Social Protection Design Issues Targeting and Conditionality Franziska Gassmann Bangkok, June 2012.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Linking Conditional Cash Transfers to Savings and Insurance A Promising Path for Poverty Reduction and Financial Inclusion? First Experiences from Latin.
Advertisements

The Latin American and Caribbean Perspective
1 Alternative measures of well-being Joint work by ECO/ELSA/STD.
External Financing for Health Care: Takemi Working Group Recommendations to G8 Ravi P. Rannan-Eliya ECOSOC Annual Ministerial Review – Regional Ministerial.
Treatment of social insurance schemes in the 2008 SNA Regional Seminar on Developing a Programme for the Implementation of the 2008 SNA and Supporting.
DECENTRALIZATION AND FINANCING OF SERVICES Gordana Matković Sofia, July 2007.
World Study on Poverty and Disparities in Childhood Panama, June 30 th and July 1 st, Childhood and Poverty in Brazil Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica.
RE-THINKING ACCOUNTABILITY Social Accountability and the Search for More Effective Public Expenditure Jeff Thindwa Participation and Civic Engagement.
1 Jacek Cukrowski Economic Development and Poverty Reduction Advisor, UNDP, Europe and the CIS Bratislava Regional Centre Aid for Trade (AfT) Needs Assessment.
Eric A. Hanushek Stanford University
1. 2 Why are Result & Impact Indicators Needed? To better understand the positive/negative results of EC aid. The main questions are: 1.What change is.
Cash transfers and childhood poverty in developing countries Armando Barrientos IDPM and CPRC The University of Manchester
Child Care Subsidy Data and Measurement Challenges 1 Study of the Effects of Enhanced Subsidy Eligibility Policies In Illinois Data Collection and Measurement.
The World Bank Human Development Network Spanish Impact Evaluation Fund.
The Institute for Economic and Social Research University of Indonesia
Explanation of slide: Logos, to show while the audience arrive.
Social Development: Proposed Strategic Directions for the World Bank
1 Activation Policies and Programs: A Social Assistance Perspective Kathy Lindert Sector Manager for Social Protection Europe and Central Asia October.
International Conference on Small States and Economic Resilience April 2007 Valetta, Malta Islands and Small States Institute Government intervention.
Identifying and profiling out of school populations – lessons from the UNICEF/UIS Out of School Children Initiative PISA for Development, Paris,
THE URBAN INSTITUTE Genevieve Kenney 2009 ACAP Medicaid Managed Care Policy Summit Hotel Monaco – Washington, DC July 15, 2009 Health Reform for Children:
Shaping UHC Policy for Post 2015: Opportunities & Risks Jeanette Vega MD, DrPH Managing Director of Health NHIS 10 Anniversary Conference Accra, November.
Giving all children a chance George Washington University April 2011 Jaime Saavedra Poverty Reduction and Equity THE WORLD BANK.
Conditional Cash Transfer penalties Vs. no penalties.
Rates of Return of Social Protection The case for non-contributory social transfers in Cambodia Franziska Gassmann Arusha, Tanzania – 17 December 2014.
IPDET Lunch Presentation Series Equity-focused evaluation: Opportunities and challenges Michael Bamberger June 27,
The impact of financial and economic crisis on the family and child in the Republic of Moldova and suggested policy responses November 10 th, 2009.
Implementation challenges of health financing policy reforms: experiences from Sub-Saharan Africa Peter Kamuzora Institute of Development Studies University.
Mexico’s Oportunidades: Self- Selection in Targeted Social Programs César Martinelli Professor of Economics, ITAM, Mexico City and Wilson Center/Comexi.
Conditional Cash Transfers for Improving Utilization of Health Services Health Systems Innovation Workshop Abuja, January 25 th -29 th, 2010.
Program Interventions for Food Security, Poverty Alleviation and Rural Development Suresh Babu October 26, 2011.
STRENGTHENING HEALTH SYSTEMS Anne Mills DCPP Editor London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine.
Chapter Three Health, Education, Poverty, and the Economy.
THE EFFECT OF INCOME SHOCKS ON CHILD LABOR AND CCTs AS AN INSURANCE MECHANISM FOR SCHOOLING Monica Ospina Universidad EAFIT, Medellin Colombia.
