Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices By: Marco A. G. Dias (Petrobras) & Katia M. C. Rocha.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Overview of Quantitative Finance and Risk Management Research By Dr. Cheng-Few Lee Distinguished Professor, Rutgers University, USA Distinguished Professor,
Advertisements

A Multi-Phase, Flexible, and Accurate Lattice for Pricing Complex Derivatives with Multiple Market Variables.
Option Valuation The Black-Scholes-Merton Option Pricing Model
Chapter 25 Risk Assessment. Introduction Risk assessment is the evaluation of distributions of outcomes, with a focus on the worse that might happen.
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 6 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull The Black-Scholes- Merton Model Chapter 13.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
MGT 821/ECON 873 Volatility Smiles & Extension of Models
Pricing Derivative Financial Products: Linear Programming (LP) Formulation Donald C. Williams Doctoral Candidate Department of Computational and Applied.
Derivatives Inside Black Scholes
Chapter 20 Basic Numerical Procedures
Options and Speculative Markets Introduction to option pricing André Farber Solvay Business School University of Brussels.
CHAPTER 13 Measurement of Interest-Rate Risk for ALM What is in this Chapter? INTRODUCTION RATE-SHIFT SCENARIOS SIMULATION METHODS.
Spot Price Models. Spot Price Dynamics An examination of the previous graph shows several items of interest. –Price series exhibit spikes with seasonal.
Ch. 19 J. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivatives Zvi Wiener Framework for pricing derivatives.
Options and Speculative Markets Inside Black Scholes Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles.
Binnenlandse Francqui Leerstoel VUB Black Scholes and beyond André Farber Solvay Business School University of Brussels.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
Chapter 21. Stabilization policy with rational expectations
Derivatives Introduction to option pricing André Farber Solvay Business School University of Brussels.
3.1 Determination of Forward and Futures Prices Chapter 3.
Diffusion Processes and Ito’s Lemma
JUMP DIFFUSION MODELS Karina Mignone Option Pricing under Jump Diffusion.
Opportunity Engineering Harry Larsen The Boeing Company SCEA 2000 Conference.
Valuing Stock Options:The Black-Scholes Model
11.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th Edition © 1999 by John C. Hull The Black-Scholes Model Chapter 11.
BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL Chapters 7 and 8.
Ewa Lukasik - Jakub Lawik - Juan Mojica - Xiaodong Xu.
IPEA - Institute for Applied Economic Research of Brazilian Government REAL OPTIONS IN ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMY “Environmental Investment Decisions - The.
18.1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th edition © 2002 by John C. Hull Numerical Procedures Chapter 18.
REAL OPTIONS IN PETROLEUM Case Studies in Exploration & Production By: Marco Antônio Guimarães Dias Petrobras, Brazil New Approaches to Value Analysis:
Option Valuation Lecture XXI. n What is an option? In a general sense, an option is exactly what its name implies - An option is the opportunity to buy.
A Step-by-Step Approach to Improving Investment Decisions and Asset Valuation Real Options in Exploration & Production of Petroleum By: Marco Antônio Guimarães.
HJM Models.
Chapter 13 Wiener Processes and Itô’s Lemma
More on Models and Numerical Procedures Chapter :13.
1 Derivatives & Risk Management: Part II Models, valuation and risk management.
By: Marco Antonio Guimarães Dias  Internal Consultant by Petrobras, Brazil  Doctoral Candidate by PUC-Rio Visit the first real options website:
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model Yuna Rhee Seyong Park Robert C. Merton (1971) [Journal.
Chapter 26 More on Models and Numerical Procedures Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull
By: Marco Antonio Guimarães Dias  Internal Consultant by Petrobras, Brazil  Doctoral Candidate by PUC-Rio Investment.
1 MGT 821/ECON 873 Numerical Procedures. 2 Approaches to Derivatives Valuation How to find the value of an option?  Black-Scholes partial differential.
Chp.5 Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous Time Model Hai Lin Department of Finance, Xiamen University.
Visual FAQ’s on Real Options Celebrating the Fifth Anniversary of the Website: Real Options Approach to Petroleum Investments
By: Marco Antonio Guimarães Dias  Internal Consultant by Petrobras, Brazil  Doctoral Candidate by PUC-Rio Visit the first real options website:
Basic Numerical Procedures Chapter 19 1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2008.
Basic Numerical Procedure
A Cursory Introduction to Real Options Andrew Brown 5/2/02.
1 MathFinance Colloquium Frankfurt, June 1 st, 2006 Exploring the Limits of Closed Pricing Formulas in the Black and Scholes.
Chapter 20 Brownian Motion and Itô’s Lemma.
Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices Workshop on Real Options in Petroleum and Energy September.
Option Pricing Models: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model aka Black – Scholes Option Pricing Model (BSOPM)
© K.Cuthbertson, D. Nitzsche FINANCIAL ENGINEERING: DERIVATIVES AND RISK MANAGEMENT (J. Wiley, 2001) K. Cuthbertson and D. Nitzsche Lecture Asset Price.
Chapter 8 Stock Valuation (Homework: 4, 13, 21 & 23)
CIA Annual Meeting LOOKING BACK…focused on the future.
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter B-S-M model is used to determine the option price of any underlying stock. They believed that stock follow.
Chapter 19 Monte Carlo Valuation. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Monte Carlo Valuation Simulation of future stock.
Real Options Stochastic Processes Prof. Luiz Brandão 2009.
Real Option Valuation Lecture XXX.  Moss, Pagano, and Boggess. “Ex Ante Modeling of the Effect of Irreversibility and Uncertainty on Citrus Investments.”
By: Marco Antonio Guimarães Dias Petrobras and PUC-Rio, Brazil Visit the first real options website: Overview of Real Options.
OPTIONS PRICING AND HEDGING WITH GARCH.THE PRICING KERNEL.HULL AND WHITE.THE PLUG-IN ESTIMATOR AND GARCH GAMMA.ENGLE-MUSTAFA – IMPLIED GARCH.DUAN AND EXTENSIONS.ENGLE.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model 1. The Stock Price Assumption Consider a stock whose price is S In a short period of time of length  t, the.
Chapter 13 Wiener Processes and Itô’s Lemma 1. Stochastic Processes Describes the way in which a variable such as a stock price, exchange rate or interest.
Chapter 14 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
CS 179 Lecture 17 Options Pricing.
Mathematical Finance An Introduction
The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Valuing Stock Options: The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Chapter 15 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
Presentation transcript:

Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices By: Marco A. G. Dias (Petrobras) & Katia M. C. Rocha (IPEA). 3 rd Annual International Conference on Real Options - Theory Meets Practice Wassenaar/Leiden, The Netherlands June 1999

Presentation Highlights u Paper has two new contributions: l Extendible maturity framework for real options l Use of jump-reversion process for oil prices u Presentation of the model: l Petroleum investment model l Concepts for options with extendible maturities è Thresholds for immediate investment and for extension l Jump + mean-reversion process for oil prices è Topics: systematic jump, discount rate, convenience yield l C++ software interactive interface l Base case and sensibility analysis è Alternative timing policies for Brazilian National Agency l Concluding remarks

E&P Is a Sequential Options Process u Drill the pioneer? Wait? Extend? u Revelation, option-game: waiting incentives Oil/Gas Success Probability = p Expected Volume of Reserves = B Revised Volume = B’ u Appraisal phase: delineation of reserves u Technical uncertainty: sequential options u Develop? “Wait and See” for better conditions? Extend the option? u Developed reserves. Model: reserves value proportional to the oil prices, V = qP l q = economic quality of the developed reserve u Other (operational) options: not included Primary focus of our model: undeveloped reserves

Economic Quality of a Developed Reserve u Concept by Dias (1998): q =  V/  P l q = economic quality of the developed reserve l V = value of the developed reserve ($/bbl) l P = current petroleum price ($/bbl) u For the proportional model, V = q P, the economic quality of the reserve is constant. We adopt this model. l The option charts F x V and F x P at the expiration (t = T) F VD 45 o tg 45 o = 1 F PD/q  tg  = q = economic quality V = q. P F(t=T) = max (q P  D, 0) F(t=T) = max (NPV, 0) NPV = V  D

The Extendible Maturity Feature T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period [Develop Now] or [Wait and See] [Develop Now] or [Extend (pay K)] or [Give-up (Return to Govern)] T I M E PeriodAvailable Options [Develop Now] or [Wait and See] [Develop Now] or [Give-up (Return to Govern)]

Options with Extendible Maturity u Options with extendible maturities was studied by Longstaff (1990) for financial applications u We apply the extendible option framework for petroleum concessions. l The extendible feature occurs in Brazil and Europe l Base case of 5 years plus 3 years by paying a fee K (taxes and/or additional exploratory work). l Included into model: benefit recovered from the fee K è Part of the extension fee can be used as benefit (reducing the development investment for the second period, D 2 ) l At the first expiration, there is a compound option (call on a call) plus a vanilla call. So, in this case extendible option is more general than compound one

Extendible Option Payoff at the First Expiration u At the first expiration (T 1 ), the firm can develop the field, or extend the option, or give-up/back to govern u For geometric Brownian motion, the payoff at T 1 is:

