Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.1 Chapter 22 Decision Analysis.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Decision Theory.
Advertisements

Chapter 3 Decision Analysis.
20- 1 Chapter Twenty McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
1 1 Slide © 2004 Thomson/South-Western Payoff Tables n The consequence resulting from a specific combination of a decision alternative and a state of nature.
Chapter 18 Statistical Decision Theory Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Statistics for Business and Economics 7 th.
Decision Theory.
Chapter Topics The Payoff Table and Decision Trees Opportunity Loss
Chapter 21 Statistical Decision Theory
Chapter 17 Decision Making 17.1 Payoff Table and Decision Tree 17.2 Criteria for Decision Making.
Chapter 3 Decision Analysis.
Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter Twenty An Introduction to Decision Making GOALS.
Managerial Decision Modeling with Spreadsheets
1 1 Slide © 2000 South-Western College Publishing/ITP Slides Prepared by JOHN LOUCKS.
©The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. 2008McGraw-Hill/Irwin An Introduction to Decision Making Chapter 20.
1 1 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Slides by JOHN LOUCKS St. Edward’s University.
DSC 3120 Generalized Modeling Techniques with Applications
Dr. C. Lightner Fayetteville State University
1 1 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or.
Chapter 7 Decision Analysis
Slides prepared by JOHN LOUCKS St. Edward’s University.
Chapter 4 Decision Analysis.
Chap 19-1 Copyright ©2012 Pearson Education, Inc. publishing as Prentice Hall On Line Topic Decision Making Basic Business Statistics 12 th Edition.
1 1 Slide Decision Analysis n Structuring the Decision Problem n Decision Making Without Probabilities n Decision Making with Probabilities n Expected.
Part 3 Probabilistic Decision Models
Chapter 8 Decision Analysis MT 235.
1 1 Slide Decision Analysis Professor Ahmadi. 2 2 Slide Decision Analysis Chapter Outline n Structuring the Decision Problem n Decision Making Without.
1 1 Slide © 2009 South-Western, a part of Cengage Learning Slides by John Loucks St. Edward’s University.
BA 555 Practical Business Analysis
Decision Analysis Chapter 3
Decision Making Under Uncertainty and Under Risk
Decision analysis: part 1 BSAD 30 Dave Novak Source: Anderson et al., 2013 Quantitative Methods for Business 12 th edition – some slides are directly from.
1 1 Slide © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole.
Chapter 14 Decision Making
BA 452 Lesson C.4 The Value of Information ReadingsReadings Chapter 13 Decision Analysis.
Operations Management Decision-Making Tools Module A
1 1 Slide © 2009 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Slides by JOHN LOUCKS St. Edward’s University.
Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft Excel, 4e © 2004 Prentice-Hall, Inc. Chap 16-1 Chapter 16 Decision Making Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft.
Decision Analysis Chapter 3
1 1 Slide © 2005 Thomson/South-Western EMGT 501 HW Solutions Chapter 12 - SELF TEST 9 Chapter 12 - SELF TEST 18.
1 Decision Analysis Here we study the situation where the probability of each state of nature is known.
Chapter 8 Decision Analysis n Problem Formulation n Decision Making without Probabilities n Decision Making with Probabilities n Risk Analysis and Sensitivity.
Lecture No. 41 Chapter 12 Contemporary Engineering Economics Copyright © 2010 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010.
“ The one word that makes a good manager – decisiveness.”
An Introduction to Decision Theory (web only)
An Introduction to Decision Theory
Decision Analysis (cont)
Chapter 3 Decision Analysis.
Value of information Marko Tainio Decision analysis and Risk Management course in Kuopio
1 1 Slide Decision Theory Professor Ahmadi. 2 2 Slide Learning Objectives n Structuring the decision problem and decision trees n Types of decision making.
Contemporary Engineering Economics, 6 th edition Park Copyright © 2016 by Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Decision-Tree Analysis Lecture No.
Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft Excel, 4e © 2004 Prentice-Hall, Inc. Chap 16-1 Chapter 16 Decision Making Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft.
Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft Excel, 5e © 2008 Prentice-Hall, Inc.Chap 17-1 Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft® Excel 5th Edition Chapter.
Basic Business Statistics, 10e © 2006 Prentice-Hall, Inc. Chap 17-1 Chapter 17 Decision Making Basic Business Statistics 10 th Edition.
Copyright © 2005 Brooks/Cole, a division of Thomson Learning, Inc Chapter 23 Decision Analysis.
Models for Strategic Marketing Decision Making. Market Entry Decisions To enter first or to wait Sources of First-Mover Advantages –Technological leadership.
Fundamentals of Decision Theory Chapter 16 Mausam (Based on slides of someone from NPS, Maria Fasli)
QUANTITATIVE TECHNIQUES
Decision Analysis.
1 1 © 2003 Thomson  /South-Western Slide Slides Prepared by JOHN S. LOUCKS St. Edward’s University.
Decision Analysis Anderson, Sweeney and Williams Chapter 4 Read: Sections 4.1, 4.2, 4.3, 4.4, 4.5, 4.6, and appendix 4.1.
Chapter 19 Statistical Decision Theory ©. Framework for a Decision Problem action i.Decision maker has available K possible courses of action : a 1, a.
Chapter 8 Decision Analysis n Problem Formulation n Decision Making without Probabilities n Decision Making with Probabilities n Risk Analysis and Sensitivity.
1 1 Slide © 2005 Thomson/South-Western Chapter 13 Decision Analysis n Problem Formulation n Decision Making without Probabilities n Decision Making with.
Decision Making Under Uncertainty
John Loucks St. Edward’s University . SLIDES . BY.
Chapter 23 Decision Analysis.
MNG221- Management Science –
Chapter 13 Decision Analysis
Statistical Decision Theory
Chapter 17 Decision Making
Presentation transcript:

