Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

2. WHY DO WE TRADE? - Part I.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "2. WHY DO WE TRADE? - Part I."— Presentation transcript:

1 2. WHY DO WE TRADE? - Part I

2 Six Valuable Lessons of Trade Theory
Free trade can raise aggregate economic efficiency and aggregate economic welfare. Free trade will benefit a country even if it is less efficient than all other countries in every industry. Some people will suffer losses with free trade. A domestic firm may lose out in international competition even if it is the lowest cost producer in the world. Trade protection may, in some special cases, be beneficial for a country. Although trade protection can be beneficial, the case for free trade remains strong. Trough specialization and division of labor we can increase economic efficiency; we will be able to consume more and larger variety of goods at same input of work. So gains for both producers and consumers. Even though you may not have absolute advantage in any production, you may will have comparative advantage. We should, though, be concerned of the net welfare. Firm may lose even if having absolute advantage in production. We can show that in some cases, for example, a country with a large market share in imports, can be better off with some optimal tariff policy. Even tough may be beneficial for a country but not for the world.

3 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
* Ratio of exports + imports to GDP multiplied by 100 Index of Openness* Country Name 1960 1980 2000 2015 Hong Kong 0,00 178,38 279,12 400,87 Estonia - 126,51 154,42 High income: no OECD 25,99 42,71 51,75 61,56 Switzerland 54,52 85,46 98,25 114,09 Iceland 86,84 69,41 71,95 100,99* Sweden 46,44 56,90 82,33 86,45 Germany 41,99 61,39 85,99 Finland 43,35 62,90 74,99 73,69 Greece 24,67 44,59 58,42 63,69 Low Income 46,82 59,68 Turkey 5,73 17,09 43,19 58,80 France 26,97 43,24 55,26 61,43 United Kingdom 41,80 49,89 51,83 56,46 OECD Members 23,65 37,37 47,51 56,71 Middle Income 19,74 28,45 51,04 50,00 India 11,10 15,12 26,44 42,41 China 8,73 12,42 39,75 40,67 Japan 21,01 27,79 20,31 36,78 United States 9,17 20,07 24,98 28,00 Some countries trade extensively, others very little. In some countries the index is very high, other rather low. How can this be understood and explained? Päivitetty k2017 The higher the index the larger the influence of trade on domestic activities. * 2014 Source: World Bank open data 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

4 Exports of goods and services in EU (% of GDP in 2015)
An other measure of openness is also used: Exports/GDP; see your text book tables. Päivitetty k2017 Source: World Bank open data 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

5 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
NOTE! Openness index value greater than 100 means that the country's exports are bigger than its overall level of production (GDP or GNP). Such a situation could occur if much of the economic activity of the country in question involves the assembly and export of final products made from imported raw or partially assembled materials. The value in excess of 100 comes about from the fact that output is (always) measured in terms of value added -- the value of capital and labor services devoted in this case to the assembly of goods -- while exports are measured in terms of the total value of goods -- including the value of the imported parts. Clearly, in such circumstances it is quite likely for exports to be greater than value added. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

6 Major Topics of Trade Theory?
The classical theory of international trade is concerned with the following three questions: 1. What are the gains from trade? In other words, if countries benefit from international trade, where do the gains come from, and how are they divided among the trading countries? 2. Why Do We Trade?

7 Major Concerns of Trade Theory? continued
2. What is the structure/pattern of trade? In other words, which goods/services are exported, and which are imported? What are the fundamental laws that govern international allocation of resources and the flow of trade? 3. What are the terms of trade? In other words, at what prices are the exported and imported goods exchanged? 2. Why Do We Trade?

8 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
International difference in autarky* price of a product S in two countries: PS/PT PS/PT Finland China NSSA With trade prices start to equalize. NSSB P0 NSS/ = national supply/demand NSD When trade starts the demand for Chinese product will increase. When trade starts the demand for Finish product will decrease. P0 Prices may be different in different countries: Then, if there is autarky (closed economy = no trade allowed), I am consumer rather in China and producer in Finland!!! If we allow international trade and transaction cost (transportation cost and other costs) is not high then arbitrage will take place… NDSA PS/PT = relative price of product S NDSB QS Country A Country B QS 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage * Autarky = closed economy = no international trade allowed in a country

9 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Because country B has a lower autarky (relative) price of S, it is said to have a comparative advantage in S and a comparative disadvantage in T and by same logic, country A has a comparative advantage in T and comparative disadvantage in S. If trade would be allowed, consumers in country A would like to buy product S from country B, and prices would start to equalize. Why Are the Autarky Prices Different? Differences in technology or productivity Difference in resource endowments Difference in demand Ricardian model of comparative advantage Hecksher-Ohlin model 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

10 Understanding the Gains from International Trade
Nations (or firms in different nations) trade with each other because they benefit from it! We can divide the different trade theories in four categories... 2. Why Do We Trade?

