Nonprofits © Allen C. Goodman 2013 Short primer on nonprofit hospitals Q: How many nonprofit hospitals are there in the United States? A: In 2008, of.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Advertisements

Public Goods © Allen C. Goodman, 2002 Services in an Urban Setting Lots of services are provided through public funds Schools, police, fire protection,
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western What’s Important in Chapter 15 Sources of Monopolies (= Price Makers = Market.
PERFECT COMPETITION Economics – Course Companion
Voting for Public Goods (Fisher, Ch. 3) © Allen C. Goodman 2015.
NonProfit Firm Introduction to Nonprofits
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Monopsony Monopsony is a situation where there is one buyer – you have seen Monopoly, a case of one seller. Here we want to explore the impact on the.
1 Compare Monopoly to Competition. 2 Compare monopoly with competition The main results here are the ideas that ----1) a monopoly firm will charge a higher.
Here we see what a monopoly is and its revenue potential.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman Public Goods Most important factor is that everyone gets the same amount. We have to get some agreement as.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
Ch. 11: Perfect Competition.  Explain how price and output are determined in perfect competition  Explain why firms sometimes shut down temporarily and.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply
1 1 st degree price discrimination A form of Monopoly Power.
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
1 Economic Models of Discrimination Sendhil Mullainathan Economics 1035 Fall 2007.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Schools as Local Public Goods (Browse O’Sullivan, Ch. 17) © Allen C. Goodman 2006.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. its.
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Voting for Public Goods (Fisher, Ch. 3) © Allen C. Goodman 2009.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Classical Model. Learning Objectives Understand the determinants of output. Understand how output is distributed. Learn.
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Externalities © Allen C. Goodman 2009 Ideal Market Processes are desirable if … We accept the value judgment that “personal wants of individuals should.
Chapter 30: The Labor Market Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Supply & Costs of Production
... are the markets in the economy that help to match one person’s saving with another person’s investment. ... move the economy’s scarce resources.
Types of Market Structure
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
Input Demand: The Labor and Land Markets
10 Production and Costs A simple production function is:
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
1 Quiz next Thursday (March 15) Problem Set given next Tuesday (March 13) –Due March 29 Writing Assignment given next Tuesday (March 13) –Due April 3.
Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman Public Goods Most important factor is that everyone gets the same amount. We have to get some agreement as.
Chapter 22 Microeconomics Unit III: The Theory of the Firm.
Today n Perfect competition n Profit-maximization in the SR n The firm’s SR supply curve n The industry’s SR supply curve.
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
8.1 Costs and Output Decisions in the Long Run In this chapter we finish our discussion of how profit- maximizing firms decide how much to supply in the.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Nonprofits © Allen C. Goodman 2015 A short primer on nonprofit hospitals Q: How many nonprofit hospitals are there in the United States? A: In 2013,
UBEA 1013: ECONOMICS 1 CHAPTER 5: MARKET STRUCTURE: PERFECT COMPETITION 5.1 Characteristic 5.2 Short-run Decision: Profit Maximization 5.3 Short-run Decision:
8.1 Costs and Output Decisions in the Long Run In this chapter we finish our discussion of how profit- maximizing firms decide how much to supply in the.
Perfect Competition Overheads. Market Structure Market structure refers to all characteristics of a market that influence the behavior of buyers and sellers,
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
Chapter 14 Questions and Answers.
Pure (perfect) Competition Please listen to the audio as you work through the slides.
Economies of Scale Introduction and appropriation issues.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications
Models of Competition Part I: Perfect Competition
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition
Public Good Optimum © Allen C. Goodman 2015
Perfect Competition: Short Run and Long Run
AP Microeconomics Review #4
Main Topics for Free Responses Since 1995
AP MICRO REVIEW FINAL EXAM
Ch. 12: Perfect Competition.
Econ 100 Lecture 4.2 Perfect Competition.
Perfect Competition Econ 100 Lecture 5.4 Perfect Competition
AP Microeconomics Review #4
Presentation transcript:

Nonprofits © Allen C. Goodman 2013

Short primer on nonprofit hospitals Q: How many nonprofit hospitals are there in the United States? A: In 2008, of 5,815 community hospitals (excludes psychiatric and long-term), 2,923 (50.3%) were nonprofit, 1,105 (19.0%) were state/local, so less than 17% (982) were for profit. Q: Are Michigan hospitals nonprofit? A: Until recently, all of Michigan's 146 acute care facilities are nonprofit. The state has a few private, specialty hospitals for psychiatric and other special services, but they are not general hospitals. DMC was bought by Vanguard (now Tenet, which is nominally for-profit) but the concessions they are looking to get (tax relief for example) would make them look like non-profit hospitals.

