Consumer Welfare and Elasticities

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
1 A B C
Advertisements

The Instruments of Trade Policy
AP STUDY SESSION 2.
1
Chapter 6 Elasticity and Demand.
Chapter 3 Demand and Behavior in Markets. Copyright © 2001 Addison Wesley LongmanSlide 3- 2 Figure 3.1 Optimal Consumption Bundle.
Copyright © 2003 Pearson Education, Inc. Slide 1 Computer Systems Organization & Architecture Chapters 8-12 John D. Carpinelli.
Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand
Cost Behavior, Operating Leverage, and Profitability Analysis
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
David Burdett May 11, 2004 Package Binding for WS CDL.
CALENDAR.
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Price Levels and the Exchange Rate in the Long Run
Break Time Remaining 10:00.
Turing Machines.
Table 12.1: Cash Flows to a Cash and Carry Trading Strategy.
Copyright © 2001 by Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights reserved. 1 Economics THIRD EDITION By John B. Taylor Stanford University.
Demand, Supply, and Markets 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for.
PP Test Review Sections 6-1 to 6-6
Chapter 6 Tariffs. Copyright © 2007 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 6-2 Topics to be Covered Types of Commercial Policies Tariffs and Types.
An Introduction to International Economics
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 9 The Instruments of Trade Policy.
Cost-Volume-Profit Relationships
MCQ Chapter 07.
1 of 59 PART III The Core of Macroeconomic Theory © 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall CHAPTER OUTLINE 11 Aggregate Demand in the.
Outline Minimum Spanning Tree Maximal Flow Algorithm LP formulation 1.
CHAPTER 27 Aggregate Demand in the Goods and Money Markets © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case,
1 The Utility-Maximizing Model Module 11. Use the utility-maximizing model to explain how consumers choose goods and services. 2 ObjectivesObjectives.
Copyright © 2012, Elsevier Inc. All rights Reserved. 1 Chapter 7 Modeling Structure with Blocks.
Chapter 1: Expressions, Equations, & Inequalities
Adding Up In Chunks.
MaK_Full ahead loaded 1 Alarm Page Directory (F11)
DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
1 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt 10 pt 15 pt 20 pt 25 pt 5 pt Synthetic.
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
: 3 00.
5 minutes.
Consumer’s and Producer’s Surpluses
1 hi at no doifpi me be go we of at be do go hi if me no of pi we Inorder Traversal Inorder traversal. n Visit the left subtree. n Visit the node. n Visit.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 A Monetary Intertemporal Model: Money, Prices, and Monetary Policy.
1 Chapter 11 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Converting a Fraction to %
Clock will move after 1 minute
A Real Intertemporal Model with Investment
Physics for Scientists & Engineers, 3rd Edition
Select a time to count down from the clock above
1 © ©1999 South-Western College Publishing PowerPoint Slides prepared by Ken Long Principles of Economics 2nd edition by Fred M Gottheil.
Copyright Tim Morris/St Stephen's School
9. Two Functions of Two Random Variables
Individual and Market Demand
3 - 1 Copyright McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2005 Markets Demand Defined Demand Graphed Changes in Demand Supply Defined Supply Graphed Changes in Supply Equilibrium.
Chapter 4 FUGACITY.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Elasticity and Consumer Surplus
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Five Consumer Welfare and Policy Analysis.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Chapter 7 MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
1 Sir Naseer Shahzada INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
Consumer Welfare 1. 2 One way to evaluate the welfare cost of a price increase (from p x 0 to p x 1 ) would be to compare the expenditures required to.
Income and Substitution Effects
MARKET DEMAND AND ELASTICITY
Presentation transcript:

Consumer Welfare and Elasticities Chapter 5 Consumer Welfare and Elasticities Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Consumer Welfare An important problem in welfare economics is to devise a monetary measure of the gains and losses that individuals experience when prices change This is important for economic policy because economic policy usually changes prices due to either taxes or subsidies Usually, we would like to design policies that maximize consumer welfare, so we need to measure it

Consumer Welfare One way to evaluate the welfare cost of a price increase (from px0 to px1) would be to compare the expenditures required to achieve U0 (initial level of utility) under these two situations expenditure at px0 = E0 = E(px0,py,U0) expenditure at px1 = E1 = E(px1,py,U0)

Consumer Welfare In order to compensate for the price rise, this person would require a compensating variation (CV) of V(px0,py,I)= V(px1,py,I+CV), U0= V(px1,py,I+CV) Solving for CV… CV +I= E(px1,py,U0), CV= E(px1,py,U0) – I, CV= E(px1,py,U0) – E(p0x,py,U0) The CV is how much money we would have to give the consumer after the price change to make him just as well off as he was before the price change

Consumer Welfare Suppose the consumer is maximizing utility at point A. Quantity of y U1 B If the price of good x rises, the consumer will maximize utility at point B. A The consumer’s utility falls from U0 to U1 U0 Quantity of x

Consumer Welfare The consumer could be compensated so that he can afford to remain on U0 C Quantity of y CV is the amount that the individual would need to be compensated A B U0 U1 I/p1x Quantity of x (I+CV)/p1x I/p0x

This was trick A in the previous set of slides! Consumer Welfare The derivative of the expenditure function with respect to px is the compensated demand function This was trick A in the previous set of slides!