Ariel Fiszbein Chief Economist Human Development World Bank.
CONDITIONAL CASH TRANSFER PROGRAMS John Hoddinott IFPRI.
Module 9 ILO Game on!. Rules  6 groups  Each group answers 4 questions  And earns budget money to implement social protection in Coresia !  Time limit:
Social Protection and Children Enrique Delamonica UNICEF Mexico, August 2012.
Chapter 6 Equity and Income Distribution
Adjustment of benefit Size and composition of transfer in Kenya’s CT-OVC program Carlo Azzarri & Ana Paula de la O Food and Agriculture Organization.
CHILD SUPPORT PROGRAMME PAKISTAN. Hypothesis CSP Pilot Hypothesis: linking additional cash support to the FSP families with children would force them.
UNICEF Policy Social Protection - Overview of Social Safety Net Assessment Barbados, 04 June 2010 Social Protection Washington DC, 26 April 2010 UNICEF.
Efficiency, equity and feasibility of strategies to identify the poor: an application to premium exemptions under national health insurance in Ghana Caroline.
Global Social Floor: a Universal Social Pension Silvia Stefanoni Deputy Chief Executive and Director of Programmes HelpAge International.
Overview of targeting in Sub- Saharan Africa - the ongoing debate in the region Cash Transfers Workshop 21 st September 2010.
Equity issues in non-contributory transfer programs PEAM course May 2006, Washington DC Emil Tesliuc Sr Economist, HDNSP.
1 SSNs have an important role in addressing chronic poverty Do not create disincentive to work Spending for SSN is modest, subject to donor funding and.
HOW CAN SOCIAL SECURITY SCHEMES BE DESIGNED FOR LOW-INCOME COUNTRIES TO EFFECTIVELY PROVIDE FOR THE POOREST? Presentation to the International Conference”
Targeting of Public Spending Menno Pradhan Senior Poverty Economist The World Bank office, Jakarta.
Targeting Outcomes, Redux Coady, Grosh, and Hoddinott (forthcoming in World Bank Research Observer) Presentation at Reaching the Poor Conference Washington,
Distribution of income. Direct and Indirect Taxation Direct taxes are paid directly to the tax authority by the taxpayer: –Personal income taxes: on all.
Multi-dimensional poverty in the region: Grenada context Presented by: Honorable Delma Thomas Minister for the Ministry of Social Development and Housing.
Targeting and Public Expenditure Margaret Grosh. Themes General Issues –Goals –Measurement –Stylized facts Applications to social safety nets –Comparison.
SUPPLY SIDE POLICIES YOUSIF AL ZAROUNI. WHAT ARE SUPPLY SIDE POLICIES? Supply side policies are policies designed to improve the supply side potential.
The Social Protection Challenge in Middle income Countries
Decent Work for All ASIAN DECENT WORK DECADE Contribution of the SPF to employment and employability Valerie Schmitt, 29 September 2010.
Conditional Cash Transfer Pilot Upper Egypt. Background Currently Egypt has a welfare regime that is comprehensive and generous but which has some limitations.
Session 3: International experience: Impact of social protection programs Puja Vasudeva Dutta World Bank.
Financing social protection 17 July 2009 Michael Samson UNICEF/ IDS Course on Social Protection.
TARGETING SOCIAL PROTECTION Stephen Devereux Centre for Social Protection Institute of Development Studies (IDS) UNICEF Social Protection Training Course.
Evaluating Social Funds: A Cross- Country Analysis of Community Investments February 2004 Laura Rawlings, Lynne Sherburne-Benz, Julie Van Domelen.
UNICEF Social Protection Work an overview Show and Tell on Social Protection Bonn, 2011 UNICEF and social protection – Rationale: Equity approach Social.
Existing Programs to support development of micro-enterprise for informal economy workers and other poverty reduction programs 16 March 2012 Banyan tree.
The SPF-I: towards a joint position on Social Protection in Europe and Central Asia SHEILA MARNIE UNDP.
Promoting social cohesion in Korea. Social spending is low but increasing rapidly Rising income inequality and relative poverty and the factors behind.
UN system in the KYRGYZ REPUBLIC
Social security for Social Justice and a fair globalisation
Building Social Protection Systems:
Quality of government expenditure
An Examination of Social Protection Coverage Across Programs in Latin America Using Indicator By Ahmad Tipu.
Presentation transcript:

