Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices Workshop on Real Options in Petroleum and Energy September.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices Workshop on Real Options in Petroleum and Energy September."— Presentation transcript:

1 Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices Workshop on Real Options in Petroleum and Energy September 19-20, 2002, Mexico City By: Marco A. G. Dias (Petrobras) & Katia M. C. Rocha (IPEA)

2 Presentation Highlights u Paper has two new contributions: l Extendible maturity framework for real options è Kemna (1993) model is too simplified (European option, etc.) l Use of jump-reversion process for oil prices è First presented in May/98 (Workshop on RO, Stavanger) u Presentation topics: l Concepts for options with extendible maturities è Thresholds for immediate development and for extension l Main stochastic processes for oil prices è Jump + mean-reversion: + real application on Marlim field l Dynamic programming x contingent claims l Model discussion, charts, C++ software interface l Public debate on timing policy for oil sector in Brazil l Concluding remarks

3 E&P Is a Sequential Options Process u Drill the pioneer? Wait? Extend? u Revelation and technical uncertainty modeling Oil/Gas Success Probability = p Expected Volume of Reserves = B Revised Volume = B’ u Appraisal phase: delineation of reserves u Invest in additional information? u Develop? “Wait and See” for better conditions? Extend the option? u Developed Reserves. u Expand the production? Stop Temporally? Abandon? Primary focus of our model: undeveloped reserves

4 The Extendible Maturity Feature (2 Periods) [Develop Now] or [Wait and See] [Develop Now] or [Extend (commit K)] or [Give-up (Return to Government)] T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period T I M E PeriodAvailable Options [Develop Now] or [Wait and See] [Develop Now] or [Give-up (Return to Government)]

5 Brazilian Timing Policy for the Oil Sector u With the Brazilian petroleum sector opening in 1997, the new regulation for exploratory areas is: l Fiscal regime of concessions, first-price sealed bid (like USA) l Adopted the concept of extendible options (two or three periods). è The time extension is conditional to additional exploratory commitment (1-3 wells), established before the bid. è Let K be the cost (or exercise price) to extend the exploratory concession term. The benefit is another option term to explore and/or to develop. l The extendible feature occurred also in USA (5 + 3 years, for some areas of GoM) and in Europe (see paper of Kemna, 1993) l American options with extendible maturities was studied by Longstaff (1990) for financial applications l The timing for exploratory phase (time to expiration for the development rights) was object of a public debate è The National Petroleum Agency posted the first project for debate in its website in February/1998, with 3 + 2 years, time we considered too short

6 Extendible Option Payoff at the First Expiration u At the first expiration (T 1 ), the firm can develop the field, or extend the option, or give-up/back to National Agency u For the geometric Brownian motion, the payoff at T 1 is:

7 Main Stochastic Processes for Oil Prices u There are many models of stochastic processes for oil prices in real options literature. I classify them into three classes. u The nice properties of Geometric Brownian Motion (few parameters, homogeneity) is a great incentive to use it in real options applications. u We (Dias & Rocha) used the mean-reversion process with jumps of random size and also the geometric Brownian motion for comparison

8 Mean-Reversion + Jump: the Sample Paths  100 sample paths for mean-reversion + jumps ( =  jump each 5  years)

9 Nominal Prices for Brent and Similar Oils (1970-2001) u With an adequate long-term scale, we can see that oil prices jump in both directions, depending of the kind of abnormal news: jumps-up in 1973/4, 1978/9, 1990, 1999; and jumps-down in 1986, 1991, 1997, 2001 Jumps-up Jumps-down

10 Poisson-Gaussian Stochastic Process u We adapt the Merton (1976) jump-diffusion idea but for the oil prices case: l Normal news cause only marginal adjustment in oil prices, modeled with a continuous-time process l Abnormal rare news (war, OPEC surprises,...) cause abnormal adjustment (jumps) in petroleum prices, modeled with a discrete time Poisson process u Differences between our model and Merton model: l Continuous time process: mean-reversion instead the geometric Brownian motion (more logic for oil prices) l Uncertainty on the jumps size: two truncated normal distributions instead the lognormal distribution l Extendible American option instead European vanilla l Jumps can be systematic instead non-systematic

11 Stochastic Process Model for Oil Prices u Model has more economic logic (supply x demand) l Normal information causes smoothing changes in oil prices (marginal variations) and means both: è Marginal interaction between production and demand (inventory level is an indicator); and è Depletion versus new reserves discoveries (the ratio of reserves/production is an indicator) l Abnormal information means very important news: è In few months, this kind of news causes jumps in the prices, due the expected large variation in either supply or demand u Mean-reversion has been considered a better model than GBM for commodities and perhaps for interest rates and for exchange rates. Why? l Microeconomic logic; term structure and volatility of futures prices; econometric tests with long time-span l However, reversion in oil prices is slow (Pindyck, 1999)

