Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Chapter Nine 1 ® CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 6th. ed. N. Gregory Mankiw By Mannig.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Chapter Nine 1 ® CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 6th. ed. N. Gregory Mankiw By Mannig."— Presentation transcript:

1 Chapter Nine 1 ® CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 6th. ed. N. Gregory Mankiw By Mannig J. Simidian

2 Chapter Nine 2 Short-run fluctuations in output and employment are called the business cycle. In previous chapters, we developed theories to explain how the economy behaves in the long run; now we’ll seek to understand how the economy behaves in the short run.

3 Chapter Nine 3 GDP is the first place to start when analyzing the business cycle, since it is the largest gauge of economic conditions. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) is the official determiner of whether the economy is suffering from a recession. A recession is usually defined by a period in which there are two consecutive declines in real GDP. In recessions, both consumption and investment decline; however, investment (business equipment, structures, new housing and inventories) is even more susceptible to decline.

4 Chapter Nine 4 In recessions, unemployment rises. This negative (when one rises, the other falls) relationship between unemployment and GDP is called Okun’s Law, after Arthur Okun, the economist who first studied it. In short, it is defined as: Percentage Change in Real GDP = 3.5% - 2  the Change in the Unemployment Rate If the unemployment rate remains the same, real GDP grows by about 3.5 percent. For every percentage point the unemployment rate rises, real GDP growth typically falls by 2 percent. Hence, if the unemployment rate rises from 5 to 8 percent, then real GDP growth would be: Percentage Change in Real GDP = 3.5% - 2  (8% - 5%) = - 2.5% In this case, GDP would fall by 2.5%, indicating that the economy is in a recession.

5 Chapter Nine 5 Many economists in business and government have the role of forecasting short-run fluctuations in the economy. One way that economists arrive at forecasts is through looking at leading indicators. Each month, the Conference Board, a private economics Research announces the index of leading economic indicators, which consists of 10 data series.

6 Chapter Nine 6 1)Average workweek of production workers in manufacturing 2)Average initial weekly claims for unemployment insurance 3)New orders for consumer goods and materials adjusted for inflation 4)New orders, nondefense capital goods 5)Vendor performance 6)New building permits issued 7)Index of stock prices 8)Money-supply (M2) adjusted for inflation 9)Interest rate spread: the yield spread between 10-year Treasury notes and 3-month treasury bills 10) Index of consumer expectations

7 Chapter Nine 7 Classical macroeconomic theory applies to the long run but not to the short run–WHY? The short run and long run differ in terms of the treatment of prices. In the long run, prices are flexible and can respond to changes in supply or demand. In the short run, many prices are “sticky” at some predetermined level. Because prices behave differently in the short run than in the long run, economic policies have different effects over different time horizons. Let’s see this in action.

8 Chapter Nine 8

9 9 Long Run Short run This macroeconomic model allows us to examine how the aggregate price level and quantity of aggregate output are determined in the short run. It also provides a way to contrast how the economy behaves in the long run and how it behaves in the short run.

10 Chapter Nine 10 Aggregate demand (AD) is the relationship between the quantity of output demanded and the aggregate price level. It tells us the quantity of goods and services people want to buy at any given level of prices. Recall the Quantity Theory of Money (MV=PY), where M is the money supply, V is the velocity of money, P is the price level, and Y is the amount of output. It makes the not quite realistic, but very convenient assumption that velocity is constant over time. Also, when interpreting this equation, recall that the quantity equation can be rewritten in terms of the supply and demand for real money balances: M/P = (M/P) d = kY, where k = 1/V is a parameter determining how much money people want to hold for every dollar of income. This equation states that supply of money balances M/P is equal to the demand and that demand is proportional to output. The assumption of constant velocity is equivalent to the assumption of a constant demand for real money balances per unit of output.

11 Chapter Nine 11 The Aggregate Demand (AD) curve shows the negative relationship between the price level P and quantity of goods and services demanded Y. It is drawn for a given value of the money supply M. The aggregate demand curve slopes downward: the higher the price level P, the lower the level of real balances M/P, and therefore the lower the quantity of goods and services demanded Y. Price level Output (Y) AD As the price level decreases, we’d move down along the AD curve. Any changes in M or V would shift the AD curve. Remember that the demand for real output varies inversely with the price level.  Y = MV/  P

12 Chapter Nine 12 Think about the supply and demand for real money balances. If output is higher, people engage in more transactions and need higher real balances M/P. For a fixed money supply M, higher real balances imply a lower price level. Conversely, if the price level is lower, real money balances are higher; the higher level of real balances allows a greater volume of transactions, which means a greater quantity of output is demanded.

13 Chapter Nine 13 The aggregate demand curve is drawn for a fixed value of the money supply. In other words, it tells us the possible combinations of P and Y for a given value of M. If the Fed changes the money supply, then the possible combinations of P and Y change, which means the aggregate demand curve shifts. Let’s see how.

14 Chapter Nine 14 Price level Output (Y) AD' AD A decrease in the money supply M reduces the nominal value of output PY. For any given price level P, output Y is lower. Thus, a decrease in the money supply shifts the AD curve inward from AD to AD'. A decrease in the money supply M reduces the nominal value of output PY. For any given price level P, output Y is lower. Thus, a decrease in the money supply shifts the AD curve inward from AD to AD'.

15 Chapter Nine 15 Price level Output (Y) AD' AD An increase in the money supply M raises the nominal value of output PY. For any given price level P, output Y is higher. Thus, an increase in the money supply shifts the AD curve outward from AD to AD'. An increase in the money supply M raises the nominal value of output PY. For any given price level P, output Y is higher. Thus, an increase in the money supply shifts the AD curve outward from AD to AD'.