Poisson-Gaussian Stochastic Process u We adapt the Merton (1976) jump-diffusion idea but for the oil prices case: l Normal news cause only marginal adjustment in oil prices, modeled with a continuous-time process l Abnormal rare news (war, OPEC surprises,...) cause abnormal adjustment (jumps) in petroleum prices, modeled with a discrete time Poisson process u Differences between our model and Merton model: l Continuous time process: mean-reversion instead the geometric Brownian motion (more logic for oil prices) l Uncertainty on the jumps size: two truncated normal distributions instead the lognormal distribution l Extendible American option instead European vanilla l Jumps can be systematic instead non-systematic

Stochastic Process Model for Oil Prices u Model has more economic logic (supply x demand) l Normal information causes smoothing changes in oil prices (marginal variations) and means both: è Marginal interaction between production and demand (inventory levels is an indicator); and è Depletion versus new reserves discoveries (the ratio of reserves/production is an indicator) l Abnormal information means very important news: è In a short time interval, this kind of news causes a large variation (jumps) in the prices, due to large variation (or expected large variation) in either supply or demand u Mean-reversion has been considered a better model than GBM for commodities and perhaps for interest rates and for exchange rates. Why? l Economic logic; term structure of futures prices; volatility of futures prices; spot prices econometric tests

Nominal Prices for Brent and Similar Oils ( ) u We see oil prices jumps in both directions, depending of the kind of abnormal news: jumps-up in 1973/4, 1978/9, 1990, 1999 (?); and jumps-down in 1986, 1991, 1998(?) Jumps-up Jumps-down

Equation for Mean-Reversion + Jumps u The stochastic equation for the petroleum prices (P) Geometric Mean-Reversion with Random Jumps is:  The jump size/direction are random:  ~ 2N l In case of jump-up, prices are expected to double l In case of jum-down, prices are expected to halve ; So,

Mean-Reversion and Jumps for Oil Prices u The long-run mean or equilibrium level which the prices tends to revert P is hard to estimate l Perhaps a game theoretic model, setting a leader-follower duopoly for price-takers x OPEC and allies l A future upgrade for the model is to consider P as stochastic and positively correlated with the prices level P u Slowness of a reversion: the half-life (H) concept Time for the price deviations from the equilibrium-level are expected to decay by half of their magnitude. H = ln(2)/(  P )  The Poisson arrival parameter (jump frequency), the expected jump sizes, and the sizes uncertainties. l We adopt jumps as rare events (low frequency) but with high expected size. So, we looking to rare large jumps (even with uncertain size). è Used 1 jump for each 6.67 years, expecting doubling P (in case of jump- up) or halving P (in case of jump-down). l Let the jump risk be systematic, so is not possible to build a riskless portfolio as in Merton (1976). We use dynamic programming

Dynamic Programming and Options T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period Period Bellman Equations u The optimization under uncertainty given the stochastic process and given the available options, is performed by using the Bellman-dynamic programming equations:

 estimation is necessary even for contingent claims  Even discounting with risk-free rate, for contingent claims, appears the parameter risk-adjusted discount rate  This is due the convenience yield (  equation for the mean-reversion process:  (P  P) [remember  = growth rate + dividend rate]  Conclusion: Anyway we need  for mean-reversion process, because  is a function of  ;  is not constant as in the GBM  So, we let  be an exogenous risk-adjusted discount rate that considers the incomplete markets/systematic jump feature, with dynamic programming a la Dixit & Pindyck (1994) A market estimation of  : use the  time-series from futures market A Motivation for Using Dynamic Programming u First, see the contingent claims PDE version of this model: u Compare with the dynamic programming version:

Boundary Conditions u In the boundary conditions are addressed: The NPV (payoff for an immediate development = V  D), which is function of q, that is, V = q P  NPV = q P  D l The extension feature at T 1, paying K and winning another call option è Absorbing barrier at P = 0 è First expiration optimally (include extension feature) è Smooth pasting condition (for both periods) è Value matching at P* (for both periods) è Second expiration optimally (D 2 can be different of D 1 ) u To solve the PDE, we use finite differences in explicit form u A C++ software was developed with an interactive interface

The C++ Software Interface: Main Window u Software solves extendible options for three different stochastic processes (two jump-reversion and the GBM)

The C++ Software Interface: Progress Calculus Window u The interface was designed using the C-Builder (Borland)  The progress window shows visual and percentage progress and tells about the size of the matrix  P x  t (grid density)

Main Results Window u This window shows only the main results u The complete file with all results is also generate

