The Economics of Climate Change

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Economic Impacts of Climate Change
Advertisements

The economics of climate change: the messages to Africa Presentation for the CDM DNA Forum Addis Ababa, 6 th October 2007 Hannah Muthoni Ryder.
The Economics of Climate Change Nicholas Stern 15 November 2006 Presentation to the Convention Dialogue, Nairobi.
International Forum of R&D for Eco-innovation Research for combining environmental priorities with economic opportunities Impact of energy scarcity on.
1 ACT AND ADAPT: CLIMATE CHANGE IN SCOTLAND Climate Change Division.
5/16/2015The NEED Project: 30 Years of Energy Education1 The Basics of Climate Change.
1 The Economics of Climate Change: Costs and Benefits of Reducing GHG Emissions Maureen Cropper University of Maryland and Resources for the Future August.
Derek Eaton Division of Technology, Industry & Economics Economics & Trade Branch Geneva, Switzerland “Designing the Green Economy” Centre for International.
The Greenhouse Effect. SPM 3 Concentration of Carbon Dioxide and Methane Have Risen Greatly Since Pre-Industrial Times Carbon dioxide: 33%
Tackling Dangerous Climate Change A UK perspective on a global issue Jonathan Brearley Director – Office Of Climate Change.
1 Key vulnerabilities to climate change Some ecosystems are highly vulnerable: Coral reefs, marine shell organisms Tundra, boreal forests, mountain and.
The Economics of Climate Change: Reflections on the Stern Report Dennis Anderson Imperial College Centre for Energy Policy and Technology (ICEPT) February.
Gabriel Bachner - Thomas Kerekes 1 A Goal for Climate-Change Policy The Stern-Review Chapter 13.
27 June 2007 Synonyms in Science Examples from Earth Systems Science Nathan Bindoff ACECRC, IASOS, CSIRO MAR University of Tasmania TPAC.
Why Climate Change is important for Vietnam. Global emissions of greenhouse gases come from a wide range of sources Source: World Resources Institute.
Chapter 2 A Safe Landing for the Climate. The climate has risen 0.7 degrees Celsius. Most of this has occurred in the mid 20 th century. Human activities.
The Economics of Global Warming
IPCC Synthesis Report Part I Overview How to address the issue of “dangerous anthropogenic perturbation” to the climate system The relationship between.
Resource Use and Sustainability Dr. George Norton Agricultural and Applied Economics Virginia Tech Copyright 2008 AAEC 3204.
Tourism Industry at Risk: The Economic Impact of Climate Change
Climate Change Policies Market failure and possible government failure.
Objective: Understand Causes, Effects and Solutions of Global Warming
Nov 2014: China-US agreement on carbon emissions -President Obama pledges to reduce GHG emissions by -26 to 28% of 2005 levels by president Xi Jinping.
Carbon Taxes, Climate Change, and Sustainable Development Tariq Banuri Stockholm Environment Institute June 2008.
Climate Change: Assessing Ecological Risk by International Region By: Katie Mohn, Sam Dykstra, Michael Hartman, Jingxue Hu, Kelsey Loy, Shiqi Miao, Ruijuan.
Trade and Climate Change: International Perspective Mac Callaway, Ph.D UNEP-RISØ Center Technical University of Denmark CPA International.
REVIEW OF THE LEGAL FRAMEWORK AND POLICY TOOLS FOR ADDRESSING CLIMATE CHANGE: SUMMARY OF SEVEN ASIAN COUNTRY STUDIES SUPPORTED BY UNEP-AECEN Presented.
Climate Science Context Brian Hoskins Director Grantham Institute for Climate Change, Imperial College Professor of Meteorology, University of Reading.
Working with Uncertainty Population, technology, production, consumption Emissions Atmospheric concentrations Radiative forcing Socio-economic impacts.
UDA: Global Warming.
Elevation AMSL = 1.5 m Area = 1.5 km2 Population = 25, m 132m Source: SOPAC Climate Change & Impacts on SIDS Rolph Payet IPCC Lead Author International.
School of something FACULTY OF OTHER The UK Low Carbon Transition Plan: Where are we going? Dr Tim Foxon Sustainability Research Institute, and Centre.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 21 The Economics of Energy, The Environment, and Global.
The Economic Perspective Economists are not concerned with whether it exists, but whether/what should be done about it. Even though climate change exists,
