Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byMark Jefferson Modified over 9 years ago
1
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Chapter 8
2
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 2 Utility Theory and Individual Choice u Economists have an answer to the question of why people behave as they do — self interest. l Economists' analysis of individual choice does not deny individual differences.
3
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 3 Utility Theory and Individual Choice u Using the simple concept of self- interest, two things determine what people do: l The pleasure people get from doing or consuming something. l The price of doing or consuming that something.
4
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 4 Utility Theory and Individual Choice u Price is the market's tool to bring quantity supplied equal to the quantity demanded. u Changes in price provide incentives for people to change what they are doing.
5
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 5 Measuring Pleasure u Economists start with a proposition that individuals try to get as much pleasure as possible out of life. u The goods and services we consume provide value (satisfaction) to us.
6
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 6 Measuring Pleasure u Individuals want to maximize the amount of satisfaction they receive through consuming goods and services.
7
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 7 Measuring Pleasure u Economists use the concept of utility— the pleasure or satisfaction that one gets from consuming a good or service. u A util is a unit created by economists to “measure” utility.
8
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 8 Utility u Utility serves as the basis of economists' analysis of individual choice. u It is personal and individual. u Utility cannot be compared across individuals.
9
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 9 Total Utility u Total utility refers to the total satisfaction one gets from consuming a product.
10
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 10 Marginal Utility u Marginal utility refers to the satisfaction one gets from the consumption of one additional unit of a product above and beyond what on has consumed up to that point.
11
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 11 Total Utility and Marginal Utility u As additional units are consumed, marginal utility decreases while total utility increases. u When marginal utility is zero, total utility stops increasing. u Beyond this point, marginal utility is negative and total utility decreases.
12
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 12 Number of pizza slices 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Total utility 14 26 36 44 50 54 56 54 Marginal utility 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 Marginal and Total Utility, Fig. 8-1a, p 180
13
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 13 Total utilityMarginal utility Slices of pizza per hour 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 123456789 Slices of pizza per hour 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 123456789 Marginal and Total Utility, Fig. 8-1b and c, p 180 Total utility Marginal utility Utils
14
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 14 Diminishing Marginal Utility u The principle of diminishing marginal utility states that, at some point, the marginal utility received from each additional unit of a good begins to decrease with each additional unit consumed.
15
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 15 Diminishing Marginal Utility u This principle does not say you do not enjoy consuming more of a good. u It only states that as you consume more of the good, you enjoy additional units less than you enjoyed the initial units.
16
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 16 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u The analysis of rational choice begins with the premise that rational individuals want as much satisfaction as they can get from their available income. u Rational means that people prefer more to less and will make choices that give them as much satisfaction as possible.
17
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 17 Rational Choices u In making choices, essentially what you are doing is buying units of utility. u Any choice (for the same amount of money) that does not give you as many units of utility as possible is an irrational choice.
18
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 18 Rational choices u Since you want to get the most for your money, you make those choices that have the highest units of utility per dollar spent.
19
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 19 Maximizing Utility u Total utility is maximized when marginal utility per dollar spent of two goods is equal.
20
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 20 Maximizing Utility u If: u Choose to consume an additional unit of good x.
21
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 21 Maximizing Utility u If: u Choose to consume an additional unit of good y.
22
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 22 Maximizing Utility u By substituting the marginal utilities and prices of goods into these formulas, you can always decide which good it makes more sense to consume. u Consume the one with the highest marginal utility per dollar.
23
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 23 Maximizing Utility and Equilibrium u When the ratios of the marginal utility to price of goods are equal, you are maximizing utility.
24
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 24 Maximizing Utility u If: u You’re in equilibrium. u You cannot increase your utility by adjusting your choices.
25
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 25 Maximizing Utility, Table 8-1, p 182 Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 TU 0 20 32 38 41 36 26 MU 20 12 6 3 0 -5 -10 MU/P 10 6 3 1.5 0 -2.5 -5 Q 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 TU 0 29 46 53 56 57 53 MU 29 17 7 3 1 0 -4 MU/P 29 17 7 3 1 0 -4 Hamburgers (P = $2)Ice Cream (P = $1)
26
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 26 Maximizing Utility, Table 8-2, p 183 Total $ spent Purchase?MU/PMU $11 ice cream cone29 $22 nd ice cream cone17 $41 hamburger1020 $53 rd ice cream cone77 $72 nd hamburger612 $93 rd hamburger36 $104 th ice cream cone33 Total utility = 94 utils
27
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 27 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u The same principle applies if more than two goods are consumed: u If MUx/Px > MUz/Pz, consume more of good x. u If MUy/Py > MUz/Pz, consume more of good y.
28
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 28 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u The general utility-maximizing rule is that you are maximizing utility when the marginal utilities per dollar are equal across all goods you consume.
29
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 29 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u When you are maximizing utility.
