, PRICE, AND VALUE

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES  An Indifference Curve An indifference curve is a line that shows combinations of goods among which a consumer is indifferent.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Figure A11.1 shows an indifference curve and map.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES In part (a), Tina is equally happy consuming at any point along the green indifference curve.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Point C is neither better nor worse than any other point along the indifference curve.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Points below the indifference curve are worse than points on the indifference curve—are not preferred.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Points above the indifference curve are better than points on the indifference curve—are preferred.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Part (b) shows three indifference curves—I 0, I 1, and I 2 —that are part of Tina’s indifference map.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES The indifference curve in part (a) is curve I 1 in part (b). Tina is indifferent between points C and G.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Tina prefers point J to points C and G. And she prefers C and G to any point on curve I 0.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES  Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which a person will give up good y (the good measured on the y-axis) to get more of good x (the good measured on the x-axis) and at the same time remain on the same indifference curve. Diminishing marginal rate of substitution is the general tendency for the marginal rate of substitution to decrease as the consumer moves down along the indifference curve, increasing consumption of good x and decreasing consumption of good y.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Figure A11.2 shows the calculation of the marginal rate of substitution. The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the magnitude of the slope of an indifference curve. First, we’ll calculate the MRS at point C.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Draw a straight line with the same slope as the indifference curve at point C. The slope of this line is 8 packs of gum divided by 4 bottles of water, which equals 2 packs of gum per bottle of water.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES This number is Tina’s marginal rate of substitution. Her MRS = 2. At point C, when she consumes 2 bottles of water and 4 packs of gum, Tina is willing to give up gum for water at the rate of 2 packs of gum per bottle of water.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES The red line at point G tells us that Tina is willing to give up 4 packs of gum to get 8 bottles of water. Her marginal rate of substitution at point G is 4 divided by 8, which equals 1 ⁄2. Now calculate Tina’s MRS at point G.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES  Consumer Equilibrium The goal of the consumer is to buy the affordable quantities of goods that make the consumer as well off as possible. The consumer’s preference map describe the way a consumer values different combinations of goods. The consumer’s budget and the prices of the goods limit the consumer’s choices.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Figure A11.3 shows consumer equilibrium. Tina’s indifference curves describe her preferences. Tina’s budget line describes the limits to what she can afford. Tina’s best affordable point is C. At that point, she is on her budget line and also on the highest attainable indifference curve.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES Tina can consume the same quantity of water at point J but less gum. She prefers C to J. Point J is equally preferred to points F and H, which Tina can also afford. Points on the budget line between F and H are preferred to F and H. And of all those points, C is the best affordable point for Tina.

APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES  Deriving the Demand Curve To derive Tina’s demand curve for bottled water: Change the price of water Shift the budget line Work out the new best affordable point

Figure A11.4 shows how to derive Tina’s demand curve. When the price of water is $1 a bottle, Tina’s best affordable point is C in part (a) and at point A on her demand curve in part (b). When the price of water is 50 cents a bottle, Tina’s best affordable point is K in part (a) and at point B on her demand curve in part (b). APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Tina’s demand curve in part (b) passes through points A and B. APPENDIX: INDIFFERENCE CURVES