11 Different Trade Theories
1. Early Trade Theory: Mercantilists 2. Classical Trade Theory: Ricardian Model (section 2.1) 3. Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model (section 2.2) 4. Alternative Approaches to Trade Theory (section 2.3) 2. Why Do We Trade?

12 1. Early Trade Theory: Mercantilists
Until mid-eighteenth century, it was believed that the purpose of international trade was to keep exports greater than imports and pile up gold, and when/if deficits were created they believed that imports had to be restricted. Mercantilists assumed trade to be a zero-sum game since they assumed that fixed amounts of goods and of gold existed in the world and that trade merely determined their distribution among the various nations. 2. Why Do We Trade?

13 Theories 2 - 4 will be now discussed in more detail ...
But in the 1740s, David Hume explained that as quantity of money (gold) changes, so also does the price level, and the nation's real wealth is unaffected. In 1770s, Adam Smith argued that import restrictions would reduce the gains from specialization and make a nation poorer. He used absolute advantage to explain the benefits of trade. Theories will be now discussed in more detail ... 2. Why Do We Trade?

14 2. Why Do We Trade? continued
2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage: Absolute vs. Comparative Advantage 2.2 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2.3 Alternative Trade Theories: Results from Practical Evidence 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

15 Economic Basis for Trade
What are the factors that determine how countries will specialize in international trade? David Ricardo (On the Principles of Political Economy, 1819), developed the theory of comparative advantage... 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

16 Economic Basis for Trade continued
According to this theory, Specialization and free trade will benefit all trading partners (= real wages will rise), even those who may be absolutely less efficient producers. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

17 Absolute vs. Comparative Advantage
Although comparative advantage is a simple concept, experience shows that it is a surprisingly hard concept for many people to understand (or accept). 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

18 Absolute vs. Comparative Advantage continued
Indeed, Paul Samuelson — the Nobel laureate economist who did much to develop the model of international trade — has described comparative advantage as the best example he knows of an economic principle that is undeniably true yet not obvious to intelligent people. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

19 Definition: Absolute Advantage
The advantage in the production of a product enjoyed by one country over another when it uses fewer resources to produce that product than the other country does. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

20 Absolute Advantage - an Illustration
Suppose country A and country B produce wheat, but that A's climate is more suited to wheat and its labor is more productive. Country A will therefore produce more wheat per acre than country B and use less labor in growing it and bringing it to the market. Country A thus enjoys an absolute advantage over country B in the production of wheat. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

21 Definition: Comparative Advantage
The advantage in the production of a product enjoyed by one country over another when that product can be produced at lower cost in terms of other products than it could be in the other country. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

22 Comparative Advantage - an Illustration
Suppose that countries C and D both produce wheat and corn and that C enjoys an absolute advantage in the production of both - that is, C's climate is better than D's, and fewer of C's resources are needed to produce a given quantity of both wheat and corn. C and D each need to choose between planting land with wheat and corn. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

23 Comparative Advantage - an Illustration continued
To produce more wheat, either country must transfer land from corn production and vice versa. Suppose that in country C, a bushel of wheat has an opportunity cost of two bushels of corn. At the same time, suppose that producing a bushel of wheat in country D requires to give up only one bushel of corn D enjoys a comparative advantage in producing wheat. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

24 Example 1: Gains from Mutual Absolute Advantage
Assume a) two countries with fixed amount of land (100 acres) and land yields given in the table below, b) only two products produced (wheat and cotton), c) preferences for food and clothing are such that both countries consume equal amounts of wheat and cotton. Production Possibilities Frontiers (PPF) before trade: 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

25 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
PPF in Each Country: Example 1: Continued When there is no trade, the allocation of resources will be such that both countries will produce 150 bushels of wheat and 150 bales of cotton. New Zealand Australia Wheat Wheat 600 W: 25 acres x 6 bu/acre C: 75 acres x 2 bales/acre W: 75 acres x 2 bu/acre C: 25 acres x 6 bales/acre Both countries would produce and consume at 150, 150. 200 (150, 150) (150, 150) PPF 600 200 Cotton Cotton 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

26 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 1: Continued Expanded possibilities after trade: If countries realize that they should specialize (Australia in cotton and New Zealand in wheat) and trade, both countries could gain. Both are now specializing: 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

27 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 1: Continued In this situation 300 bushels of wheat is traded for 300 bales of cotton: New Zealand Australia Wheat Wheat 600 (300, 300) (300, 300) 200 200 600 Cotton Cotton 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

