Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
Advertisements

Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade
Chapter 2: Absolute Advantage
Application: International Trade
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 The Standard Trade Model.
International Trade Models Mercantilism; The Classical Theories: –The Principle of Absolute Advantage –The Principle of Comparative Advantage The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson.
Economic Studies 2th Stage Prepared by Nyaz Najmadin To Accompany International Economics: Theory and Policy International Economics: Theory.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
The Standard Trade Model
3 Gains and Losses from Trade in the Specific-Factors Model 1
1 of 62 Copyright © 2011 Worth Publishers· International Economics· Feenstra/Taylor, 2/e. Chapter 2: Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model Trade and.
Sources of Comparative Advantage
GAINS AND LOSSES FROM TRADE IN THE SPECIFIC-FACTORS MODEL
Application: International Trade
The Classical Model of International Trade
Session 7 International Trade: Comparative Advantage and Trade Barriers Disclaimer: The views expressed are those of the presenters and do not necessarily.
The Standard Trade Model
Foundations of Modern Trade Theory: Comparative Advantage
Trade Theories: #1 - Mercantilism. Defining mercantilism … Mercantilism The theory that a country should accumulate financial wealth by amassing as many.
Classical Theories of International Trade
MORE ON PRODUCTION POSSIBILITIES & SUPPLY/DEMAND INTERNATIONAL TRADE.
Chapter 18: International Trade. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Trade Facts Principal.
Comparative Advantage and Factor Endowments
Basic Economic Concepts for Understanding the Value of Trade
9-1 Copyright © 2012 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. C H A P T E R 9 Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Copyright © 2012 Pearson Prentice.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Comparative Advantage and Factor Endowments.
Trade: Factor Availability and Factor Proportions Are Key
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning Lesson 5 International Aspects – Part 1.
© 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning, all rights reserved C H A P T E R Interdependence and the Gains from Trade E conomics P R I N C I P L.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
#1 What is Production? Production is the process by which resources are transformed into useful forms. Resources, or inputs, refer to anything provided.
The Classical Model of International Trade
The Production Possibility Model, Trade, and Globalization No one ever saw a dog make a fair and deliberate exchange of one bone for another with another.
Introduction: Thinking Like an Economist 1 CHAPTER 2 No one ever saw a dog make a fair and deliberate exchange of one bone for another with another dog.
Chapter 9 International Trade.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 9 Application: International Trade.
Reinert/Windows on the World Economy, 2005 Absolute Advantage CHAPTER 2.
1 Chapter 21 International Trade and Finance ©2004 Thomson/South-Western Key Concepts Key Concepts Summary Summary Practice Quiz.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
Ricardian Model A lesson in Comparative Advantage.
The Standard Trade Model
The Classical World of David Ricardo and Comparative Advantage Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Resources, Comparative Advantage, and Income Distribution.
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Labor Productivity and Comparative Advantage:
International Economics Mordecai E. Kreinin Copyright ©2002 South-Western/Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. Copyright ©2002 South-Western/Thomson.
LECTURE 6: Gains from Trade in Neoclassical Theory
Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved Chapter 3 Lecture - Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
Chapter Seventeen The Gains from International Trade.
Chapter 6 The Theory of Tariffs and Quotas. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 6-2 Chapter Objectives Introduce the theory.
Introduction: Thinking Like an Economist 1 CHAPTER 2 No one ever saw a dog make a fair and deliberate exchange of one bone for another with another dog.
Copyright © 2002 Pearson Education, Inc.Slide 3-1 Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. THE PRODUCTION POSSIBILITY MODEL, TRADE, AND GLOBALIZATION THE.
Why Countries Trade Chapter 1
1 CHAPTER 7 LECTURE - GLOBAL MARKETS IN ACTION. 2  Because we trade with people in other countries, the goods and services that we can buy and consume.
International Economics Tenth Edition
International Economics Eleventh Edition
THE PRODUCTION POSSIBILITY MODEL, TRADE, AND GLOBALIZATION
Chapter 28 International Trade and Finance
International Economics Tenth Edition
Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade
International Economics Twelfth Edition
International Economics Twelfth Edition
Application: International Trade
Choice, Opportunity Costs, and Specialization
International Economics: Theory and Policy, Sixth Edition
Application: International Trade
International Trade and Tariff
International Trade Models
Presentation transcript:

Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade

Learning Objectives Analyze numerical examples of absolute and comparative advantage. Draw a diagram showing gains from trade. Define and state the differences between the concepts of absolute advantage, comparative advantage, and competitiveness. Discuss the economic and ethical considerations of economic restructuring caused by international trade.

Introduction: The Gains from Trade The improvement in national welfare is known as the gains from trade

Adam Smith and the Attack on Economic Nationalism In 1776, Adam Smith published the first modern statement of economic theory, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations The Wealth of Nations attacked mercantilism—the system of nationalistic economics that dominated economic thought in the 1700s Smith proved wrong the belief that trade was a zero sum game—that the gain of one nation from trade was the loss of another Voluntary exchange (trade) is a positive sum game —both nations gain

Implications of Adam Smith’s Theory Access to foreign markets helps create wealth If no nation imports, every company will be limited by the size of its home country market Imports enable a country to obtain goods that it cannot make itself or can make only at very high costs Trade barriers decrease the size of the potential market, hampering the prospects of specialization, technological progress, mutually beneficial exchange, and, ultimately, wealth creation

Adam Smith and Trade Barriers Smith was highly critical of trade barriers Trade barriers decrease - Specialization - Technological progress - Wealth creation The modern view of trade shares Smith’s dislike for trade barriers

A Simple Model of Production and Trade A basic model, often referred to as the Ricardian model, named after economist David Ricardo Assumptions Markets are competitive: Firms are price takers Static world: Technology is constant and there are no learning effects Labor is perfectly mobile: It can easily move back and forth between industries but perfectly immobile across national borders.

TABLE 3.1 Assumptions of the Simple Ricardian Trade Model

Absolute Productivity Advantage and the Gains from Trade Productivity: The amount of output obtained from a unit of input Labor productivity: (units of output) / (hours worked) If two loaves of bread can be produced in 1 hour, productivity = (2 loaves) / (1 hour) Absolute productivity advantage: The advantage held by a country that produces more of a certain good per hour worked than another

TABLE 3.2 Output per Hour Worked

Absolute Productivity Advantage and the Gains from Trade The U.S. opportunity cost of bread is 1.5 tons of steel: each unit of bread produced requires the economy to move labor out of steel production, forfeiting 1.5 tons of steel that it could have produced instead. In sum, trade between U.S. and Canada will occur at a price between these two limits

Comparative Productivity Advantage and the Gains from Trade Question: What happens if a country does not have an absolute productivity advantage in anything? Answer: Even if a country does not have any goods with an absolute productivity advantage, it can still benefit from trade - The idea that nations benefit from trade has nothing to do with whether a country has an absolute advantage in producing a particular good

Production Possibilities Curve (PPC) A production possibilities curve (PPC) shows the tradeoffs a country faces when choosing between two goods

FIGURE 3.1 A Production Possibilities Curve for the United States

FIGURE 3.2 Opportunity Costs and the Slope of the PPC

What Determines the Slope of the PPC? Using Figure 3.2 as an example, the slope of the PPC is -0.67: The number of loaves of bread forgone divided by the quantity of steel obtained

Relative Prices Without trade, the U.S. would forgo 0.67 loaves of bread for an additional ton of steel. This is the opportunity cost of steel, or the relative price of steel Why relative price? Because the price is not in monetary units but in units of the other good -Relative price of steel is the inverse of the price of bread: if 0.67 loaves of bread is the price of a ton of steel in the U.S., then 1.5 tons of steel is the price of one loaf of bread

The Consumption Possibilities Curve Autarky: The complete absence of trade; all nations can only consume the goods they produce at home Trade allows countries to raise their consumption Example: If the opportunity cost of steel in Canada is 3 loaves of bread per ton, and in the U.S. 0.67 loaves per ton, both countries can consume more by trading Gains from trade will occur if the price of steel settles somewhere between the opportunity costs in Canada and the U.S.