Parameters Values for the Base Case u The more complex stochastic process for oil prices (jump- reversion) demands several parameters estimation u The criteria for the base case parameters values were: l Looking values used in literature (others related papers) è Half-life for oil prices ranging from less than a year to 5 years è For drift related parameters, is better a long time series than a large number of samples (Campbell, Lo & MacKinlay, 1997 ) l Looking data from an average oilfield in offshore Brazil è Oilfield currently with NPV = 0; Reserves of 100 millions barrels l Preliminary estimative of the parameters using dynamic regression (adaptative model), with the variances of the transition expressions calculated with Bayesian approach using MCMC (Markov Chain Monte Carlo) è Large number of samples is better for volatility estimation u Several sensibility analysis were performed, filling the gaps

Jump-Reversion Base Case Parameters

The First Option and the Payoff u Note the smooth pasting of option curve on the payoff line u The blue curve (option) is typical for mean reversion cases

The Two Payoffs for Jump-Reversion u In our model we allow to recover a part of the extension fee K, by reducing the investment D 2 in the second period l The second payoff (green line) has a smaller development investment D 2 = 4.85 $/bbl than in the first period (D 1 = 5 $/bbl) because we assume to recover 50% of K (e.g.: exploratory well used as injector)

The Options and Payoffs for Both Periods T I M E Options Charts T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period Period

Options Values at T 1 and Just After T 1 u At T 1 (black line), the part which is optimal to extend (between ~6 to ~22 $/bbl), is parallel to the option curve just after the first expiration, and the distance is equal the fee K l Boundary condition explains parallel distance of K in that interval l Chart uses K = 0.5 $/bbl (instead base case K = 0.3) in order to highlight the effect

The Thresholds Charts for Jump-Reversion u At or above the thresholds lines (blue and red, for the first and the second periods, respectively) is optimal the immediate development. l Extension (by paying K) is optimal at T 1 for 4.7 < P < 22.2 $/bbl l So, the extension threshold P E = 4.7 $/bbl (under 4.7, give-up is optimal)

Alternatives Timing Policies for Petroleum Sector u The table presents the sensibility analysis for different timing policies for the petroleum sector l Option values are proxy for bonus in the bidding l Higher thresholds means more investment delay l Longer timing means more bonus but more delay (tradeoff) u Results indicate a higher % gain for option value (bonus) than a % increase in thresholds (delay) l So, is reasonable to consider something between 8-10 years

Alternatives Timing Policies for Petroleum Sector u The first draft of the Brazilian concession timing policy, pointed = 5 years l The timing policy was object of a public debate in Brazil, with oil companies wanting a higher timing u In April/99, the notable economist and ex-Finance Minister Delfim Netto defended a longer timing policy for petroleum sector using our paper: l In his column from a top Brazilian newspaper (Folha de São Paulo), he commented and cited (favorably) our paper conclusions about timing policies to support his view! u The recent version of the concession contract (valid for the 1 st bidding) points up to 9 years of total timing, divided into two or three periods l So, we planning an upgrade of our program to include the cases with three exploration periods

Comparing Dynamic Programming with Contingent Claims u Results show very small differences in adopting non- arbitrage contingent claims or dynamic programming l However, for geometric Brownian motion the difference is very large  OBS: for contingent claims, we adopt  = 10% and r = 5% to compare

Sensibility Analysis: Jump Frequency u Higher jump frequency means higher hysteresis: higher investment threshold P* and lower extension threshold P E

Sensibility Analysis: Volatility u Higher volatility also means higher hysteresis: higher investment threshold P* and lower extension threshold P E u Several other sensibilities analysis were performed l Material available at

Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM u Is the use of jump-reversion instead GBM much better for bonus (option) bidding evaluation? u Is the use of jump-reversion significant for investment and extension decisions (thresholds)?  Two important parameters for these processes are the volatility and the convenience yield . In order to compare option value and thresholds from these processes in the same basis, we use the same   In GBM,  is an input, constant, and let  = 5%p.a.  For jump-reversion,  is endogenous, changes with P, so we need to compare option value for a P that implies  = 5%: u Sensibility analysis points in general higher option values (so higher bonus-bidding) for jump-reversion (see Table 3)

Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM u Jump-reversion points lower thresholds for longer maturity  The threshold discontinuity near T 2 is due the behavior of , that can be negative for lower values of P:  ( P  P) A necessary condition for early exercise of American option is  > 0