12 Equation for Mean-Reversion + Jumps u The stochastic equation for the petroleum prices (P) Geometric Mean-Reversion with Random Jumps is:  The jump size/direction are random:  ~ 2N l In case of jump-up, price is expected to double l In case of jum-down, price is expected to drop by half ; So,

13 Real Case with Mean-Reversion + Jumps u A similar process of mean-reversion with jumps was used by Dias for the equity design (US$ 200 million) of the Project Finance of Marlim Field (oil prices-linked spread) l Equity investors reward: è Basic interest-rate + spread (linked to oil business risk) l Oil prices-linked: transparent deal (no agency cost) and win-win: è Higher oil prices  higher spread, and vice versa (good for both) u Deal was in December 1998 when oil price was 10 $/bbl l We convince investors that the expected oil prices curve was a fast reversion towards US$ 20/bbl (equilibrium level) l Looking the jumps-up & down, we limit the spread by putting both cap (maximum spread, protecting Petrobras) and floor (to prevent negative spread, protecting the investor) l This jumps insight proved be very important: è Few months later the oil prices jumped-up (price doubled by Aug/99) –The cap protected Petrobras from paying a very high spread

14 Parameters Values for the Base Case u The more complex stochastic process for oil prices (jump- reversion) demands several parameters estimation l Jumps frequency: counting process with a jump criteria l The jumps data were excluded in order to estimate mean- reversion (jumps and reversion processes are independent) u The criteria for the base case parameters values were: l Looking values used in literature for mean-reversion è For drift related parameters, is better a long time series than a large number of samples (Campbell, Lo & MacKinlay, 1997 ) è Large number of samples is better for volatility estimation l Econometric estimative of the parameters using dynamic regression (adaptative model), with the variances of the transition expressions calculated with Bayesian approach using MCMC (Markov Chain Monte Carlo) l Used other econometric (classical) approaches u Several sensibility analysis were performed, filling the gaps

15 Jump-Reversion Base Case Parameters

16 Mean-Reversion and Jumps Parameters u The long-run mean or equilibrium level which the prices tends to revert can be estimated by econometric way l Another idea is a game theoretic model, setting a leader- follower duopoly for price-takers x OPEC and allies l A future upgrade for the model is to consider P as stochastic (GBM) and positively correlated with the prices level P u Slowness of a reversion: the half-life (H) concept l Time for the price deviations from the equilibrium-level are expected to decay by half of their magnitude. Range: 1-5 years  The Poisson arrival parameter (jump frequency), the expected jump sizes, and the sizes uncertainties. l We adopt jumps as rare events (low frequency) but with high expected size. So, we looking to rare large jumps (even with uncertain size). è Used 1 jump for each 6.67 years. Poisson is a counting process and we consider only large-jumps to set this frequency. l We allow also the jump risk be systematic, so is not possible to build a riskless portfolio as in Merton (1976). We use dynamic programming

17 Dynamic Programming and Options T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period Period Bellman Equations u The optimization under uncertainty given the stochastic process and given the available options, was first performed by using the Bellman-dynamic programming equations:

18  Even discounting with risk-free rate, for contingent claims, appears the parameter risk-adjusted discount rate  This is due the convenience yield (  equation for the mean-reversion process:  (P  P) [remember  = growth rate + dividend yield]  Conclusion: Anyway we need  for mean-reversion process, because  is a function of  ;  is not constant as in the GBM u As in Dixit & Pindyck (1994), we use dynamic programming Let  be an exogenous risk-adjusted discount rate that considers the incomplete markets/systematic jump feature l We compare the results dynamic programming x contingent claims A Motivation for Using Dynamic Programming u First, see the contingent claims PDE version of this model: u Compare with the dynamic programming version:  estimation is necessary even for contingent claims

19 Boundary Conditions u In the boundary conditions are addressed: Payoff for an immediate development is NPV/bbl = V  D. l Developed reserve value is proportional to P: V = q P l The extension feature at T 1, paying K and winning another call option è Absorbing barrier at P = 0 è First expiration optimally (include extension feature) è Smooth pasting condition (for both periods) è Value matching at P* (for both periods) è Second expiration optimally (D 2 can be different of D 1 ) u To solve the PDE, we use finite differences u A C++ software was developed with an interactive interface

20 C++ Software Interface: The Main Window u Software solves extendible options for 3 different stochastic processes and two methods (dynamic programming and contingent claims)

21 The Options and Payoffs for Both Periods T I M E Options Charts T 2 : Second Expiration t = 0 to T 1 : First Period T 1 : First Expiration T 1 to T 2 : Second Period Period