Consumer Welfare The amount of CV required can be found by integrating across a sequence of small increments to price from px0 to px1 this integral is the area to the left of the compensated demand curve between px0 and px1

Compensating Variation px When the price rises from px0 to px1, the consumer suffers a loss in welfare welfare loss px1 x1 px0 x0 xc(px…U0) Quantity of x

Another way to measure changes in consumer welfare The CV is how much money we would have to give the consumer after the price change to make him just as well off as he was before the price changed. The reference of the CV is the initial level of utility An alternative measure of the change in consumer welfare is the Equivalent Variation (EV) The Equivalent Variation is how much money would have to be taken away from the consumer before the price changed to leave him as well off as he would be after the price change. The reference of the EV is the final level of utility In another words: the EV is the amount of money that the consumer will be willing to pay to avoid the price change the CV is the amount of money that the consumer will require to accept the price change

Example CV and EV CV: compensate individuals for an increase in the price of air travel due to a green tax EV: The government promised to lower the VAT in their political manifesto to win the elections. After they are elected, they realise that EU does not allow them. The government uses the EV to compensate individuals for that.

V(px0,py,I-EV)= V(px1,py,I), Equivalent Variation To avoid the change of prices, the individual will be willing to pay the EV: V(px0,py,I-EV)= V(px1,py,I), V(px0,py,I-EV)= U1 Solving for EV… I-EV= E(p0x,py,U1), EV= I-E(p0x,py,U1), EV= E(px1,py,U1) – E(p0x,py,U1)

Consumer Welfare As in the case of the CV, the EV required can be found by integrating across the compensated demand curve from px0 to px1 this integral is the area to the left of the compensated demand curve between px0 and px1, at the final level of utility

Consumer Welfare It is unclear which one should be used: CV or EV They are different: notice, areas of different compensated demand curves (according to the level of utility: initial or final) Do we use the compensated demand curve for the original target utility (U0) (that is, the CV) or the new level of utility after the price change (U1) (that is, the EV)?

The Consumer Surplus Concept Another way to look at this issue is to ask how much the person would be willing to pay for the right to consume all of this good that he wanted at the market price of px0

The Consumer Surplus Concept The area below the Marshallian demand curve and above the market price is called consumer surplus the extra benefit the person receives by being able to make market transactions at the prevailing market price changes in consumer surplus measure the welfare effects of price changes

Consumer Welfare px When the price rises from px0 to px1, the actual market reaction will be to move from A to C The consumer’s utility falls from U0 to U1 C px1 A px0 x(px…) xc(...U0) xc(...U1) x1 x0 Quantity of x

Consumer Surplus px Is the consumer’s loss in welfare best described by area px1BApx0 [using xc(...U0)] or by area px1CDpx0 [using xc(...U1)]? C B px1 Is U0 or U1 the appropriate utility target? A px0 D xc(...U0) xc(...U1) x1 x0 Quantity of x

Consumer Surplus The change is CS will be between the CS and the EV px The change is CS will be between the CS and the EV The area px1CApx0 falls between the sizes of the welfare losses defined by xc(...U0) and xc(...U1) C x(px…) B px1 A px0 D xc(...U0) xc(...U1) x1 x0 Quantity of x

Consumer Surplus The change is CS will be between the CS and the EV px The change is CS will be between the CS and the EV The area px1CApx0 falls between the sizes of the welfare losses defined by xc(...U0) and xc(...U1) C x(px…) px1 A px0 D xc(...U0) xc(...U1) x1 x0 Quantity of x

Welfare Loss from a Price Increase Suppose that the compensated demand function for x is given by The welfare cost of a price increase from px = 1 to px = 4 is given by

Welfare Loss from a Price Increase If we assume that V = 2 and py = 2, CV = 222(4)0.5 – 222(1)0.5 = 8 If we assume that the utility level (V) falls to 1 after the price increase (and used this level to calculate welfare loss), EV = 122(4)0.5 – 122(1)0.5 = 4

Welfare Loss from Price Increase Suppose that we use the Marshallian demand function instead The welfare loss from a price increase from px = 1 to px = 4 is given by

Welfare Loss from a Price Increase If income (I) is equal to 8, loss = 4 ln(4) - 4 ln(1) = 4 ln(4) = 4(1.39) = 5.55 this computed loss from the Marshallian demand function is a compromise between the two amounts computed using the compensated demand functions

Elasticities

Elasticity – general formula Assume function: H=H(g1,g2,..,gn) Elasticity of H wrt. gi: *eH,gi= how much H changes in %, if gi increases by 1% It is useful because it is unit-free, we do not have to specify the units… a 1% can be easily understood independently that we use £ or $