The Economics of Climate Change Adaptation
The Economics of Global Climate Change Figures and Tables By Jonathan M. Harris and Brian Roach Copyright © 2007 Jonathan M. Harris.
Presentation to the St. Louis Regional Chamber and Growth Association (RCGA) Energy and Environmental Council by Commissioner Kevin Gunn Missouri Public.
The Economics of Climate Change Nicholas Stern Australian Davos Connection 28th March 2007.
James F. Casey Associate Professor of Economics and Environmental Studies Williams School of Commerce, Economics and Politics Washington and Lee University.
Why focus on Policy Catherine Thomasson, MD 9/20/15.
THINKING LONG TERM: Confronting Global Climate Change Written by James J. MacKenzie Senior Associate World Resources Institute (WRI)
The Science and Economics of Climate Change Based on presentations by John Houghton of IPCC, Earthguage, the Met. Office and the Stern Review.
Global Sustainability: The Case for Collaboration Environmental Issues.
Adaptation to Global Warming Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
The Economics of Climate Change Adaptation UNDP Accra 2012 Robert Mendelsohn Yale University.
IPCC Key conclusions from the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Bert Metz Netherlands Environmental Assessment.
Stanley J. Kabala, Ph.D. Center for Environmental Research & Education Duquesne University Pittsburgh, Pa. U.S.A.
Kyoto Protocol IDC3O3 Ms. Nguyen.
Cost of Inaction June Reyes and Erika Kociolek. Inaction “All too infrequently, inaction is motivated by the perceived high cost of reducing greenhouse.
1 IPCC The challenges of climate change WMO UNEP R. K. Pachauri Chairman, IPCC Director-General, TERI Helsinki University 14 th February 2008.
Climate change Challenges and Opportunities Ian Lowe April 28, 2009.
The Economics of Climate Change Nicholas Stern World Bank Jakarta 23th March 2007.
A world with 9 Billion people…. Towards Building global Water, Food and Energy Resilience Dr. Ger Bergkamp Director General World Water Council 30 March.
1 Environmental Services Training Group LOCAL AUTHORITY ENVIRONMENT CONFERENCE 2015 Protecting Our Environment Hodson Bay Hotel, Athlone, May 2015.
GREENHOUSE EFFECT. What Is Greenhouse Effect??? an atmospheric heating phenomenon, caused by short-wave solar radiation being readily transmitted inward.
The Economics of Climate Change: (i) Risks, Targets (ii) Adaptation (iii) A Global Deal Nicholas Stern UNGA Thematic Debate 31 July 2007.
World Regional Geography Unit I: Introduction to World Regional Geography Lesson 4: Solutions to Global Warming Debate.
Climate Change Mitigation and Complexity Agus P Sari Country Director, Indonesia EcoSecurities.
Recap What is a carbon wedge? What strategies did you come up with do reduce climate change?
Climate Change: Economic and Policy Implications Robert B. Richardson, PhD Department of Community, Agriculture, Recreation and Resource Studies Michigan.
Looking at the Impacts of Climate Change: Uncertainty, Precaution and Regulation Tim Swanson.
Tourism Industry at Risk: The Economic Impact of Climate Change
The Economics of Energy, The Environment, and Global Climate Change
Climate Change Causes.
Climate Change All facts and images are from NASA and NOAA unless otherwise indicated.
The Economics of Global Climate Change Figures and tables
The Economics of Global Climate Change Figures and tables
The Economics of Global Climate Change Figures and Tables
Convenient or Not, the Climate is Changing
Presentation transcript:

The Economics of Climate Change Daniel De La Torre Ugarte Professor, University of Tennessee Trade, Environment, Climate Change and Sustainable Development Branch, UNCTAD

Environemental Problems According to Area of Influence Domestic: Local/Regional Bi-national / Multinational Global

Sources of emissions

Externalities Left on its own, the market will not solve the problem in a social optimal way Climate change is an externality: the emitter does not bear the direct costs of their action. As with any externality without policy interventions, the emitter has little motivation to consider the costs in their decision-making.

