Basic Price Optimization

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
C HAPTER Elasticity of Demand and Supply price elasticities of demand and supply, income and cross elasticities of demand, and using elasticity to forecast.
Advertisements

What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
1 CHAPTER.
13A CHAPTER Monopolistic Competition.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
4 CHAPTER Elasticity.
Chapter 4 Individual and Market Demand
Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Lesson 7-1 The “Marketplace”
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
+ Lecture 5: Price Discrimination AEM 4160: Strategic Pricing Prof. Jura Liaukonyte 1.
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Perfect Competition 12.
4 Elasticity Notes and teaching tips: 9, 27, 42, 43, 49, and 63.
Ind – Develop a foundational knowledge of pricing to understand its role in marketing. (Part II) Entrepreneurship I.
Demand Analysis and Strategy Paul C. Godfrey Mark H. Hansen Marriott School of Management.
Chapter foundations of Chapter M A R K E T I N G Understanding Pricing 13.
We can construct a linear demand function by using the common-sense notion that if the price p of a good rises, the demand for that good in the market.
A Disneyland dilemma: Two-part tariffs for a mickey mouse monopoly
Elasticity: Concept & Applications For Demand & Supply.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. You buy your music online and play it on an iPod. As the prices of a music download and an iPod have tumbled, the volume.
Fundamentals of Markets © 2011 D. Kirschen and the University of Washington 1.
Consumer Theory.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. Airlines and automobile producers are facing tough times: Prices are being slashed to drive sales and profits are turning.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
A Definition of Economics
Ekstrom Math 115b Mathematics for Business Decisions, part II Project 1: Marketing Computer Drives Math 115b.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Twelve Pricing and Advertising.
Equilibrium and Efficiency
Project 1: Marketing An Introduction. Goal Your goal is three-fold: To find the price of a particular product that will maximize profits. Determine the.
Chapter 14 Firms in competitive Markets
Ch. 21: Production and Costs Del Mar College John Daly ©2003 South-Western Publishing, A Division of Thomson Learning.
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets.
Economics Chapter Supply, Demand, and Elasticity Combined Version
Elasticity of Demand and Supply
Chapter 10 The Theory of Monopoly
Pricing Examples. Bundling In marketing, product bundling offers several products for sale as one combined product. This is common in the software business.
Chapter 15 Factor Markets Work is of two kinds: first, altering the position of matter at or near the earth’s surface relative to other matter; second,
MICROECONOMICS TOPIC 2 Economics DEMAND.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Lecture 4Slide 1 Topics to be Discussed Individual Demand Income and Substitution Effects Market Demand Consumer Surplus Empirical Estimation of Demand.
Chapter 4: Demand Opener
Perfect Competition *MADE BY RACHEL STAND* :). I. Perfect Competition: A Model A. Basic Definitions 1. Perfect Competition: a model of the market based.
Costs and Profit Maximization Under Competition
Elasticity of Demand and Supply 1 © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except.
Chapter 6 Demand, Supply, and Markets Economics 11 March 2012.
Chapter 4 Demand, Supply, and Markets © 2009 South-Western/Cengage Learning.
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency. What Makes a Market Competitive? Buyers and sellers have absolutely no effect on price Three characteristics: Absence.
Pricing Copyright © Texas Education Agency, All rights reserved.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopolistic Competition and Oligopoly 14 & 15 CHAPTER.
3 CHAPTER Demand and Supply © Pearson Education 2012 After studying this chapter you will be able to:  Describe a competitive market and think about.
Markets Markets – exchanges between buyers and sellers. Supply – questions faced by sellers in those exchanges are related to how much to sell and at.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
1 Chapter 3 Lecture DEMAND AND SUPPLY. 2 Market and Prices A market is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers to get information and do business.
11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
1 Chapter 1 Appendix. 2 Indifference Curve Analysis Market Baskets are combinations of various goods. Indifference Curves are curves connecting various.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Chapter 22: The Competitive Firm Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Market Factors Affecting Price
An extension to Salop’s model Focused on variety differentiation: consumers differ on the most preferred variety Expands it to include quality differentiation:
We’ve seen that competitive markets bring “order” -- price adjusts to balance supply and demand. Any other desirable properties of competitive markets?
Producer Choice: The Costs of Production and the Quest for Profit Mr. Griffin AP ECON MHS.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
ChapterDemand 8 8 Guiding Questions  Section 1: Understanding Demand  How does the law of demand affect the quantity demanded? The law of demand states.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Idil Yaveroglu Lecture Notes
Presentation transcript:

