Derivatives to Business and Economics. Our textbook tells us that business analysts and economists have increasingly turned to mathematical models to.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Advertisements

Profit maximization.
Introduction.
1 Applications of Extrema OBJECTIVE  Solve maximum and minimum problems using calculus. 6.2.
9 Import Tariffs and Quotas under Imperfect Competition 1
Find equation for Total Revenue Find equation for Marginal Revenue
Optimization using Calculus
Chapter 9 – Profit maximization
Application Of Derivatives To Business And Economics
C hapter 11 Price and Output in Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition, and Perfect Competition © 2002 South-Western.
1 Labor Demand and Supply. 2 Overview u In the previous few chapters we have focused on the output decision for firms. Now we want to focus on the input.
What Is A Monopoly? A monopoly firm is the only seller of a good or service with no close substitutes Key concept is notion of substitutability Hall &
Monopoly, setting quantity
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Chapter 9 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Profit Maximization and Supply.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Optimal Decisions using Marginal Analysis
Marginal Functions in Economics
Economics 101 – Section 5 Lecture #15 – March 4, 2004 Chapter 7 How firms make decisions - profit maximization.
Chapter 2 Functions and Graphs
Types of Market Structure
Chapter 2 Functions and Graphs Section 1 Functions.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
Section 12.1 Techniques for Finding Derivative. Constant Rule Power Rule Sum and Difference Rule.
Section 3.5 Find the derivative of g (x) = x 2 ln x.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
Chapter 1 Linear Functions
WELCOME TO THETOPPERSWAY.COM.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 12 Further Applications of the Derivative.
Chapter 10-Perfect Competition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2015 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Section 12.2 Derivatives of Products and Quotients
The mean value theorem and curve sketching
Economics Chapter 5 Supply
Monopoly ETP Economics 101. Monopoly  A firm is considered a monopoly if...  it is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not have close.
Business and Economic Applications. Summary of Business Terms and Formulas  x is the number of units produced (or sold)  p is the price per unit  R.
BY DR LOIZOS CHRISTOU OPTIMIZATION. Optimization Techniques.
Summary C(x) is the cost function C(x)/x is the average cost C’(x) is the marginal cost p(x) is the demand function which is the price per unit if we sell.
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly 13 CHAPTER.
Goldstein/Schneider/Lay/Asmar, CALCULUS AND ITS APPLICATIONS, 11e – Slide 1 of 107 § 2.7 Applications of Derivatives to Business and Economics.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 3 Applications of Differentiation.
MAT Applied Calculus 3.4 – Marginal Functions in Economics
Applied Economics for Business Management Lecture #8.
BUSSINESS MATHEMATICS
SECTION 1.6 MATHEMATICAL MODELS: CONSTRUCTING FUNCTIONS MATHEMATICAL MODELS: CONSTRUCTING FUNCTIONS.
Managerial Economics Managerial Economics = economic theory + mathematical eco + statistical analysis.
Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles And Applications, Market Structure Sellers want to sell at the highest possible price Buyers want to buy.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
1.2 Linear functions & Applications. Linear Function f defined by (for real numbers m and b) x=independent variable y=dependent variable.
Chapter 22: The Competitive Firm Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Chapter 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand 1 of 52 Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld,
And Unit 3 – Theory of the Firm. 1. single seller in the market. 2. a price searcher -- ability to set price 3. significant barriers to entry 4. possibility.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Monopoly ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
1 Chapter 11 Labor Markets Key Concepts Key Concepts Summary Summary Practice Quiz Internet Exercises Internet Exercises ©2000 South-Western College Publishing.
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved. 2 Differentiation.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
Economic Definitions Profit = Revenue – Cost P(x) = R(x) – C(x) Assume the cost of producing x radios is C(x) =.4x 2 +7x + 95 dollars. A. Find the cost.
Pure (perfect) Competition Please listen to the audio as you work through the slides.
Monopoly 15. Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. it is the sole seller of its product. its product does.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Copyright © 2015, 2011, and 2008 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 1 Functions and Graphs Section 1 Functions.
Lecture 3:Elasticities. 2 This lecture covers: Why elasticities are useful Estimating elasticities Arc formula Deriving elasticities from demand functions.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Competition.
Chapter 2 Functions and Graphs
Chapter 2 Functions and Graphs
Economic Definitions Profit = Revenue – Cost P(x) = R(x) – C(x)
Copyright © Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.
3.10 Business and Economic Applications
Chapter 25 Monopoly Key Concept: Monopolist chooses y so that p(y)+p’(y)y=MC(y). This is inefficient because for efficiency, the comparison should be p(y)=MC(y).
Presentation transcript:

Derivatives to Business and Economics

Our textbook tells us that business analysts and economists have increasingly turned to mathematical models to help them describe what is happening, predict the effects of various policy alternatives, and choose reasonable courses of action. The derivative is one of the mathematical tools employed by economists and business analysts. Section 2.7 is devoted to illustrating a few of the many applications of the derivative to the problems of business and economics.