Climate Change is a Unique Externality” The emission of greenhouse gasses imposes costs on others that are not borne by the emitter. The costs will be felt over a long time period and over the entire world. But, the exact nature of costs is uncertain: they will be shaped by policies, market mechanisms, & other events. Those most affected—future generations– cannot speak up for their interests

Basic Policy Approaches For Reducing GHGs Tax the emitter equivalent to the marginal external social costs Ultimately borne by households, raises revenues that can be used to achieve other goals, provides incentives to economize on the damaging activity The allocation of property rights linked with emissions trading Provides large emitters the flexibility to trade emission rights across sectors. Direct regulation Tends to place burden on industry (which generally passes on the costs to consumers—if they can/will pay) Provide financial incentives Usually popular, sends clear signals, but often suffers from free rider problem.

Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change Author: Economist Sir Nicholas Stern Purpose: Created for the British government to address climate change using economic analysis Length: 700 pages! Published: October, 2006

The Science Doubling of pre-industrial greenhouse gases (~ 1900) = 2°-5° C change in mean global temperatures This doubling will most likely occur between 2030 and 2060, at today’s rate of carbon emissions Feedback effects could bring temperatures even higher (permafrost thaw) 3 ½ to 9 degrees F

Risk If carbon emissions stabilize at today’s rates: 0-2% chance of less than 1° C increase in temps. 2-20% chance of greater than 5° C increase in temps. Risk on high side > risk on low side

Projected impacts of climate change Global temperature change (relative to pre-industrial) 0°C 1°C 2°C 3°C 4°C 5°C Food Falling crop yields in many areas, particularly developing regions Possible rising yields in some high latitude regions Falling yields in many developed regions Water Significant decreases in water availability in many areas, including Mediterranean and Southern Africa Small mountain glaciers disappear – water supplies threatened in several areas Sea level rise threatens major cities Ecosystems Extensive Damage to Coral Reefs Rising number of species face extinction So, how did the Review demonstrate that climate change is so important? It did so in two ways. First, it looked at the potential impacts and effects of climate change at different increases in temperature, then related those temperature rises to projections of greenhouse gas emissions. Many of you will know that this is the task of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change’s WG2 on impacts, adaptation and vulnerability, and it supports the findings of the Review. If the world continues to emit greenhouse gases in the quantities we are doing right now, we run very high risks – it implies a rise in temperature of around 4-5 degrees C above pre-industrial levels, which we’ve not really considered or seen before. A change of 5 degC could change the worlds physical geography, and therefore human geography, how we live our lives. And these effects are, in the main, negative effects and inequitable – they hit poor countries earliest and hardest. Let me give just one example briefly: at a temperature increase of 1 deg C, we expect severe impacts in the marginal Sahel, at an increase of 2-3deg C we may see a 25-60% increase in the people at risk of hunger with half of that increase in Africa and West Asia, while at 4-5degC scientists expect crop yields to decline by up to a third in Africa. Many other effects of climate change are mediated through water, risks of more extreme events such as both drought and flooding - leading to major water shortages. There are risks to ecosystems, of extinction of major species, of abrupt and major irreversible changes. Extreme Weather Events Rising intensity of storms, forest fires, droughts, flooding and heat waves Risk of Abrupt and Major Irreversible Changes Increasing risk of dangerous feedbacks and abrupt, large-scale shifts in the climate system

Anticipated Regional Impacts Climate change impacts will vary upon regions. This table provides a sample of some predictions for regions of the world.