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.1 Chapter 22 Decision Analysis

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.2 Decision Analysis… In decision analysis: We deal with the problem of selecting one alternative from a list of several possible decisions. There may be no statistical data, or if there are data, the decision may depend only partly on them, and Profits and losses are directly involved. We will draw upon concepts from probability theory, Bayes’ Law, and expected value.

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.3 Decision Problem – Terminology… Choices, decisions, possibilities, alternative courses of action, decision alternatives… these are referred to as acts (a i ). E.g.: a 1 : Invest in a GIC, or a 2 : Invest in the stock market. Acts are controllable; they reflect our choices.

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.4 Decision Problem – Terminology… What actually comes to pass in the future, an outcome, is referred to as a state of nature (s i ): E.g.: s 1 : Interest rates increase, or s 2 : Interest rates stay steady or decline. States of nature are uncontrollable. When enumerating states of nature, we should define all possible outcomes, (i.e. the list should be mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive)

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.5 Decision Problem – Terminology… For each combination of an act and a state of nature, the amount of profit is calculated. All this data: acts, states of nature, and profits are summarized into a payoff table: Acts: States of Nature: a1a1 a2a2 …ajaj s1s1 payoff 1,1 payoff 1,2 …payoff 1,j s2s2 payoff 2,1 payoff 2,2 …payoff 2,j : :::: sisi payoff i,1 payoff i,2 …payoff i,j E.g. This is the payoff we will receive IF we take action a 2 AND s 1 comes to pass in the future…

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.6 Decision Problem – Terminology… An opportunity loss is the difference between what the decision maker’s profit for an act is and what the profit could have been had the best decision been made. Opportunity loss is calculated row-wise, by taking the combination of act & state of nature with the highest value and then subtracting this maximum value from all the payoffs in the row. If done correctly, we will be left with one zero (where the maximum payoff was located) and positive numbers for all other act / state of nature combinations.