Concluding Remarks u The paper main contributions are: l Use of the options with extendible maturities framework for real assets, allowing partial recovering of the extension fee K l We use a more rigourous and more logic but more complex stochastic process for oil prices (jump-reversion) u The main upgrades planned for the model: l Inclusion of a third period (another extendible expiration), for several cases of the new Brazilian concession contract l Improvement on the stochastic process, by allowing the long-run mean P to be stochastic and positively correlated u First time a real options paper cited in Brazilian important newspaper u Comparing with GBM, jump-reversion presents: l Higher options value (higher bonus); higher thresholds for short lived options (concessions) and lower for long lived one

Additional Materials for Support

Demonstration of the Jump-Reversion PDE u Consider the Bellman for the extendible option (up T 1 ): u We can rewrite the Bellman equation in a general form:  Where  (P, t)  is the payoff  function that can be the extendible payoff (feature considered only at T 1 ) or the NPV from the immediate development. Optimally features are left to the boundary conditions. u We rewrite the equation for the continuation region in return form: u The value E[dF] is calculated with the Itô´s Lemma for Poisson + Itô mix process (see Dixit & Pindyck, eq.42, p.86), using our process for dP: u Substituting E[dF] into (*), we get the PDE presented in the paper (*)

Finite Difference Method u Numerical method to solve numerically the partial differential equation (PDE) u The PDE is converted in a set of differences equations and they are solved iteratively u There are explicit and implicit forms l Explicit problem: convergence problem if the “probabilities” are negative è Use of logaritm of P has no advantage for mean-reverting l Implicit: simultaneous equations (three-diagonal matrix). Computation time (?) u Finite difference methods can be used for jump- diffusions processes. Example: Bates (1991)

Explicit Finite Difference Form  Grid: Domain space  P x  t Discretization F(P,t)  F( i  P, j  t  F i, j With 0  i  m and 0  j  n  where m = P max /  P and n = T /  t “Probabilities” p need to be positives in order to get the convergence (see Hull) P t Domain Space (distribution)

Finite Differences Discretization u The derivatives approximation by differences are the central difference for P, and foward-difference for t: F PP  [ F i+1,j  2F i,j + F i-1,j ] / (  P) 2 F P  [ F i+1,j  F i-1,j ] / 2  P F t  [ F i,j+1  F i,j ] /  t u Substitutes the aproximations into the PDE

Economic Quality of a Developed Reserve u Schwartz (1997) shows a chart NPV x spot price and gives linear for two and three factors models l For the two factors model, but with time varying production Q(t), the economic quality of a developed reserve q is: Where A(t) is a non-stochastic function of parameters and time. A(t) doesn’t depend on spot price P l In this example there are 10 years of production  is the reversion speed of the stochastic convenience yield u Economic quality of a developed reserve depends of the nature (permo-porosity and fluids quality), taxes, operational cost, and of the capital in-place (by D). è Concept doesn’t depend of a linear model, but it eases the calculus

u Sensibility analysis show that the options values increase in case of: Increasing the reversion speed  (or decreasing the half-life H); Decreasing the risk-adjusted discount rate , because it decreases also  due the relation  (P  P) + , increasing the waiting effect; Increasing the volatility  do processo de reversão; Increasing the frequency of jumps ; l Increasing the expected value of the jump-up size; l Reducing the cost of the extension of the option K; l Increasing the long-run mean price P; l Increasing the economic quality of the developed reserve q; and l Increasing the time to expiration (T 1 and T 2 ) Others Sensibility Analysis

Sensibility Analysis: Reversion Speed

Sensibility Analysis: Discount Rate 

Estimating the Discount Rate with Market Data  A practical “market” way to estimate the discount rate  in order to be not so arbitrary, is by looking  with the futures market contracts with the longest maturity (but with liquidity) Take both time series, for  (calculated from futures) and for the spot price P. With the pair (P,  ) estimate a time series for  using the equation:  (t)  (t)  [P  P (t)]. This time series (for  ) is much more stable than the series for . Why? Because  and P has a high positive correlation (between to 0.915, in the Schwartz paper of 1997). An average value for  from this time series is a good choice for this parameter  OBS: This method is different of the contingent claims, even using the market data for 

Sensibility Analysis: Lon-Run Mean

Sensibility Analysis: Time to Expiration

Sensibility Analysis: Economic Quality of Reserve

Geometric Brownian Base Case

Drawbacks from the Model u The speed of the calculation is very sensitive to the precision. In a Pentium 133 MHz: Using  P = 0.5 $/bbl takes few minutes; but using more reasonable  P = 0.1, takes two hours!  The point is the required  t to converge ( or less) è Comparative statics takes lot of time, and so any graph u Several additional parameters to estimate (when comparing with more simple models) that is not directly observable. l More source of errors in the model u But is necessary to develop more realistic models!

The Grid Precision and the Results u The precision can be negligible or significant (values from an older base case)

Software Interface: Data Input Window