16 Chapter Nine 16 Aggregate supply (AS) is the relationship between the quantity of goods and services supplied and the price level. Because the firms that supply goods and services have flexible prices in the long run but sticky prices in the short run, the aggregate supply relationship depends on the time horizon. There are two different aggregate supply curves: the long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) and the short-run aggregate supply curve (SRAS). We also must discuss how the economy makes the transition from the short run to the long run. But, first, let’s build the long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS).

17 Chapter Nine 17 Because the classical model describes how the economy behaves in the long run, we can derive the long-run aggregate supply curve from the classical model. Recall the amount of output produced depends on the fixed amounts of capital and labor and on the available technology. To show this, we write Y = F(K, L) = Y According the classical model, output does not depend on the price level. Let’s think about this considering the market clearing process in the labor market, the “L” component of the production function.

18 Chapter Nine 18 Real wage, W/P W/P ndndndnd Hours worked Let’s begin at full employment, n*, with a wage of W/P 0. n * W/P 0 W/2P 0 Now let’s see how workers will respond when there is a sudden increase in the price level. nsnsnsns (Employees) (Employers) n At this new lower real wage, workers will cut back on hours worked. But, at the same time, employers increase their demand for workers. n  What will happen next?

19 Chapter Nine 19 W/P ndndndnd Hours worked n * W/2P0W/2P0W/2P0W/2P0 (Employees) (Employers) n n  So, right now the labor market is in “disequilibrium” where the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied. nsnsnsns We’re now going to see how “flexible wages” will allow the labor market to come back to equilibrium, at full employment, n*. To hire more workers, the employer must raise the real wage to 2W. 2W/2P02W/2P02W/2P02W/2P0 As a result of 2W, more workers are hired, and the labor market can move...

20 Chapter Nine 20 The vertical line suggests that changes in the price level will have no lasting impact on full employment. The vertical line suggests that changes in the price level will have no lasting impact on full employment. The mechanism we just went through will enable us to build our long run aggregate supply curve. P Y Y Y=F (K, L)

21 Chapter Nine 21 A reduction in the money supply shifts the aggregate demand curve downward from AD to AD'. Since the AS curve is vertical in the long run, the reduction in AD affects the price level, but not the level of output. The vertical-aggregate supply curve satisfies the classical dichotomy, because it implies that the level of output is independent of the money supply. This long-run level of output, Y, is called the full-employment or natural level of output. It is the level of output at which the economy’s resources are fully employed, or more realistically, at which unemployment is at its natural rate. P Y Y B A

22 Chapter Nine 22 Remember that the the vertical LRAS curve assumed that changes in the price level left no lasting impact on Y (because of the market-clearing process)--that will be the model for examining the long term. But we need a theory for the short run, defined as the interval of time during which markets are not fully cleared. P Y LRAS Y Y = F (K,L) P0P0 AD A B C A simple, but useful first approach is to assume short-run price rigidity meaning that the aggregate supply curve is flat. As AD shifts to AD we slide in an east-west direction to point B on the short run aggregate supply curve (SRAS). Then, in the long run, we move from B to C (move up and along AD). SRAS

23 Chapter Nine 23 P Y LRAS Y Y = F (K,L) AD SRAS In the long run, the economy finds itself at the intersection of the long-run aggregate supply curve and aggregate demand curve. Because prices have adjusted to this level, the SRAS crosses this point as well.

24 Chapter Nine 24 P Y LRAS Y AD SRAS AD' A B C The economy begins in long-run equilibrium at point A. Then, a reduction in aggregate demand, perhaps caused by a decrease in the money supply M, moves the economy from point A to point B, where output is below its natural level. As prices fall, the economy recovers from the recession, moving from point B to point C.

25 Chapter Nine 25 Exogenous changes in aggregate supply or aggregate demand are called shocks. A shock that affects aggregate supply is called a supply shock. A shock that affects aggregate demand is called a demand shock. These shocks that disrupt the economy push output and unemployment away from their natural levels. A goal of the aggregate demand/aggregate supply model is to help explain how shocks cause economic fluctuations. Economists use the term stabilization policy to refer to the policy actions taken to reduce the severity of short-run economic fluctuations. Stabilization policy seeks to dampen the business cycle by keeping output and employment as close to their natural rate as possible. The model in this chapter is a simpler version of the one we’ll see in coming chapters.

26 Chapter Nine 26 P Y LRAS Y AD SRAS AD' A B C The economy begins in long-run equilibrium at point A. An increase in aggregate demand, due to an increase in the velocity of money, moves the economy from point A to point B, where output is above its natural level. As prices rise, output gradually returns to its natural rate, and the economy moves from point B to point C.

27 Chapter Nine 27 P Y LRAS Y AD SRAS A B An adverse supply shock pushes up costs and prices. If AD is held constant, the economy moves from point A to point B, leading to stagflation—a combination of increasing prices and declining level of output. Eventually, as prices fall, the economy returns to the natural rate at point A. SRAS'

28 Chapter Nine 28 P Y LRAS Y AD SRAS AD' A B In response to an adverse supply shock, the Fed can increase aggregate demand to prevent a reduction in output. The economy moves from point A to point B. The cost of this policy is a permanently higher level of prices. SRAS'

29 Chapter Nine 29 Aggregate demand Aggregate supply Shocks Demand shocks Supply shocks Stabilization policy Aggregate demand Aggregate supply Shocks Demand shocks Supply shocks Stabilization policy


Download ppt "Chapter Nine 1 ® CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations A PowerPoint  Tutorial To Accompany MACROECONOMICS, 6th. ed. N. Gregory Mankiw By Mannig."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google