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.7 Example 22.1… Let’s put some numbers to these concepts… A man wants to invest $1 million for 1 year. He has three possible alternatives (i.e. acts) a 1 : Invest in a GIC paying 10%. a 2 : Invest in a bond at 8%. a 3 : Invest in stocks. Acts: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.8 Example 22.1… Our investor concludes that there are three possible outcomes that can happen during the year his money is invested (i.e. states of nature) s 1 : Interest rates increase. s 2 : Interest rates stay the same. s 3 : Interest rates decrease. States of Nature: s 1  R>0 s 2  R=0 s 3  R<0

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning 22.9 Example 22.1… Our investor determines the amount of profit he will make for each possible combination of an act and a state of nature and we create a profit table… Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1  R>0 $100,000-$50,000$150,000 s 2  R=0 $100,000$80,000$90,000 s 3  R<0 $100,000$180,000$40,000 E.g. We expect to lose $50,000 IF we invest in an 8% bond AND the interest rate goes up in the future…

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Example 22.1… Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1  R>0 $100,000-$50,000$150,000 s 2  R=0 $100,000$80,000$90,000 s 3  R<0 $100,000$180,000$40,000 opportunity loss table Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1  R>0 $50,000$200,000$0 s 2  R=0 $0$20,000$10,000 s 3  R<0 $80,000$0$140,000 Opportunity loss is calculated row-wise, by taking the combination of act & state of nature with the highest value and then subtracting this maximum value from all the payoffs in the row… If done correctly, we will be left with one zero (where the maximum payoff was located) and positive numbers for all other act / state of nature combinations…

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Decision Trees… Often a decision maker must choose between sequences of acts. Here a payoff table will not suffice to determine the best alternative; instead, we require a decision tree. Though similar to a probability tree, a decision tree represents acts and states of nature sequentially (chronologically). By convention: a square node is used to denote a point where a decision (act) is made, and a circular node represents a state of nature…

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Decision Tree… decision state of nature start with a decision node $100,000* –$50,000 $80,000 $180,000 $150,000 a1a1 a2a2 a3a3 s1s1 s2s2 s3s3 s1s1 s2s2 s3s3 $90,000 $40,000 *A GIC (a 1 ) always pays $100,000 regardless of (s i ) t

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Monetary Value Decision… Often it is possible to assign probabilities to the states of nature, that is some values P(s i ). Our investor believes that future interest rates are most likely to remain essentially the same as they are today and that (of the remaining two states of nature) rates are more likely to decrease than to increase. His probabilities might be: P(s 1 ) =.2 P(s 2 ) =.5 P(s 3 ) =.3

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Monetary Value Decision… Since we’ve determined probabilities for the states of nature, we can compute the expected monetary value (EMV) of each act… EMV(a j ) = P(s 1 ) x Payoff 1,j + P(s 2 ) x Payoff 2,j + … + P(s i ) x Payoff i,j Hence in our example: EMV(a 1 ) =.2(100,000) +.5(100,000) +.3(100,000) = $100,000 EMV(a 2 ) =.2(-50,000) +.5(80,000) +.3( ) = $84,000 EMV(a 3 ) =.2(150,000) +.5(90,000) +.3(40,000) = $87,000 Hence we choose the act (a 1 ) with the highest expected monetary value; i.e. EMV* = $100,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Monetary Value… We can use our payoff table for this purpose as well… EMV* = $100,000 Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1P=.20 $100,000-$50,000$150,000 s 2P=.50 $100,000$80,000$90,000 s 3P=.30 $100,000$180,000$40,000 EMV: $100,000$84,000$87,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Opportunity Loss (EOL) Decision We can also calculate the expected opportunity loss (EOL) of each act by using the opportunity loss table and our probabilities for states of nature… opportunity loss table Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1P=.20 $50,000$200,000$0 s 2P=.50 $0$20,000$10,000 s 3P=.30 $80,000$0$140,000 EOL: $34,000$50,000$47,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Rollback Technique for Decision Trees…  Add the probabilities for the states of nature to the branches on our probability tree… $100,000 –$50,000 $80,000 $180,000 $150,000 a1a1 a2a2 a3a3 P(s 1 )=.20 $90,000 $40,000 P(s 2 )=.50 P(s 3 )=.30 P(s 1 )=.20 P(s 2 )=.50 P(s 3 )=.30 P(s)=1.00