FIGURE 3.3 Production and Trade Before Specialization Let the price of bread settle at 2 loaves per ton U.S. trading possibilities are illustrated by the consumption possibilities curve (CPC) with a slope of -2 A = the combination of steel and bread available for trade

The Gains from Trade In sum, suppose the relative price of steel is 2 loaves of bread When the U.S. increases steel output by 1 ton, it gives up 0.67 loaves of bread output; however, it can now trade the steel for 2 loaves, leaving a net gain of 1.33 loaves (2 - 0.67 = 1.33) To meet U.S. demand for 2 more loaves of bread, Canada gives up 0.67 tons of steel output; however, it can now trade 2 loaves for 1 ton of steel, leaving a net gain of 0.33 tons (1 - 0.67 = 0.33)

FIGURE 3.4 Production to Maximize Income By specializing production at B and trading for bread, the U.S. obtains the largest possible consumption bundle C = the consumption bundle the U.S. obtains by producing at B, or by specializing in steel and trading for bread

FIGURE 3.5 Canada’s Gains from Trade Conversely, Canada, by specializing in the production at B and trading for steel, Canada obtains the largest possible consumption bundle.

Domestic Prices and the Trade Price How do we make sure that the trade price settles within If the trade price was 4 loaves of bread, both countries would specialize in steel. However, the consequent bread shortage and steel glut would increase the price of bread and decrease the price of steel; once the price of bread fell to less than 3.0, Canadian producers would switch back to bread If trade price is closer to 0.67, gains are larger for Canada; if it is closer to 3.0, gains are larger for the U.S.; however, both would gain from trade when the price falls in this range

Absolute and Comparative Productivity Advantage Contrasted Absolute productivity advantage is having a higher labor productivity. If each country has an absolute productivity advantage in one of the goods, both benefit by specializing in that good and trading it for the other good.

Absolute and Comparative Productivity Advantage Contrasted (cont.) Comparative productivity advantage is if a country’s opportunity costs of producing a good are lower than those of its trading partners. The concept is based on the idea that nations maximize their material well-being when they use their resources where they have their highest value.

Gains from Trade with No Absolute Advantage Japan has an absolute advantage in both cars (2>0.5) and steel (3>1), yet it can still gain from trade, as can Malaysia Once trade opens, the world price of cars will be between one and two tons of steel per car

TABLE 3.3 Output per Hour Worked

TABLE 3.4 Indicators of the Korean Economy

Comparative Advantage and “Competitiveness” Comparative advantage = competitive advantage when the prices of both inputs and outputs are an accurate indication of their relative scarcity Comparative advantage ≠ competitive advantage when the markets fail to correctly value the price of inputs and outputs -Imbalances result from government policies, such as subsidies or protection

Economic Restructuring Economic restructuring: Changes in the economy that may require some industries to grow and others to shrink or disappear In the Ricardian model, trade opening moved labor from bread to steel production: restructuring improved U.S. overall economic welfare but made its bread industry disappear If trade results in net gain (in an increase of the consumption bundle), a country will be better off by trading; however, some sectors may still lose

Economic Restructuring (cont.) Given that some lose due to economic restructuring, the government can seek to get the winners from trade and restructuring to compensate the losers Trade adjustment assistance (TAA) helps losers by providing extended unemployment benefits, worker retraining, and temporary tax on imports For example, the U.S. government created a special program for workers laid off because of NAFTA; in 1994, 17,000 workers qualified for the program

TABLE 3.5 Low-Cost and High-Cost Cotton Producers