22 The Thresholds Charts for Jump-Reversion u At or above the thresholds lines (blue and red, for the first and the second periods, respectively) is optimal the immediate development. l Extension (by paying K) is optimal at T 1 for 4.7 < P < 22.2 $/bbl l So, the extension threshold P E = 4.7 $/bbl (under 4.7, give-up is optimal)

23 Debate on Exploratory Timing Policy u The oil companies considered very short the time of 3 + 2 years that appeared in the first draft by National Agency l It was below the international practice mainly for deepwaters areas (e.g., USA/GoM: some areas 5 + 3 years; others 10 years) l During 1998 and part of 1999, the Director of the National Petroleum Agency (ANP) insisted in this short timing policy l The numerical simulations of our paper (Dias & Rocha, 1998) concludes that the optimal timing policy should be 8 to 10 years l In January 1999 we sent our paper to the notable economist, politic and ex-Minister Delfim Netto, highlighting this conclusion l In April/99 (3 months before the first bid), Delfim Netto wrote an article at Folha de São Paulo (a top Brazilian newspaper) defending a longer timing policy for petroleum sector l Delfim used our paper conclusions to support his view! l Few days after, the ANP Director finally changed his position! è Since the 1 st bid most areas have 9 years. At least it’s a coincidence!

24 Alternatives Timing Policies in Dias & Rocha u The table below presents the sensibility analysis for different timing policies for the petroleum sector l Option values (F) are proxy for bonus in the bid l Higher thresholds (P*) means more delay for investments è Longer timing means more bonus but more delay (tradeoff) u Table indicates a higher % gain for option value (bonus) than a % increase in thresholds (delay) l So, is reasonable to consider something between 8-10 years

25 Comparing Dynamic Programming with Contingent Claims u Results show very small differences in adopting non- arbitrage contingent claims or dynamic programming l However, for geometric Brownian motion the difference was large  OBS: for contingent claims, we adopt  = 10% and r = 5% to compare

26 Sensibility Analysis: Jump Frequency u Higher jump frequency means higher hysteresis: higher investment threshold P* and lower extension threshold P E

27 Sensibility Analysis: Volatility u Higher volatility also means higher hysteresis: higher investment threshold P* and lower extension threshold P E u Several other sensibilities analysis were performed l Material available at http://www.puc-rio.br/marco.ind/

28 Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM u Jump-reversion points lower thresholds for longer maturity  The threshold discontinuity near T 2 is due the behavior of , that can be negative for low oil prices P:  ( P  P) A necessary condition for American call early exercise is  > 0

29 Concluding Remarks u The paper main contributions were: l Use of the American call options with extendible maturities framework for real assets l We use a more rigourous and logic (but more complex) stochastic process for oil prices (jump-reversion) u The main upgrades planned for the model: l Inclusion of a third period (another extendible expiration), for several cases of the new Brazilian concession contract l Improvement on the stochastic process, by allowing the long-run mean be stochastic and positively correlated with P u Comparing with GBM, jump-reversion presented: l Higher options value (higher bonus); higher thresholds for short lived options (concessions) and lower for long lived one u First time a real options paper contributed in a Brazilian public debate being cited by a top newspaper

30 Additional Materials for Support

31 Demonstration of the Jump-Reversion PDE u Consider the Bellman for the extendible option (up T 1 ): u We can rewrite the Bellman equation in a general form:  Where  (P, t)  is the payoff  function that can be the extendible payoff (feature considered only at T 1 ) or the NPV from the immediate development. Optimally features are left to the boundary conditions. u We rewrite the equation for the continuation region in return form: u The value E[dF] is calculated with the Itô´s Lemma for Poisson + Itô mix process (see Dixit & Pindyck, eq.42, p.86), using our process for dP: u Substituting E[dF] into (*), we get the PDE presented in the paper (*)

32 Finite Difference Method u Numerical method to solve numerically the partial differential equation (PDE) u The PDE is converted in a set of differences equations and they are solved iteratively u There are explicit and implicit forms l Explicit problem: convergence problem if the “probabilities” are negative è Use of logaritm of P has no advantage for mean-reverting l Implicit: simultaneous equations (three-diagonal matrix). Computation time (?) u Finite difference methods can be used for jump- diffusions processes. Example: Bates (1991)

33 Explicit Finite Difference Form  Grid: Domain space  P x  t Discretization F(P,t)  F( i  P, j  t  F i, j With 0  i  m and 0  j  n  where m = P max /  P and n = T /  t “Probabilities” p need to be positives in order to get the convergence (see Hull) P t Domain Space (distribution)