Public Goods – Why? We go through several discussions. I'll reiterate the Weisbrod discussion regarding the public good. It's helpful to derive a public good equilibrium. My favorite way is a simple one where we have a social welfare function in which: W = W(U 1, U 2, U 3,...) = Weighted Σ U i for a community of individuals. We must decide how much public good G to make. In the pure sense, the public good is nonexcludable and nonrival. U i = U i (x i, G)- Each person gets some x i and all get G. X =  x i = f (G) f' < 0.

Public Goods So, optimize W =  w i U i (x i, G) + {  x i - f(G)}(1) w.r.t. x i  W/  x i = w i U i x + = 0.(2)  W/  G =  w i U i G - f' = 0(3) From (2) w i = - /U i x Insert into (3)  W/  G =  U i G /U i X + f' = 0(3) Factor out, and we get:  U i G /U i X + f' = 0   MRS GX = -f' = MRT Well-known Samuelson condition. w 1 = - /U 1 x w 2 = - /U 2 x w 3 = - /U 3 x Etc.

Optimum The condition above tells you the optimum. It doesn’t necessarily tell you how to get it. G X 1 0 ?X* 1 ?X* 2 G* 2

Optimum The condition above tells you the optimum. It doesn’t necessarily tell you how to get it. G X ?X* 1 ?X* 2 G*

Bread and Public Health Suppose that we live in a suburb. Suppose there are 5 residents. Each one earns $50,000. They can spend it on bread, or PH. 50 Bread PH Prefers Bread Prefers PH

Bread and Public Health (PH) They have to pick a tax level that each one of them will pay. If they decide on $10,000, each will pay $10, Bread PH Prefers Bread Prefers PH

Bread and PH Let’s add a few more “identical” people. 50 Bread PH We have five possible levels of “PH” p1p1 p2p2 p3p3 p4p4 p5p5

Bread and PH Alternatively, individuals 1-5 are willing to give up different amounts of bread to get PH resources. 50 Bread PH We have five different levels of taxes. p1p1 p2p2 p3p3 p4p4 p5p5

Suppose she promises p 5. Person 5 is happy (he didn’t want much). But everyone else wanted more. So politician loses election 4-1. How do we decide? Consider a politician. She has to win an election, and he has to get enough votes by promising the right amount of PH resources 50 Bread PH p1p1 p2p2 p3p3 p4p4 p5p5

How do we decide? 50 Bread PH Suppose she promises p 4. 1, 2, and 3 are happier because they’re getting closer to what they want. But he’ll still lose Suppose she now promises p 3. She’ll win the election because Persons 1 and 2 are happier yet, and Person 3 is happiest, he’s getting exactly what he wants. p1p1 p2p2 p3p3 p4p4 p5p5 This outcome will beat any other in a head-to-head contest.

If you don’t believe me Bread PH Suppose another politician promises p 2. Person 3 won’t be happy anymore because you’re providing MORE PH resources than he wants … so he’ll vote against it. KEY POINT !!! The median voter is decisive. Eq’m PH will be at p 3. Each voter will pay b 3 in taxes and get p b3b3 p1p1 p2p2 p3p3 p4p4 p5p5

What does median voter model say? If you have some number of jurisdictions, one can argue that the levels of public health, schools, fire protection, police protection are broadly consistent with consumer preferences. Is it perfect? –No, not all citizens vote. –If there are a lot of issues, the same citizen is not likely to be the median voter on every issue. When you get to the median voter result, there may still be some who would prefer that more be provided. They may choose to give additionally through nonprofit operations.

Non-Profit Institutions Why do we have them? –Weisbrod: People who want more public goods, beneficial externalities, want a means to provide it (e.g. hospitals, charity) –Hansmann: Contract failure (how do we evaluate hotels v. nursing homes). Provide quality and quantity. What kinds of motivations do they have, if profit isn’t one of them?

Quality and Quantity  = TR - TC = p (s, n) n - c (s, n) s = quality, n = quantity Setting  = 0: p (s, n) n = c (s, n) Quantity n $ p (s 1, n) c (s 1, n) p (s 2, n) c (s 2, n) p (s 3, n) c (s 3, n) n1n1 n3n3 n2n2

Quality and Quantity Differentiating fully p s n ds + p n n dn + p dn = c s ds + c n dn Collecting terms: (p + p n n - c n ) dn = (c s - p s n) ds [p(1+1/e) - c n ] dn = (c s - p s n) ds, where e is the elasticity of demand. ds/dn = [p(1+1/e) - c n ] / (c s - p s n) Assume that p s > 0, c s > 0, c n > 0, p n < 0. If we have linear demand curves then p n is constant.