Social Protection Design Issues Targeting and Conditionality Franziska Gassmann Bangkok, June 2012

Outline Targeting Rationale Methods Costs versus benefits Evidence Conditionality Definition Rationale Evidence

Targeting… …is concerned with the allocation and distribution of resources and services (Spicker, 2005) …will be an issue wherever a subsidy/transfer is provided to one group and financed by others (WB, 2000) …is a means of increasing program efficiency by increasing the benefit that the poor can get within a fixed program budget (Coady et.al. 2004)

Why targeting? The demand for safety nets or transfers may be indefinite, though resources are usually limited Implies a need for targeting Although universal access may be the goal (e.g. health services, education), some targeting may be needed to Channel limited public resources where financing is a public/private mix E.g. subsidies for health insurance, fee waivers for education Equalize quality of services or ensure better quality services for the poor, demand-constrained households Gain political support

Social transfers for everybody or only a few? Objective of social protection To raise and/or protect the living standard of the poor with public spending Objective of policy maker design a policy that is effective and efficient Effective: achieves the objective, reaches the target group Efficient: there is no alternative policy that would have the same result at lower cost

How to identify the few?

Example: Burkina Faso a.High poverty rate with apparently rather equal distribution among the poor b.The poorest 10% have a consumption level of less than half of the other poor. This group is most in need of a transfer. 7 Source : Grosh et al., 2008

Targeting Methods Categorical/group Geographic Demographic (children, elderly, other) Individual assessments Means test (verified, not verified) Proxy means test Community-based Self-selection By purchase of commodity Work requirement Broad targeting Types of public spending

Means tests Income and/or asset-based Eligibility is assessed individually or per household or family Verified means-test: Information is verified against independent sources Simple means-test No independent verification Examples: industrialized countries, most Eastern Europe, Kyrgyz Republic, Mozambique, India, Sri Lanka Individual assessment

Proxy means tests Eligibility is assessed per household or family Test is based on multiple indicators at household level More easily observable than income Score determines whether household is eligible Needs: Detailed and regular analysis of household level data (e.g. HBS) Poverty needs to be clearly correlated with specific household characteristics High capacity needs Reduces error of inclusion Examples: Armenia, Chile, Mexico, Colombia, Indonesia Individual assessment

Community-based targeting Eligibility assessed individually or per household or family Presumption that local authorities are better able to identify the poor because they have more accurate information Use of existing structures or newly established ones With or without central directives Little evidence on effectiveness Possible drawbacks: Overburden local authorities Capturing by local elites, reinforcing existing differences Conflict over resources Example: Albania, Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Zambia Individual assessment

Categorical/group targeting Eligibility is assessed per individual, household or family characteristics that are Easy to observe Hard to manipulate Correlated with poverty Age, gender, disability, work status, … Lower administrative needs Examples: family benefits, social pensions; many pilot programs start in geographically selected target districts Categorical/group

Categorical targeting using demographic indicators 13 Example: targeting children < 5 years

Categorical targeting based on geographical indicators Poverty map of extreme poverty in Panama (source : poverty map 2003, MEF) 14

Self-targeting Universal coverage, but design discourages the non-poor to apply Hard physical labor Very low wage Quality of good (e.g. broken rice) Often achieved by imposing a cost to participation Work requirement Having long queues Attaching a stigma Example: Argentina, Bolivia, India Self-selection

Summarizing… Frequently a combination of targeting methods – hybrid forms The alternative to narrow targeting Universal access to a benefit Broad targeting

Principle: some categories of public spending matter more to the poor than to other categories Social services Primary education Health care centers The case for broad targeting: Better health, education, access to clean water or basic physical infrastructure raise well-being of the poor higher productivity, higher income Can be expensive, lot of leakage

Subsidies per Capita, Indonesia Source: van de Walle, 1998 Broad targeting

Costs versus benefits Is targeting an effective and efficient policy instrument to reduce poverty?