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Rollback Technique for Decision Trees…  Calculate the expected monetary value (EMV) for each round node… $100,000 –$50,000 $80,000 $180,000 $150,000 a1a1 a2a2 a3a3 P(s 1 )=.20 $90,000 $40,000 P(s 2 )=.50 P(s 3 )=.30 P(s 1 )=.20 P(s 2 )=.50 P(s 3 )=.30 EMV= (.20)(-50,000) + (.50)(80,000) + (.30)(180,000) = $84,000 P(s)=1.00 EMV= (1)(100,000) = $100,000 EMV= (.20)(150,000) + (.50)(90,000) + (.30)(40,000) = $87,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Rollback Technique for Decision Trees…  Calculate the expected monetary value (EMV) for each round node… $100,000 –$50,000 $80,000 $180,000 $150,000 a1a1 a2a2 a3a3 $90,000 $40,000 $84,000 $100,000 $87,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Rollback Technique for Decision Trees… At each square node, we make a decision by choosing the branch with the largest EMV. $100,000 –$50,000 $80,000 $180,000 $150,000 a1a1 a2a2 a3a3 $90,000 $40,000 $84,000 $100,000 $87,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Additional Information… We can acquire useful information from consultants, surveys, or other experiments in an effort to improve our decision process, but this additional information comes at a cost to us. What’s the maximum price we’d be willing to pay for such a survey? This leads us to the concept of expected payoff with perfect information (EPPI).

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Payoff With Perfect Information If we knew with certainty which state of nature would come to pass, we would would make our decisions accordingly. If our investor knew for sure that state of nature #1 (s 1 – interest rates rising) were to come to pass, he would invest in stocks in order to earn $150,000 (instead of investing in GICs [return = $100,000] which we calculated when we didn’t have perfect information). Back to our payoff table – what is the highest payoff for each state of nature (each row)?

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Payoff With Perfect Information We calculate our Expected Payoff With Perfect Information (EPPI) as any other expected value (i.e. use P(s i )’s) EPPI =.2(150,000) +.5(100,000) +.3(180,000) = $134,000 Acts: States of Nature: a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock s 1P=.20 $100,000-$50,000$150,000 s 2P=.50 $100,000$80,000$90,000 s 3P=.30 $100,000$180,000$40,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Value of Perfect Information… Without perfect information, our investor could put his money into a GIC and earn EMV* = $100,000 expected profit. Subtracting EMV* from EPPI leaves us with a quantity known as EVPI: the Expected Value of Perfect Information EVPI = EPPI – EMV* = $134,000 – $100,000 = $34,000

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Value of Perfect Information… Expected Value of Perfect Information EVPI = EPPI – EMV* = $134,000 – $100,000 = $34,000 The expected value of perfect information is $34,000 more than what our investor could earn without perfect information. Thus EVPI provides an upper bound for survey costs to improve the decision making information on hand.

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Decision Making w/ Additional Information Suppose our investor wants to improve his decision-making capabilities by hiring a consultant. IMC (the consultant), will, for a $5,000 fee, analyze the economic conditions and forecast the behavior of interest rates over the next 12 months. IMC details of their past successes forecasting interest rates. These are stated as conditional probabilities (also known as likelihood probabilities). Should we pay the $5,000 fee? Is it worth it to buy this data?

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Likelihood Probabilities… I 1 : IMC predicts the interest rates will increase I 2 : IMC predicts the interest rates will stay the same I 3 : IMC predicts the interest rates will decrease I 1 (predicts s 1 ) I 2 (predicts s 2 ) I 3 (predicts s 3 ) s1s1 P(I 1 |s 1 )=.60P(I 2 |s 1 )=.30P(I 3 |s 1 )=.10 s2s2 P(I 1 |s 2 )=.10P(I 2 |s 2 )=.80P(I 3 |s 2 )=.10 s3s3 P(I 1 |s 3 )=.10P(I 2 |s 3 )=.20P(I 3 |s 2 )=.70 E.g. when interest rates rose in the past, IMC correctly predicted this happening 60% of the time…

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Likelihood Probabilities… P(I 1 |s 1 ) =.60 When the interest rates actually increased (s 1 ) in the past, IMC correctly predicted this happening 60% of the time. That means 40% of the time they were wrong. 30% of the time they predicted stable rates and 10% of the time they predicted falling rates, hence the other likelihood probabilities: P(I 3 |s 1 ) =.10 (say) We refer to I i as an “indicator variable”.