34 Finite Differences Discretization u The derivatives approximation by differences are the central difference for P, and foward-difference for t: F PP  [ F i+1,j  2F i,j + F i-1,j ] / (  P) 2 F P  [ F i+1,j  F i-1,j ] / 2  P F t  [ F i,j+1  F i,j ] /  t u Substitutes the aproximations into the PDE

35 Comparing Jump-Reversion with GBM u Is the use of jump-reversion instead GBM much better for bonus (option) bidding evaluation? u Is the use of jump-reversion significant for investment and extension decisions (thresholds)?  Two important parameters for these processes are the volatility and the convenience yield . In order to compare option value and thresholds from these processes in the same basis, we use the same   In GBM,  is an input, constant, and let  = 5%p.a.  For jump-reversion,  is endogenous, changes with P, so we need to compare option value for a P that implies  = 5%: u Sensibility analysis points in general higher option values (so higher bonus-bidding) for jump-reversion (see Table 3)

36 Economic Quality of a Developed Reserve u Concept by Dias (1998): q =  V/  P l q = economic quality of the developed reserve l V = value of the developed reserve ($/bbl) l P = current petroleum price ($/bbl) u For the proportional model, V = q P, the economic quality of the reserve is constant. We adopt this model. l The option charts F x V and F x P at the expiration (t = T) F VD 45 o tg 45 o = 1 F PD/q  tg  = q = economic quality V = q. P F(t=T) = max (q P  D, 0) F(t=T) = max (NPV, 0) NPV = V  D

37 The First Option and the Payoff u Note the smooth pasting of option curve on the payoff line u The blue curve (option) is typical for mean reversion cases

38 The Two Payoffs for Jump-Reversion u In our model we allow to recover a part of the extension fee K, by reducing the investment D 2 in the second period l The second payoff (green line) has a smaller development investment D 2 = 4.85 $/bbl than in the first period (D 1 = 5 $/bbl) because we assume to recover 50% of K (e.g.: exploratory well used as injector)

39 Options Values at T 1 and Just After T 1 u At T 1 (black line), the part which is optimal to extend (between ~6 to ~22 $/bbl), is parallel to the option curve just after the first expiration, and the distance is equal the fee K l Boundary condition explains parallel distance of K in that interval l Chart uses K = 0.5 $/bbl (instead base case K = 0.3) in order to highlight the effect

40 The C++ Software Interface: Progress Calculus Window u The interface was designed using the C-Builder (Borland)  The progress window shows visual and percentage progress and tells about the size of the matrix  P x  t (grid density)

41 Main Results Window u This window shows only the main results u The complete file with all results is also generate

42 Software Interface: Data Input Window

43 u Sensibility analysis show that the options values increase in case of: Increasing the reversion speed  (or decreasing the half-life H). But note that P 0 < P in the base case; Decreasing the risk-adjusted discount rate , because it decreases also  due the relation  (P  P) + , increasing the waiting effect; Increasing the volatility  do processo de reversão; Increasing the frequency of jumps ; l Increasing the expected value of the jump-up size; l Reducing the cost of the extension of the option K; l Increasing the long-run mean price P; l Increasing the economic quality of the developed reserve q; and l Increasing the time to expiration (T 1 and T 2 ) Others Sensibility Analysis

44 Sensibility Analysis: Reversion Speed

45 Sensibility Analysis: Discount Rate 

46 Estimating the Discount Rate with Market Data  A practical “market” way to estimate the discount rate  in order to be not so arbitrary, is by looking  with the futures market contracts with the longest maturity (but with liquidity) Take both time series, for  (calculated from futures) and for the spot price P. With the pair (P,  ) estimate a time series for  using the equation:  (t)  (t)  [P  P (t)]. This time series (for  ) is much more stable than the series for . Why? Because  and P has a high positive correlation (between +0.809 to 0.915, in the Schwartz paper of 1997). An average value for  from this time series is a good choice for this parameter  OBS: This method is different of the contingent claims, even using the market data for 

47 Sensibility Analysis: Lon-Run Mean

48 Sensibility Analysis: Time to Expiration

49 Sensibility Analysis: Economic Quality of Reserve

50 Geometric Brownian Base Case

51 Drawbacks from the Model u The speed of the calculation is very sensitive to the precision. In a Pentium 133 MHz: Using  P = 0.5 $/bbl takes few minutes; but using more reasonable  P = 0.1, takes two hours!  The point is the required  t to converge (0.0001 or less) è Comparative statics takes lot of time, and so any graph u Several additional parameters to estimate (when comparing with more simple models) that is not directly observable. l More source of errors in the model u But is necessary to develop more realistic models!

52 The Grid Precision and the Results u The precision can be negligible or significant (values from an older base case)


Download ppt "Petroleum Concessions with Extendible Options Using Mean Reversion with Jumps to Model Oil Prices Workshop on Real Options in Petroleum and Energy September."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google