28 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 1: Continued Trade enables both countries to move beyond their previous resource and productivity constraints. Both countries (after trade) can consume beyond their production possibilities (PPFs)! This is the beauty of trade! 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

29 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 2: Gains from trade when one country has a double absolute advantage Production Possibilities and Consumption in a Closed Economy (same assumptions as before): NZ: 50 x 6 = 300 both wheat and cotton. A: 75 x 1 = 75 wheat 25 x 3 = 75 cotton 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

30 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 2: Continued When countries realize that they can benefit from specialization and trade: Only partial specialization: 75 x 6 = 450 and 25 x 6 = 150 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

31 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Example 2: Continued If 100 bu of wheat from NZ is traded to 200 bales of cotton from Australia Consumption after trade: Stage 3 When countries specialize they will maximize their combined output and use resources more efficiently: both countries are better off than they were before the trade (closed economy consumptions were 300, 300 and 75,75). Both have moved beyond their own production possibilities. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

32 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
By exposing firms and products to international competition, economies are encouraged to focus on areas of comparative advantage. This helps ensure that scarce skills and resources are deployed where they are most productive. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

33 International Equilibrium with Increasing Costs
Next we will extend the classical model of trade to the more general case of increasing opportunity costs and introduce demand by means of social indifference curves. Indifference Map and Consumer Equilibrium Increasing Opportunity Cost Clothing a) Product specific factors. b) Different industries use factors in different proportions. Clothing I’’’ I’’ PPF I’ Food Food 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

34 General Equilibrium in a Small Open Economy
2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

35 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Specialization Based on Comparative Advantage (countries PPF are different) and the Resulting Gains from Trade 2. After trade production takes place in Q and Q* and consumption at S and S*, respectively. 1. Assume such a domestic price ratios that E (in US) and E* (in UK) are consumption and production in autarky (= no trade). America Britain Figure 1 (a) Figure 1 (b) 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

36 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Specialization Based on Comparative Advantage and the Resulting Gains from Trade continued Figure 1: In autarky, America produces and consumes at E, and Britain at E*. With trade, America shifts production from E to Q and consumes at S by exporting VQ units of food to Britain in exchange for VS units of British clothing. America is better off with trade because S lies on a higher indifference curve than E. Indeed, in our illustration, America consumes more food and more clothing at S than at E. Britain shifts production from E* to Q* and consumption from E* to S*. Britain’s welfare increases also. Trade triangles SVQ and Q*V*S* are identical. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

37 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage
Different set of indifference curves! Same Production Technique in Both Countries, Trade Based on Different Taste Figure 2 In autarky US produces and consumes at A and UK at B. After free trade both will produce at Q but consume at A’ and B’, respectively. America Again both countries can consume beyond their production possibilities. Clothing Britain Food 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

38 Trade Based on Different Taste continued
Figure 2: Trade based on different tastes. America and Britain share the same production frontier MN (= same technology in both countries). In autarky, America produces and consumes at A, and Britain at B. With free trade, both countries produce at Q, but America consumes at A’ and Britain at B’. Trade triangles A’VQ and QSB’ are identical. 2. Why Do We Trade? The Law of Comparative Advantage

39 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.2 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model
2.1 The Law of Comparative Advantage: Absolute vs. Comparative Advantage 2.2 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model 2.3 Alternative Trade Theories: Results from Practical Evidence 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

40 What are the ultimate determinants of comparative advantage?
Ricardo did not bother to answer this question. He just assumed that the differences in comparative advantage depended on comparative difference in labor productivity (that is, differences in technology), but he did not explain the basis for these differences. Implicit reason in his example was climate... 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

41 What are the ultimate determinants of comparative advantage? continued
It remained to Heckscher and Ohlin to offer an explanation for comparative advantage. And this theory has become, since 1930s, the orthodox explanation of the ultimate cause of international trade. Eli Heckscher ( ) Bertil Ohlin ( ) 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

42 What are the ultimate determinants of comparative advantage? continued
Their basic idea is: 1. Commodities differ in their factor requirements. 2. Countries differ in their factor endowments. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

43 What are the ultimate determinants of comparative advantage? continued
A country has comparative advantage in those commodities that use its abundant factors intensively. This is why labor-abundant countries, such as India and China export footwear, rugs, textiles, and other labor intensive commodities; and land-abundant countries, such as Argentina, Australia, and Canada, export meat, wheat, wool, and other land-intensive commodities. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

44 The Basic Assumptions of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model:
1. Number of countries, factors, and commodities are all two (often referred to as the 2 x 2 x 2 model). 2. Technology is the same in both countries. 3. Constant returns to scale 4. Strong factor intensity 5. Incomplete specialization 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