Source : Devereux Initial welfare distribution

Case 1 – Universal Transfer Source : Devereux

Case 2 – Perfect targeting

From a purely theoretical perspective… …targeting the poorest is the most effective and efficient option in reducing the poverty gap …targeting achieves the biggest reduction of the poverty gap taking into account budget constraints

Is this plausible? Targeting comes at a cost Human rights Stigmatization of the poor Political economy Benefits of targeting versus its costs

Targeting comes at a cost

For example: Administrative costs Source: Grosh, et al. 2008

Easy vs. hard-to-verify income

Targeting: Trade-off between costs and efficiency Type I errors: eligible families are excluded Exclusion error (reduced horizontal efficiency) Type II errors: non-eligible families are included Inclusion error (reduced vertical efficiency) The aim to reduce Type II errors tends to increase Type I errors Higher targeting costs are acceptable if they lead to sufficiently better targeting (Coady et.al. 2004)

Errors of Inclusion Source: Grosh et.al. 2008

Potential reasons for targeting errors Targeting methods not appropriate given the country context and nature of poverty Insufficient financing limits inclusion of all the poor Poor do not take up benefit Lack of information High transaction costs High opportunity costs Stigma

Evidence of targeting effectiveness

Targeting Methods – Comparison Study by Coady, Grosh & Hoddinott (2004) 122 programs from 48 countries 49 cash transfers, 18 near cash, 12 food transfers 18 food-subsidy and 5 non-food subsidy programs 20 public work programs

Targeting Performance by Targeting Method Source: Coady et.al., 2004

Main findings Targeting can work… Mean = 1.25, top-10 between 2 and 4 …but not always One quarter of programs is regressive No clearly preferred method Within method variation of 80% Weak ranking Means, geographic, work requirement Proxy means, community based, to children To elderly, community bidding, commodities Context, program design and implementation matter

Conclusion Targeting is never perfect! Trade-off between costs and benefits How much imperfection is tolerable? Targeting effectiveness depends on country context and implementation Are programs for the poor poor programs? Political economy should not be underestimated People underestimate how difficult it is to target the poor (van de Walle, 1998)

Conditionality

Conditionality – a first glance Definition of conditionality: conditionality asks for some form of behavioral compliance in exchange for the money in order to continue receiving support beneficiaries have to meet certain conditions that are spelled out by the program Frequent conditions Education : enrolment, attendance of 85% Health: regular check-ups for children 0-5, vaccinations, assisted birth, preventive health care measures

One term with multiple meanings

There are many CCT programs worldwide

But they differ substantially… Exemptions Majority of programs, no official exemptions, at times indirect exemptions In Kenya & Tanzania those without access are exempt In Jamaica, children with disabilities are exempt Coverage Non-compliance affects the entire transfer in 40% of CCTs vs. 13% of CCTs where only a supplementary grant is affected Objective 22% of all 41 CCTs reviewed have an exclusive health or education focus Expected performance In 67% of all CCTs conditionality is output- related Passing grade in Cambodia; single repetition in Turkey Monitoring No monitoring in Ecuador Light monitoring in Pakistan, Bangladesh & Cambodia More intensive monitoring in Brazil, Chili, Mexico & Kenya Enforcement Punitive in Mexico & Jamaica Developmental in Brazil & Chili

Why opt for conditionality?

Argument 1 : Private efficiency Households under-invest in the education and health of their children from a private point of view Parents are not always well informed about the (future) value of education Parents (or at least one of them) do not always behave altruistically towards their children Parents have self-control problem and are willing to sacrifice future for present consumption Parents of low-income households tend to be more risk- averse and shy away from investments in education Conditionality could guide beneficiaries, encourage them to invest and function as a self-control device

Argument 2: Social efficiency Households under-invest in the education and health of their children from a social point of view They do not factor in positive side effects from educating children or from preventive health care measures They do not consider future social costs of under- investment such as increased crime, lost labor contribution and less informed political participation Conditionality can encourage households to increase their investments

Argument 3 : Political economy Social cash transfers often have difficulties in securing long- term political support due to worries about Beneficiaries not knowing how to spend the money and misusing this flexibility Beneficiaries becoming dependent and not being interested in improving their situation Not having any control over the impact of a rather cost- intensive intervention Conditionality can make a social cash transfer program more attractive by controlling the use of funds, giving beneficiaries an extra nudge and guaranteeing a certain impact. Redistribution may be better acceptable if beneficiaries behave accordingly (condition).