Quality and Quantity ds/dn = [p(1+1/e) - c n ] / (c s - p s n) At low n, denominator is positive since p s n is small (or 0), and c s > 0. The numerator is positive since it reflects marginal revenue minus marginal costs. So ds/dn > 0. As n , denominator becomes negative, so we have (+)/ (-) < 0. So ds/dn < 0. Quantity n Quality s ds/dn > 0 ds/dn < 0

Quality and Quantity ds/dn = [p(1+1/e) - c n ] / (c s - p s n) At low s, c s is small. If we start with both small s and small n, then p s n may be small, and we may have a positive denominator. The numerator is positive since it reflect marginal revenue less marginal costs – here ds/dn > 0. If p s n is large, the denominator is negative. So ds/dn < 0. Quantity n Quality s ds/dn > 0 ds/dn < 0

Where do we end up? Suppose that nonprofit managers care only about quality (A). Quantity n Quality s A Suppose that nonprofit managers care only about quantity (B). B Suppose they care about both (C). C

Let’s maximize utility L = U(N,S) + [P (N,S) N - C (N, S)]  L/  N = U N + (P N N + P - C N ) = 0.(C.1)  L/  S = U S + (P S N - C S ) = 0.(C.2) Equating, we get: U N /U S = (P N N + P - C N ) / (P S N - C S ). or: U N /U S = [P(1+1/  ) – C N ]/(P S N - C S ). This, of course, gives us our tangency. Let's look at where U N = 0. This gives horizontal indifference curves, and suggests that P [1+(1/  )] = C N. This is the monopolist's cost mark-up. If U S = 0, we have vertical indifference curves, and we get a different optimum. A Phelps Observation

U N + (P N N + P - C N ) = 0. If we hold services constant, rearrange C.1 (previous slide) to get a first order condition vis-a-vis pricing, such that: P = (C N - U N / ) [  /(1+  )]. If U N = 0, then P = C N [  /(1+  )]. Normal monopoly markup. Generally, we would expect  ≤ -1. (Algebraically - Why ???). BUT: U N / = MU N /MU , implying that  = -P/(P – C N + U N / ) However, if the utility function of the hospital sufficiently emphasizes quantity of output through U N, then the hospital will willingly operate in the realm of inelastic demand (  approaches 0), and indeed might even willingly charge a negative price (bribe [or subsidize] people to use the service) under some situations. What if N is really important? A Phelps Observation

Pauly-Redisch What if there is a way to maximize profits/person? NARP = [p Q(M) - other factor costs]/M. Differentiate w.r.t. M  pQ'/M - pQ/M 2 = 0. pQ' = pQ/M Simply, MP = AP. In contrast, with open staff, physicians will enter up to level M 0. Number of staff physicians, M Physician Income Net Ave. Rev., N Supply curve for physicians S. S M* Y max MP M0M0

P-R v. Newhouse How does this relate to the Newhouse model? Go back and simply set up the optimization, where rather than 0 profits, the constraint is now:  = p (s, n) n - c (s, n), where  can be positive, if there is profit maximizing behavior. First order conditions are the same, because we've just put in a constant. Quantity n Quality s  = 0  = max So, Pauly-Reddisch hospital produces less.

With competition! Demand at any hospital will decrease At previous output they can’t cover costs. Hence output must fall Leads to 0 profits for all. Quantity n Quality s  = neg neg 0! Think of this as a hill on an island. If the water level rises, at some point, only the peak will be safe

Frech on Nonprofits Are they inefficient? If you put constraints on the amount of wealth managers can take out of ownership, you may lead to less efficient use of resources. Simple Model Nonpecuniary benefits n Wealth w U (w, n) n0n0 n1n1

Frech on Nonprofits 1 + (U n /U w ) (  n/  w) - /U w = 0. -(U n /U w ) = (  w/  n) (1 - /U w ). -(U n /U w )/ (  w/  n) = (1 - /U w ). Nonpecuniary benefits n Wealth w U (w, n) n0n0 n1n1

How do non-π and for-π co- exist? Look first at the “traditional” market model. D S Q $$ q mkt firm p* AC In the LR, the “marginal” firm will produce output q*. q* Lakdawalla-Philipson, 2006

How do non-π and for-π co- exist? Here, the for-π firm faces constraint, π ≥ 0 D S Q $$ q mkt firm p* AC q* Non-π firm faces constraint π + D ≥ 0. D = donations. Entry for non π Lakdawalla-Philipson, 2006

How do non-π and for-π co- exist? D S Q $$ q mktfirm p* AC q* Entry for non π For-π firms enter or leave as we move up and down industry supply curve. With enough non-π firms, the industry average cost minimizes at a low cost, driving out for-π firms. Capital to non-π provided at negative interest rates, since they do not require interest or principal payments. Lakdawalla-Philipson, 2006 Non  ’s 

How do non-π and for-π co- exist? D S Q $$ q mkt firm p* AC q* Entry for non π So, in the LR, the for- profits are the marginal firms, and their cost structure determines the market equilibrium price. Lakdawalla-Philipson, 2006 If there is regulation of hospital cost structures, the hospital effects are determined by the for- profit hospitals that enter and leave.