30
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 30 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u When this principle is met, the consumer is in equilibrium. u The cost per additional unit of utility is equal for all goods and the consumer is as well off as it is possible to be.
31
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 31 Rational Choice and Marginal Utility u The rule does not say that the rational consumer should consume a good until its marginal utility reaches zero. u Consumers do not have enough money to reach this point, as they face an income constraint.
32
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 32 Opportunity Cost u Opportunity cost is the benefit forgone of the next-best alternative. l It is essentially the marginal utility per dollar you forgo. u To say MUx/Px > MUy/Py is to say that the opportunity cost of not consuming good x is greater than the opportunity cost of not consuming good y. u So we consume x.
33
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 33 Opportunity Cost u When all the marginal utilities per dollar spent are equal, the opportunity cost of all the alternatives are equal.
34
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 34 Rational Choice and the Laws of Demand u The principle of rational choice leads to the law of demand. l When the price of a good goes up, the marginal utility per dollar from that good goes down and we demand less of it.
35
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 35 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u Initially MUx/Px = MUy/Py u When the price of good y goes up, then MUx/Px > MUy/Py. u Our condition for maximizing utility is no longer satisfied. u So when the price of a good goes up, we would choose to consume less of that good.
36
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 36 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u Our utility maximizing rule is no longer satisfied u We should now buy more of good x
37
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 37 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u MUx decreases as we buy more x (diminishing marginal utility) and u MUy increases as we buy less of the good y u We are back at a point where MUx/Px = MUy/Py and we maximize utility (but we now consume less x and more y than before the price increase).
38
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 38 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u Quantity demanded rises as price falls, other things constant. u Quantity demanded falls as price rises, other things constant.
39
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 39 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u The above shows the relationship between marginal utility and the price we are willing to pay.
40
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 40 Rational Choice and the Law of Demand u Since our demand for a good is an expression of our willingness to pay for it, quantity demanded is related to marginal utility.
41
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 41 Maximizing Utility Using Indifference Curves u Economists often use graphic representation of the consumer’s choice. u The problem consists of two parts: l The budget constraint (or the income constraint) and l Indifference curves, which represent utility
42
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 42 Graphing the Budget Line u The budget constraint represents all the combinations of two goods that a person can afford to buy with given income. u The budget constraint is also called the income constraint, or budget line.
43
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 43 Jaz’s Budget Line u Jaz has $10 and buys chocolate and pop whose prices are $1 and $0.50 respectively.
44
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 44 Graphing the Budget Line, Fig. 8-2, p 187 0 2 4 6 8 10 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 Chocolate bars Cans of pop Slope= - P pop /P chocolate = - ½ Income = $10
45
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 45 The Indifference Curve u An indifference curve represents all the combinations of the two goods amongst which an individual is indifferent.
46
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 46 The Indifference Curve u Jaz is equally as well off (her utility is the same) from consuming bundles A, B, C, D or E.
47
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 47 Jaz’s Indifference Curve, Fig. 8-3a, p 188 0 4 8 12 16 20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 Chocolate bars Cans of pop |Slope|= MU pop /MU chocolate bars = MRS of pop for chocolate bars U A B C D E Indifference curve
48
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 48 The Indifference Curve u The slope of the indifference curve is called the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) u The slope is bowed inward, indicating that MRS is decreasing as Jaz’s bundles contain more of the good on the horizontal axis.
49
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 49 The Indifference Curve u The reason for decreasing MRS is that as Jaz gets more and more of one good, she is willing to give up lots of it to get more of the relatively scarce good. |Slope| = MU pop /Mu chocolate = MRS
50
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 50 A Map of Indifference Curves u The bundles of goods forming indifference curve U 3 give Jaz higher utility than bundles along U 2, u While the bundles of goods forming indifference curve U 1 give Jaz less utility than bundles along U 2.
51
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 51 A Map of Indifference Curves, Fig. 8-3b, p 188 0 4 8 12 16 20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 Chocolate bars Cans of pop U2U2 A B C D E U1U1 U3U3
52
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 52 Combining Indifference Curves and Budget Line u The goal for a consumer is to get as high on an indifference curve as possible, given her income constraint. u More is preferred to less.
53
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 53 Combining Indifference Curves and Budget Line, Fig. 8-4, p 189 0 4 8 12 16 20 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 Chocolate bars Cans of pop U2U2 U1U1 U3U3 Slope= -MU pop /Mu chocolate bars Slope= -P pop /P chocolate bars D C G K
54
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 54 Combining Indifference Curves and Budget Line u At the point D, Jaz maximizes her utility when: MU pop /Mu chocolate bars = P pop /P chocolate bars
55
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. 8 - 55 Combining Indifference Curves and Budget Line u In other words, utility is maximized when the slopes of the budget constraint and the indifference curve are equal.
56
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand End of Chapter 8
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com Inc.
All rights reserved.