Basic Price Optimization Lecture 5

The Price Response Curve, d(p) How demand for a product varies as a function of price A function for each element in the PRO cube – each combination of product, market-segment and channel Similar to market demand function in economics E.g. different book sellers – effectiveness of marketing campaigns, perceived customer differences in quality, product differences, location etc. Percieved customer differences in quality – amazon’s recommendations; product differences – book mining

Each seller is relatively small E.g. wheat – a commodity, indifference among offerings, perfect knowledge about prices and will buy only from the lowest-price seller Each seller is relatively small Must only worry about how much to produce No need for Pricing and Revenue Optimization Surprisingly rare

Properties of price-response curve PRO decisions have time associated with them – minutes/hours in ecommerce, days/weeks in retail, longer as in long-term contract pricing Nonnegative Continuous – no gaps or jumps, thus invertible Differentiable – can take a derivative Downward sloping Downward-sloping demand curves do not mean that high prices will always be associated with low demand. A hotel revenue management will experience higher average rates when occupancy is high and lower average rates when occupancy is low. What the downward-sloping property does indicate is that, in any time period, demand would have been lower if prices had been higher, and vice versa.

For the rest we will ignore: Giffen goods – a student with an $8 budget per week for dinner; burger $1 and steak $2, the latter being eaten on Sundays; the price of burger goes up to $1.1 – and its demand goes up to 7; VERY rare in reality Price as an indicator of quality – wine: a market with many alternatives and some „lazy“ buyers, who use price as a proxy Conspicuous consumption – a rock star drinking $300 bottles of Cristal champagne and drive Bentleys as such buyers must overwhelm the rest, who will decrease their consumption. Economists doubt, whether they have ever existed Who do not have time or resources $10 – family dinner; $15 if couple next door is dropping by; $25 if wine-snob friends are coming Several restaurants have noted that a disproportionate number of customers tend to order the second-cheapest chardonnay on the menu—and they tailor their pricing accordingly. A medical-product company with a new home testing device – 75% lower than the cost of prevailing technology. Came to market at 60% below prevailing list price, but sales were slow. After repackaging, they came back at -20%, and the product was no longer considered inferior and unreliable, but cheaper enough to boost sales. French champagne and British cars

Price sensitivity: slope, a local estimator Semiconductors, current price $0.13 per chip, slope 1000 chips/week per cent; 2 cent increase -= 2000 chips per week; 3 cent decrease += 3000 chips per week; depends on units – pounds and cents vs. tons and dollars

Price sensitivity: elasticity, a local estimator, arc and point elasticity Percentage change in demand to the percentage change in price; does not depend on units

Semiconductors, current price $0 Semiconductors, current price $0.13 per chip, at 10000 chips per month; thinks his price elasticity is 1.5 Thus, a 15% increase in price, from $0.13 to $0.15, would lead to a decrease in demand of about 1.5*15%=22.5%: from 10000 to 7750

Short and long run elasticity Gasoline – short run 0.2, long run 0.7; similar milk – 20c price rise and long run response Durables (such as automobiles and washing machines) – long run elasticity is lower than short-run Level of analysis – market or company Short run gasoline – take fewer trips and use public transportation; long run – use higher mpg cars and depress the overall demand even further Milk and 20c price rise – short time reaction weak, but in the long run other stores are selected

Short and long run elasticity Fungible goods – such as salt – no long run choice On company level – see cars and Chevrolets

Willingness to pay Maximum for one customer– the reservation price

A uniform willingness-to-pay distribution corresponds to a linear price-response function

Partitions the price response function into a total-demand component and a willingness-to-pay component E.g. total demand varies seasonally, while the wtp distribution remains constant over the period of time We decompose our goal into estimating total demand and estimating the price response An advertising campaign will not increase the total population, but will shift wtp distribution When we open a new store, the total demand will be determined by the population served, but we can use wtp from similar demographics populations

Wtp can change – e.g. temperature sensitive Coca-Cola vending machines A sudden windfall or a big raise may increase an individual’s maximum wtp – if these are uncorralated population will be unchanged as a whole, but systematic changes will have the price-response function shifting Does not incorporate additional induced demand – price reduction may have one buying two pairs of socks Wtp framework is better for „big ticket“ consumer items and industrial goods

Linear wtp Is not a realistic global model If a competitor offers a close substitute, it will only work close to the market price

C is a parameter: d(1) = C These two – 3.10 from above, second from wtp slide nr 13

Constant elasticity price-response functions Not a realistic global model – in reality we expect elisticity to change as price changes If e<1 (inelastic demand) R’(p)>0, seller can increase revenue by increasing price If e>1, seller can increase revenue by decreasing price If e=1 then price change does not change revenue Wtp function is highly concentrated near zero Assumes, that the distribution of wtp drops steadily as price increases, but only approaches 0