Feature: Why are RNs' Wages Higher in Nonprofit Nursing Homes? Holtmann and Idson (1993) explain why Registered Nurses (RNs) are paid higher wages by non-π than by for-π nursing homes. As described above, nonprofits are formed in response to patients' informational limitations in assessing quality. Specifically, because of patients' difficulties in distinguishing among nursing homes of varying quality, the market may fail to produce high quality nursing homes. RNs seem to receive higher wages in the non-π nursing home sector. Earlier studies (for example, Borjas, Frech and Ginsburg, 1983) attributed these differentials to the premise that since non-π do not distribute the residuals (the revenues less the costs), that they are less interested in minimizing the costs. Holtmann and Idson compare the earlier “property rights” hypothesis an alternative hypothesis, that non-π nursing pay higher wages to get higher quality.

wjwj Decomposing Differences Suppose we are looking at the impact of experience. We get two regressions. How do we analyze it. Experience Wage Rate Sector j Sector k Mean for Sector j is E j. Mean for Sector k is E k. Key -- Evaluate at mean. EjEj EkEk wkwk Coefficient effect Useful TechniqueFor Health Econ… and other things!

Some Math Mathematically, proceed as follows. Begin with sector j and sector k samples: ln W k =  i  ik z ik (1a) ln W j =  i  ij z ij (1b) Define  ik =  ij +   i ; and z ik = z ij +  z i. Then, ln W k - ln W j =  i  ik z ik -  ij z ij =  i (  ij +   i ) (z ij +  z i ) -  ij z ij (2) Gathering terms: ln W k - ln W j =  i   i z ij +  ij  z i +   i  z i.(3) The first term is a coefficient effect, holding z constant; the second is a attribute effect, holding  constant; the third is an interaction. Note + sign Watch Subscripts

However, if formulated alternatively, the decomposition leads to different component parts. Defining instead  ij =  ik -   i ; and z ij = z ik -  z i, then, ln W k - ln W j =  i  ik z ik -  ij z ij =  i  ik z ik - (  ik -   i ) (z ik -  z i )(2) Gathering terms: ln W k - ln W j =  i   i z ik +  ik  z i -   i  z i.(3) Although (3) and (3) are formally the same, the component parts differ due to the weights (z ik and  ik, rather than z ij and  ij ). To avoid weighting problems, add (3) and (3), and divide by 2. Some Math Note - sign ln W k - ln W j =  i   i z ij +  ij  z i +   i  z i.(3)

This yields: ln W k - ln W j =  i   i +  z i,(4) or ln (W k / W j ) =  i   i +  z i, and W k / W j = exp (  i   i ) exp (  i  z i ) where: = (  ik +  ij )/2, and(5a) = (z ik + z ij )/2.(5b) Term  i   i is the coefficient effect (where  ik varies between sectors); term  i  z i is the attribute effect (where z i varies between sectors). Some Math

Back to Holtmann and Idson They want to look at the differences in wages, and see how they vary between non-profit and for-profit nursing homes. If this is the case, then paying more for higher quality does not mean waste. Mean wage in non-profit homes = $9.95 Mean wage in for-profit homes = $9.72  2% difference. Table 1 –Seems that non-profit homes have nurses w/ more nursing experience, more degrees. Table 2 –Run some wage regressions Columns 2, 3 – Separate w/ a selection adjustment Selection seems to affect coefficients on for-profit homes. But not much on non-profit. Selection – 1 = for profit; 0 = non-profit. Experience and education seemed to select nurses into non-profit.

Wage Regressions Wage regressions Return to education and experience seems higher in non-profit setting. Non-profit homes value, and hence reward, both general and specific training and experience investments more than for-profit homes. On the other hand, returns to a Nursing M.A., and in general, to educational factors, are higher in the for- profit sector. Table 3 Experience and tenure effects help to explain higher observed wages in the nonprofit sector. Sectoral valuation, particularly facility size, tends to offset.

Comparisons The authors then compare the “quality” and the “property rights” hypotheses. According to the property rights hypothesis employees in nonprofit homes are paid higher wages than they could command in for-profit homes; this implies a higher return to their productivity related attributes than in for-profit homes. However, the authors’ methods show that workers in nonprofit facilities are generally compensated at a lower rate for their productivity-related attributes, and it is the fact that they have more of these attributes that leads to the wage differences. They view these distinctions as “strong evidence against the property-rights hypothesis that nonprofits are paying wasteful, inefficient wage premiums.”