Argument 4 : Empowerment Beneficiary households of social transfers and/or individual members are often in an inferior position Government support is often presented as charity as opposed to an entitlement The use of the transfer is often decided by the household head without any further consultation Conditionality can give beneficiaries / individual household members a negotiation device and allow them to exercise their rights

Argument 5 : Equity Targeting is bound to be imperfect and costly. Households who do not qualify for the transfers apply and benefit nevertheless (inclusion error) Trying to reduce inclusion errors can have a negative impact on exclusion errors and end up being costly Conditionality can make a program unattractive to those who dont quality and therefore serve as a screening device

Evidence ?

Evidence on behavioral changes Few (long-term) studies on the impact of conditionality at household level In the past, the good performance of a conditional cash transfer program was erroneously cited as evidence of the value added of conditionality The impact varies greatly from a magnifier effect of conditionality of 16 times (Mexico) to no impact at all in Malawi

Evidence on the political economy Very little evidence on the political effects A study by Taylor-Gooby (2001) confirms the rising popularity of activation / conditionality in the Western World Conditionality was seen as an important tool by politicians in Brazil to guarantee impact, avoid dependency; better monitoring reduced however mayors chances of reelection Mixed results for Zambia: popularity of conditionality as such but unpopularity of consequences of conditionality

Evidence on empowerment Very little but anecdotal evidence Adato et al (2002) show that the trainings women had to attend increased their confidence & awareness Molyneux (2006) & Bradshaw (2008) hint at disempowering effects with conditionality confining women to their female duties & suggestion that they were bad mothers before Zambia Individuals with a partner unanimously confirmed that conditionality had helped them to negotiate household expenditure with the partner

Evidence on equity Limited evidence Alvarez et al (2008) find that conditionality improved the targeting effectiveness in Mexico In Zambia, a monthly transfer of 10 US$ wouldnt have discouraged the better off from participating In rural areas in Zambia, the better off even had a greater likelihood of participating than the poorer segments Self-assessedYesNo Very poor10%90% Poor13%87% Middle11%89% Upper middle0%100% Rich0%100%

Conditionality may lead to inefficiency Impact inefficiency Conditionality in one area can negatively effect behavior in another area Households can perceive conditionality as lack of trust and get demotivated Design inefficiency Conditionality does not address actual/real problem Implementation inefficiency Direct/indirect administrative costs Capacity constraints Promotion of corruption

How to decide? Source: Fiszbein & Shady, 2009

1.The rationale behind conditionality is to optimize household behavior, empower beneficiaries, increase the political attractiveness of social cash transfer programs and improve the targeting effectiveness 2.The evidence base on which conditionality rests, in particular for the empowerment, political economy and equity effects is rather thin 3.Conditionally also has the potential to introduce a number of impact, design and implementation inefficiencies that lower the cost- effectiveness of a social cash transfer program. 4.Prior to deciding for or against conditionality, it is important to analyze the potential of conditionality to effect any positive changes, the costs and inefficiencies associated with it as well as the capacity of a country to successfully manage the process Key messages: Conditionality

Recommended reading Targeting: Grosh, M. et.al. (2008), For Protection and Promotion. The Design and Implementation of Social Safety Nets, The World Bank, Washington DC.: chapter 4 (Targeting) /For_Protection_and_Promotion-Ch4.pdf /For_Protection_and_Promotion-Ch4.pdf SAMSON, M., VAN NIEKERK, I. & MAC QUENE, K Designing and Implementing Social Transfer Programmes, Cape Town, Economic Policy Research Institute. Conditionality Fiszbein, A. and N. Shady (2009), Conditional Cash Transfers. Reducing present and future poverty, The World Bank, Washington DC. de Janvry, A. and E. Sadoulet (2005). Conditional cash transfer programs for child human capital development: Lessons derived from experience in Mexico and Brazil. GRADE 25th anniversary Conference, "Investigación, Politicas y Desarrollo". Lima, Peru. Available from: Standing, G. (2007). Conditional Cash Transfers: Why Targeting and Conditionalities Could Fail. One Pager No. 47. Brasilia, Brazil, International Poverty Centre. United Nations Development Programme. Available from: povertycentre.org/pub/IPCOnePager47.pdfhttp:// povertycentre.org/pub/IPCOnePager47.pdf Schuering, E. (2010), Conditions, conditionality, conditionalities, responsibilities – finding common ground, MGSoG Working Paper, 2010WP014, Maastricht Graduate School of Governance, Maastricht.