45 The Basic Assumptions of the Heckscher-Ohlin Model continued:
6. Perfect competition 7. Factors are perfectly mobile within each country but perfectly immobile between countries. 8. Tastes are largely similar between countries. 9. Free trade 10. Transportation costs are zero. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

46 Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem with a Single Technique
The structure of trade, in general, can be traced back to differences in factor endowments, technology, and tastes. Since Heckscher-Ohlin theory assumes that technology and tastes are similar between countries, it attributes the comparative advantage to differences in factor endowments. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

47 Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem with a Single Technique continued
In summary, the capital-abundant country exports the capital-intensive commodity, and the labor-abundant country exports the labor-intensive commodity. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

48 Example 1: Factor Endowments and Production-Possibilities
One country Required inputs per unit of output: 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

49 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.2 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Example 1: Continued Cloth 600 M Capital constraint J 225 E Labor constraint 150 JEH is the PPF H G 150 200 450 Steel Figure 3 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

50 2. Why Do We Trade? - 2.2 Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model
Example 1: Continued Figure 3: Derivation of the production-possibilities frontier. If the economy had an unlimited supply of capital (labor), it would be able to produce along the labor constraint JG (capital constraint MH). When the supplies of both factors are limited, both constraints become binding and the production frontier coincides with the heavy kinked line JEH. Because steel is capital intensive relative to cloth, the capital constraint is steeper than the labor frontier. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

51 Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem with a Single Technique
Cloth Figure 4 Since same tastes in both countries, only one set of communal indifference curves. Before trade, America produces and consumes at R, and Britain at Q*. With free trade, America shifts production to Q and consumption to C. Britain maintains production at Q* but consumes at C*. Steel Figure 4 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

52 Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem with a Single Technique
Figure 4: Production frontiers JQH and J*Q*H* reflect the fact that America is endowed with more capital than Britain, while Britain is endowed with more labor than America. Before trade, America produces and consumes at R, and Britain at Q*. With free trade, America shifts production to Q and consumption to C. Britain maintains production at Q* but shifts consumption to C*. Trade triangles CQV and Q*C*V* are identical. America exports steel, and Britain cloth. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

53 Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem with Many Techniques
Cloth Before trade, America produces and consumes at R, and Britain at R*. With free trade, America produces at Q and consumes at C, and Britain at Q* and C*, respectively. Steel Figure 5 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

54 Heckcher-Ohlin Theorem with Many Techniques
Figure 5: Production frontier JH of America (the capital-abundant country) is skewed along the axis for steel (the capital-intensive commodity); and the production frontier J*H* of Britain (the labor-abundant country) is skewed along the axis for cloth (the labor-intensive commodity). Before trade, America produces and consumes at R, and Britain at R*. With free trade, America produces at Q and consumes at C, and Britain at Q* and C*, respectively. Trade triangles CQV and Q*C*V* are identical, America exports steel, and Britain cloth. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

55 Derivation of Offer Curves and the International Equilibrium
Figure 6 (a) Figure 6 (b) 2. At p = 3, America shifts production to Q and consumption to S. 3. And at p = 4, R and K, respectively. US offer curve Clothing America’s imports of clothing 1. In autarky (p = 2) US produces and consumes at E. Food America’s exports of food TOT = Terms of Trade = ratio of export and import prices 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

56 Derivation of Offer Curves and the International Equilibrium continued
Figure 6: Derivation of America’s offer curve. At the Autarkic relative price of food (p), assumed to be equal to 2, America produces and consumes at E in panel (a), and trades at the origin of panel (b). At p=3, America shifts production to Q and consumption to S in panel (a), and trades at S in panel (b). Similarly, at p=4, America produces at R and consumes at K in panel (a), and trades at K in panel (b). Trade triangles SVQ and KGR are identical to triangles SJO and KLO, respectively. The locus of all trade points (such as S and K) in panel (b) is America’s offer curve. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

57 International Equilibrium
Here the offer curves of two trading countries define the international equilibrium at K. Figure 7 America’s imports Britain’s exports Clothing Food America’s exports Britain’s imports 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

58 Derivation of Offer Curves and the International Equilibrium continued
Figure 7: International equilibrium International equilibrium occurs at K, where the offer curves intersect. America exports OL units of food to Britain and imports OL* units of clothing from Britain. The slope of terms-of-trade line TOT3 gives equilibrium terms of trade OL*/OL. 2. Why Do We Trade? Modern Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin Model

59 2. WHY DO WE TRADE? End of Fun! - Part II On next lecture:


Download ppt "2. WHY DO WE TRADE? - Part I."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google