Marshallian Demand Elasticities Most of the commonly used demand elasticities are derived from the Marshallian demand function x(px,py,I) Price elasticity of demand (ex,px)

Marshallian Demand Elasticities Income elasticity of demand (ex,I) Cross-price elasticity of demand (ex,py)

Iso-elastic demand function Usually used in econometrics Ln(x)=a*ln(px)+b*ln(py)+c*ln(I) Elasticities are: if ex,px =a if ex,py =b if ex,I = c Called iso-elastic because the elasticities are fixed numbers

Price Elasticity of Demand The own price elasticity of demand is always negative the only exception is Giffen’s paradox The size of the elasticity is important if ex,px < -1, demand is elastic if ex,px > -1, demand is inelastic if ex,px = -1, demand is unit elastic

Price Elasticity and Total Spending Total spending on x is equal to total spending =pxx Relation between total spending and changes of the price:

Price Elasticity and Total Spending The sign of this derivative depends on whether ex,px is greater or less than -1 if ex,px > -1, quantity changes less than price in % terms, so total spending and price move in the same direction if ex,px < -1, quantity changes more than price in % terms, so total spending and price move in the same direction

Compensated Price Elasticities It is also useful to define elasticities based on the compensated demand function

Compensated Price Elasticities If the compensated demand function is xc = xc(px,py,U) we can calculate compensated own price elasticity of demand (exc,px) compensated cross-price elasticity of demand (exc,py)

Compensated Price Elasticities The compensated own price elasticity of demand (exc,px) is The compensated cross-price elasticity of demand (exc,py) is

Compensated Price Elasticities The relationship between Marshallian and compensated price elasticities can be shown using the Slutsky equation: If sx = pxx/I, then

Compensated Price Elasticities The Slutsky equation shows that the compensated and uncompensated price elasticities will be similar if the share of income devoted to x is small the income elasticity of x is small So, the different measures of welfare will be very similar if:

Another interesting relation If we increase prices and income by the same percentage, optimal quantities will not change. So: Any proportional change in all prices and income will leave the quantity of x demanded unchanged

Why is the previous relation useful? The previous relation could be used to either: Test the assumptions embedded in econometric models Incorporate restrictions in econometric models to gain efficiency Find out the value of some elasticities when we have information about other elasticities The following expressions can also be used for the same purposes Notice that econometrics is very important in our context… we need numbers to compute the welfare measures !!!

Engel Aggregation The relation between the income elasticity of several goods We can obtain it by differentiating the budget constraint with respect to income:

Engel Aggregation This relation is useful because it might be easier to estimate the elasticities of some goods rather than others…

Cournot Aggregation The relation between own and cross-price effects Useful because we might have information about the elasticity of some goods, but we want to find out about the elasticity of others… We can obtain this relation by differentiating the budget constraint with respect to px

Cournot Aggregation

Demand Elasticities The Cobb-Douglas utility function is U(x,y) = xy (+=1) The demand functions for x and y are

Demand Elasticities Calculating the elasticities, we get

Demand Elasticities We can also show homogeneity Engel aggregation Cournot aggregation

Demand Elasticities We can also use the Slutsky equation to derive the compensated price elasticity The compensated price elasticity depends on how important other goods (y) are in the utility function

Important Points to Note: Proportional changes in all prices and income do not shift the individual’s budget constraint and therefore do not alter the quantities of goods chosen demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero in all prices and income

Important Points to Note: When purchasing power changes (income changes but prices remain the same), budget constraints shift for normal goods, an increase in income means that more is purchased for inferior goods, an increase in income means that less is purchased

Important Points to Note: A fall in the price of a good causes substitution and income effects for a normal good, both effects cause more of the good to be purchased for inferior goods, substitution and income effects work in opposite directions no unambiguous prediction is possible

Important Points to Note: A rise in the price of a good also causes income and substitution effects for normal goods, less will be demanded for inferior goods, the net result is ambiguous

Important Points to Note: The Marshallian demand curve summarizes the total quantity of a good demanded at each possible price changes in price prompt movements along the curve changes in income, prices of other goods, or preferences may cause the demand curve to shift

Important Points to Note: Compensated demand curves illustrate movements along a given indifference curve for alternative prices they are constructed by holding utility constant and exhibit only the substitution effects from a price change their slope is unambiguously negative (or zero)

Important Points to Note: Demand elasticities are often used in empirical work to summarize how individuals react to changes in prices and income the most important is the price elasticity of demand measures the proportionate change in quantity in response to a 1 percent change in price

Important Points to Note: There are many relationships among demand elasticities own-price elasticities determine how a price change affects total spending on a good substitution and income effects can be summarized by the Slutsky equation various aggregation results hold among elasticities

Important Points to Note: Welfare effects of price changes can be measured by changing areas below either compensated or ordinary demand curves such changes affect the size of the consumer surplus that individuals receive by being able to make market transactions

Important Points to Note: The negativity of the substitution effect is one of the most basic findings of demand theory this result can be shown using revealed preference theory and does not necessarily require assuming the existence of a utility function