Applications in our textbook are centered around the theory of the firm. We will study the activity of a business or industry and restrict our analysis to a time period during which background conditions (supplies, wage rates, etc.) are fairly constant.

There are three main functions we will work with in this section C(x) = cost of producing x units of a product R(x) = revenue generated by selling x units of a product P(x) = R(x) – C(x) = the profit (or loss) generated by producing and selling x units of the product. NOTE: These functions are often only defined for nonnegative integers. Why?

Often, these functions give rise to a set of discrete points on a graph.

In studying these functions, economists usually assume that C(x) is defined for all values of x and draw a smooth curve through the points. If we assume that C(x) has a smooth graph, then we can use the tools of calculus (derivatives) to study it.

Suppose that the cost function for a manufacturer is given by C(x) = (10 -6 )x x 2 +5x dollars (a)Describe the behavior of the marginal cost. (b)Sketch the graph of C(x) For (a), recall that marginal is the word for derivative in business and economics. For (b), we can get information about the graph from calculating first and second derivatives.

In sketching the graph of the marginal cost y = C’(x), we can use y’ = C’’(x) to provide us with information about the graph. We can tell that the marginal cost graph will be a parabola that opens upward. How?

The relative minimum point of the marginal cost graph can be discovered by examining y’ = C’’(x) = 0. Solving C’’(x)= (x-1000) = 0 for x uncovers a horizontal tangent at x = The associated value of y in the marginal cost graph is calculated by (3)(10 -6 )(1000) (1000) + 5 = 3 – = 2

The graph of the marginal cost function.

Since the graph of the marginal cost function never reaches 0, then there are no relative extreme points in the graph of the cost function. We also note that the graph of C’(x) is never negative. What does this tell us about the graph of C(x)? What else can we tell about the graph of C(x) from looking at the graph of C’(x)?

The graph of the cost function.

Revenue Functions

R(x) is the revenue received from the sale of x units of some commodity. We call R’(x) the marginal revenue. Economists use marginal revenue to measure the rate of increase in revenue per unit increase in sales. If x units are sold at a price p per unit, the total revenue R(x) is given by R(x) = xp

Some economic concepts for revenue If a firm is small and has many competitors, then its sales have little effect on the market price of its commodity. The price is then constant as far as the one firm is concerned, and the marginal revenue R’(x) equals the price p.

However, if the firm’s production of a commodity has a significant impact on the availability of the commodity (for example, when the firm has a monopoly), then an interesting problem arises. Consumers will purchase more of the commodity when the price is low, and fewer units when the price is high. Let f(x) be the highest price per unit at which all x units can be sold to customers. Since consumers will buy less when the price increases, the graph of f(x) will be decreasing.

The demand equation p = f(x) determines the total revenue function. If a firm wants to sell x units, the highest price it can set is f(x) dollars per unit. The revenue function becomes R(x) = xp = xf(x)

The concept of the demand curve applies to an entire industry, as well as a single monopolistic firm. In this case, many producers offer the same commodity for sale. If x denotes the total output of the industry, then f(x) is the market price per unit of output and xf(x) is the total revenue earned by the industry from the sale of x units.

The demand equation for a certain product is p = 6 – ½ x dollars Find the level of production that maximizes revenue.

We want to begin by developing our revenue function R(x). R(x) = xp so The marginal revenue is given by R’(x) Note that R(x) is the graph of a parabola that opens downward. How do we know?

We use R’(x) = 0 to identify the relative maximum point. 6 –x = 0 x = 6 The corresponding value of y is

The graph of R(x) appears as

Profit Functions

Once we know the cost function C(x) and the revenue function R(x), we can compute the profit function P(x). P(x) = R(x) – C(x)

Suppose that the demand equation for a monopolist is p = x and the cost function is C(x) = 50x + 10,000. Find the value of x that maximizes the profit and determine the corresponding price and total profit for this level of production.

We need to construct the profit function P(x) = R(x) – C(x). C(x) has been given, so we compute R(x) using the demand equation Then, our profit function is The graph of P(x) is a parabola that opens downward. How do we know?

The relative extreme point of P(x) will be the point at which profit is the highest. We need to compute the marginal profit function P’(x), and solve P’(x) = 0 for x. Solving P’(x) = 0, we have -.02(x-2500) = 0 which yields x = 2500

If 2500 units are produced, the profit would be P(2500) = -.01(2500) (2500) – 10,000 = 52, 500 dollars The highest price at which the 2500 units can be sold is P = (2500) = 100 – 25 = 75 dollars Answer: Produce 2500 units and sell them at $75 per unit. The profit will be $52, 500.

Setting Production Levels

Suppose that a firm has cost function C(x) and revenue function R(x). In a free-enterprise economy, the firm will set production x in such a way as to maximize the profit function P(x) = R(x) – C(x). If P(x) has its maximum at x = a, then P’(a) = 0. It follows that since P’(x) = R’(x) – C’(x) that R’(a) – C’(a) = 0 or R’(a) = C’(a) Thus profit is maximized at the production level for which marginal revenue equals marginal cost.