What is a realistic price-response function? Car with market price of $13000 At $20k a few loyal customer will buy … and there is no big change from $20k->$21k If we are selling at $9k, almost everyone, who wants to buy a compact car, will buy from us (except the few very loyal to a competitor) … and there is no big change from $9k->$8k But at about the market price, elasticity is high At market price, many more will buy from us, when we are selling at $250 below, and even more will shift, if we ask $500 below the market price

The logit price response functions

b =0.0005; 0.001; 0.01; p=$13000; Price sensitivity is the highest at p^=-(a/b) We will fix p^=$13000, thus a=-$13000*b C is the market size=20000 As b grows, the market is more price sensitive, approaching perfect competition

Logistic distribution, has fat tails Price response function, that is based on normal distribution, is probit. It is difficult to work with as there is no closed-form version and logistic can be made to coincide with it in the viable range.

Empirical research has shown the logit function to be present on a wide range of markets

Price response with competition Incorporating Competiton in the Price-Response Function Often the prices are not available at the time In business-to-business markets they are never made visible to the competition Retailers do not have the time or resources to do exhaustive research on a daily basis BUT price-response function will be based on history and thus it already includes „typical“ competitive pricing Most managers identify competition as the number one factor influencing pricing, many complain about being at the mercy of their competitors who have „stupid“ or „irrational“ pricing

2) Consumer-Choice Modeling E.g. Online Petroleum Information System Different grades of petroleum offered by different sellers in all major markets in USA and Canada Different wtp’s represent the values that are placed on features and „brand value“ associated with each product Surplus is the difference between the price and the wtp

Not the cheapest – Audio Two, nor his favourite Cacophonia, but Koshiba

Let p(p1,p2,..,pn) – vector of prices Let μi be the market share of product i μi=fi(p) for all i Each alternative has a share between 0 and 1 Each buyer chooses one product Increase in price decreases the market share Increasing the price of a product increases the market shares of all competitors (substitutes)

The multinominal logit, b being price sensitivity Note that Koshiba is highly sensitive and gets a low market share when compared to Cacophonia, which is twice as expensive

The multinominal logit and the logit price-response function When other prices are constant the MNL reduces to LPRF Assume that other prices are constant, we set: Where a=ln(k) and we know that: 1/K=e^(-lnK)

To state the important If competitive prices are stable MNL provides little predictive value over LPRF There is a vast literature on consumer-choice modeling; Statistical packages such as SAS include procedures for estimating the parameters of the logit and probit market-share functions But there are weaknesses, namely: ….

Weaknesses Assumption: everyone purchases one alternative; what if some don’t purchase at all – since their wtp is below all prices? Thus we cannot say that market size D is independent of the prices offered: an aggressive discount not only siphons customers away from competitors, but will also make someone pay, who might not have purchased at all

We theoretically need information on all alternatives, whereas usually only some major competitors are considered A solution here is to derive a competitive index price by weighting the prices of major competitors and using this as a single competitive price in multinominal logit

Price response with competition 3)Anticipating competitive response More strategically: if we drop a price, will the competitors match; if we raise a price – once again, what will the competitors do? The approaches here fall under decision analysis and game theory – and there is a vast literature on the use of game theory in strategic pricing, but we are concidering tactical decisions of PRO

For example if customers in a market choose a supplier based on MNL price response model, then our action is to maximize our expected contribution given the competitors prices by setting our price The philosophy of pricing and revenue optimization is to make money by many small adjustments, searching for and vacuuming up small and transient puddles of profit as they appear in the marketplace Customers - by choosing the biggest surplus

Many of the price adjustments will fall below the radar screen of the competition, and will not trigger any explicit response But potential retaliations by competitors should still be considered: e.g. Hertz in the early 1990s by communicating its upcoming sophisticated PRO system in the price war eager car rental industry – it was able to generate additional revenue through thousands of small adjustments to prices, that the competitors were unable to match

Incremental costs The incremental cost of a customer commitment is the difference between the total costs a company would experience if it makes the commitment and the total cost it would experience if it doesn’t.

Examples An airline: additional meal and fuel cost + commissions or fees paid for booking A retailer – buying a stock of fashion goods: zero A drugstore – ordering a number of bottles of shampoo weekly: wholesale unit cost A distributor – bidding for a yearly contract with a hospital: expected cost of purchases, but also cost of customer service, operating costs and holding costs due to variance in orders and the returns To be the preferred provider of disposable medical supplies; it knows, about this expensive customer, that high levels of customer support is required, there is a wide variance in orders, high rates of product returns