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Terminology… Our original probabilities, P(s i ) are called prior probabilities — they were determined prior to any new information. We have likelihood probabilities, P(I i | s j ) from the company providing the information. What we’re interested in finding are posterior probabilities (a.k.a. revised probabilities), which are of the form P(s j | I i ) – what is the probability of a state of nature occurring, given that it was indicated by additional information. That is: what’s the probability the consultant will be right!

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Posterior Probabilities… We can compute posterior probabilities for each indicator variable in turn with this approach:  P(s j ) – prior probabilities; known.  P(I i | s j ) – likelihood probabilities; known. P(s j and I i ) = P(s j ) x P(I i | s j ) – from:  P(I i ) = sum of all P(s j and I i )’s P(s j | I i ) = P(s j and I i ) / P(I i ) – again, from Thus we have our posterior probability! (You may recall this as Bayes’ Law from earlier)

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Calculating Posterior Probabilities…(I 1 )  and  are given, we use to get sjsj  P(s j )  P(I 1 |s j ) P(s j and I 1 ) s1s (.20)(.60)=.12 s2s (.50)(.10)=.05 s3s (.30)(.10)=.03

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Calculating Posterior Probabilities…(I 1 ) Add up column to get the marginal probability for I 1 –  sjsj  P(s j )  P(I 1 |s j ) P(s j and I 1 ) s1s (.20)(.60)=.12 s2s (.50)(.10)=.05 s3s (.30)(.10)=.03  P(I 1 )=.20

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Calculating Posterior Probabilities…(I 1 ) Again, using divide the values in by  to get sjsj  P(s j )  P(I 1 |s j ) P(s j and I 1 ) P(s j |I 1 ) s1s (.20)(.60)=.12.12/.20=.60 s2s (.50)(.10)=.05.05/.20=.25 s3s (.30)(.10)=.03.03/.30=.15  P(I 1 )=.20 *repeat this process for indicators I 2 and I 3 …

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Posterior Probabilities… After the probabilities have been revised (i.e. made into posterior probabilities) we can use them in exactly the same way we used the prior probabilities — to calculate the expected monetary value of each act: EMV(a 1 ) =.60(100,000) +.25(100,000) +.15(100,000)= $100,000 EMV(a 2 ) =.60(-50,000) +.25(80,000) +.15(180,000)= $17,000 EMV(a 3 ) =.60(150,000) +.25(90,000) +.15(40,000)= $118,500 Thus, if IMC forecasts an increase in interest rates, the best course of action is act a 3 (since it has the highest EMV). *repeat this process for indicators I 2 and I 3 …

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Summary of the EVM Calculations… The action with the highest expected monetary value will change depending on what the consultant predicts… Acts: ICM Predicts a 1 GICa 2 Bonda 3 Stock I1I1 $100,000$17,000$118,500 I2I2 $100,000$76,550$91,150 I3I3 $100,000$145,770$56,760

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Preposterior Analysis… But we still haven’t answered the question – is it worth $5,000 to buy the consultant’s information or go it alone? If IMC predicts s 1, choose a 3, payoff = $118,500 If IMC predicts s 2, choose a 1, payoff = $100,500 If IMC predicts s 3, choose a 2, payoff = $145,770 We also know the marginal probabilities… P(I 1 ) =.20, P(I 2 ) =.52, P(I 3 ) =.28

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Monetary Value… We can calculate an expected monetary value with additional information as the weighted average of: the expected monetary values, and P(I 1 ), P(I 2 ), and P(I 3 ) as weights. Hence: EMV' =.20(118,500) +.52(100,000) +.28(145,770)= $116,516

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Monetary Value… The value of the consultant’s forecast is the delta between the expected monetary value with additional information (EMV') and the expected monetary value without additional information (EMV*). This difference is called the expected value of sample information and is denoted EVSI. Thus, EVSI = EMV' - EMV* = $116,516 - $100,000 = $16,516

Copyright © 2009 Cengage Learning Expected Value of Sample Information Since the expected value of sample information is greater than the cost of obtaining the information… $16,516 > $5,000 …we should advise our investor to hire IMC consultants and obtain an interest rate forecast before investing.