The incremental costs are (closely related to ABC): Forward looking: some costs are sunk, others have still to be made Marginal: made for this customer, may not be the same as the average cost of similar past commitment Not fully allocated: not the overhead or fixed cost of staying in business Can depend on the type, size and duration of the commitment: for a multiunit order setup costs are allocated across all the units May be uncertain: Roadway Express, a trucking company – covering all the freight tendered by the customer at an agreed-on tariff Not fully allocated – the ones that result from the commitment Uncertain – amount, timing, and origin and destination not set beforehanbd – for all customers; will depend on whether it is a backhaul business (utilize capacity of existing trucks) or headhaul

The basic price optimization problem, to maximize the margin, m(p) total contribution; c is incremental cost m(p) total contribution and c incremental cost

Marginal revenue (derivative of total revenue with respect to price) should equal marginal cost (always negative) – total contribution is maximized

Price-response function d(p)=10000-800p Incremental cost $5 Marginal revenue R’(p)=10000-1600p Marginal cost = -$4000 P*=$8.75

If marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost, contribution can be increased by increasing price If marginal revenue is lower than marginal costs, price should be decreased – in order to increase contribution

Optimal contribution margin and elasticity We can rewrite 3.17 as 3.20, where e(p) is point elasticity; since the second term in 3.20 is always positive: If elasticity at our price is <1, we can increase total contribution by increasing price

If in 3.20 m’(p) = 0 then we get 3.21 (p-c)/p is the margin per unit expressed as a fraction of price – ‘the contribution margin ratio’ – if you purchase at $150 and sell at $200, it is ($200-$150)/$150=0.33 Thus, we derive a relationship between price elasticity, contribution margin and the optimal price as on the next page

At the optimal price, the contribution margin ratio is equal to the reciprocal of elasticity Let us derive p* from 3.21 At the current price, an electronics goods retailer seems to face a constant-elasticity price-response function, e=2.5, for a TV set Thus by 3.21 1/2.5=40% for a contribution margin; and for p*=(2.5/1.5)*180=$300 in order to maximize total contribution

And… we have imputed elasticity A seller thinks, he is pricing optimally, and his contribution margin ratio is 20% This can only be true, if the price elasticity is 5 Imputed price elasticity is a good ‘reality check’ on the credibility of a company’s current pricing

An example – a widget maker Unit production cost is constant at $5 Demand is given by a linear price-response fn: d(p)=10000-800p Thus, demand will be 0 for prices above $12.5

An example – a widget maker Demand is given by a linear price-response fn: d(p)=10000-800p Thus, d’(p)=800 Using 3.18, we see that the optimal price must solve: 10000-800p*=800(p*-$5) Which is 1600p*=14000; or p*=8.75

An example – a widget maker Total sales:10000-800*$8.75=3000 units Total revenue: 3000*$8.75=$26250 Total contribution: 3000*($8.75-$5)=$11250 TC is 0 at p=c=$5, max at p*=$8.75 and 0 at p=$12.5

An example – a widget maker Marginality check

Maximizing revenue Sometimes (e.g. in order to ‘buy’ more market share), we want to maximize total revenue (not total contribution) (or when c = 0) Revenue maximizing price occurs where the elasticity of the price-response function is 1 c = 0 also basically for movie theatres, video rentals, sporting events, also see industries active in markdown

Maximum revenue – marginal revenue =0 Maximum contribution – marginal revenue = marginal cost As in the figure, marginal revenue is a decreasing function of price, at least in the region of optimal price As we see, revenue maximizing price is lower than the contribution maximizing price

Widget company ‘buys’ more market share From 3.23 we see that: -800*p*+10000-800p*=0; thus p*=$6.25 and from d($6.25) = 10000-800*p->d=5000 Per unit margin is $1.25 and total contribution margin is 5000*$1.25=$6250 Maximum was $11250 – thus we gave up $5000 And ‘bought’ an additional 2000 units of demand We should at least check for the constraint that states price > incremental costs, to be out of red

Weighted combinations of revenue and contribution A company might want to maximize a weighted combination of total contribution and revenue, using 0<= α <=1 for that α=1 means total contribution maximization; α=0 means revenue maximization 3.26 means maximization of contribution with a discounted cost 3.26 is a transformed version of 3.25

The price that maximizes a weighted combination of revenue and contribution is greater than or equal to the revenue-maximizing price and less than or equal to the contribution-maximizing price.

…moreover The core problem of PRO is a constrained optimization problem, where the objective function is to maximize total contribution The constraints can be business rules (e.g. desire to maintain a minimum market share) or constraints on capacity or inventory The constraints may overrule the optimal price found as a result of calculations A key input is the price-response function

There are three approaches to incorporating competitive pricing into price optimization; the first assumes competitive pricing is already present in the price-response function – it is correctly used in a stable environment, or when prices are not available; in a more volatile environment competitive prices are included in a broader price-response model; the final approach tries to anticipate competitive response to one’s actions – this is usually done only when a strategic pricing change is contemplated