Examples of Impacts of Climate Change: Africa (The information provided with this map is self explanatory)

Examples of Impacts of Climate Change: Asia (The information provided in this table is self explanatory)

Stabilization and Commitment to Warming 5% 400 ppm CO2e 95% 450 ppm CO2e 550 ppm CO2e 650ppm CO2e There are some very serious threats we face, and by considering those risks, the Review finds that we should try to do something to stabilise greenhouse gas emissions, in order to avoid these dangerous temperature increases. Our emissions are a flow each year that accumulates in the atmosphere, building up stocks over time – concentrations – and it is that stock that leads to climate change. At the moment, we are at around 430ppm concentrations, and rising by around 2ppm per year. Therefore, stabilising at around 450ppm, where the risk of a temperature rise of around 2deg C will be about 50:50, will be very difficult – we will get to 450 within the next 10 years on current projections. But even something more “realistic” of stabilising at around 550ppm would be very risky – that gives a 50:50 chance of a 3 deg C rise, but it is far less risky than staying on a BAU path, which gets us to 5 deg rises. This underlines the problem, that the actions we – the world - takes now make a very large difference. 750ppm CO2e Eventual temperature change (relative to pre-industrial) 0°C 1°C 2°C 3°C 4°C 5°C 17

Mean losses in income per capita from scenarios of climate change I mentioned earlier that the Stern Review demonstrated that climate change is urgent and serious in two ways, and this is the second. As you will know, economists like to turn concepts, actions, events into numbers – and that is exactly what we did here. We considered just how much these sorts of impacts might cost the world, and comparing those to what the costs of doing something about emissions now – trying to stabilise at those levels I’ve already mentioned of 450-550ppm – might be. To do this, we averaged over three things – time, risk and countries. Depending on how you average these things, on whether, for example, you take an ethical view about how we should value future generations, about how we should value those who are poorer than us, we found that these costs equated to something between 5 and 20% of GDP every year if we continue as we are. 5 and 20% of GDP – those are big numbers, and a wide range. But even that valuation is limited – there were many things, many impacts on human life, that as economists, we still can’t value. And modelling is a simplification exercise. But at least it gives a broad range of the kinds of costs we might expect. Essential to take account of risk and uncertainty Models do not provide precise forecasts Assumptions on discounting, equity, and risk aversion affect results

Taking urgent action makes good economics - delaying is dangerous and costly The cost of cutting emissions consistent with a 550ppm CO2e stabilisation trajectory averages 1% of GDP per year in 2050 – this can be achieved by deployment of available technologies and those expected to be commercialised in coming decades Delaying emissions reductions significantly constrains the opportunities to achieve lower stabilisation - strong mitigation is fully consistent with aspirations for growth and development in poor and rich countries And compared to the costs of reducing emissions? Well, that depends on when we start to cut emissions, how we do so, and how much technology costs fall over time. This graph illustrates the scale of action required. Doing more, costs more. But, for example, we found that a very wide range of models – both top down and bottom up - suggest that trying to stabilise at 550ppm will cost 1% of GDP per year. Again, that finding was corroborated by the IPCC report on mitigation released earlier this month. It is manageable, and it means we can grow and be green. In fact, comparing this to the potential costs of doing nothing, it is the other way round – if we don’t tackle climate change we will reduce growth and development. And that’s a strong message. A strong message delivered by Sir Nick that was embraced by African Heads of State at the African Union summit here in Addis Ababa earlier this year – so much so that they adopted a declaration on climate change and development. 19

Costs of climate change A loss of 5% average per capita GDP ‘now and forever’ Costs are not evenly distributed Developing nations will pay higher price Sub-Sahara Africa (high non-market costs) India & Southeast Asia (9-13% loss in GDP) Developed nations will vary depending upon geography US (1-1.2% loss in GDP)

What kinds of costs? Agriculture Water Temperature Mortality Increased flooding / droughts Extreme weather events Mortality Heat Malnutrition Disease Infrastructure Storm damage Coastal Protection Species Loss

Other potential cost factors Non-market impacts Environment & human health Amplified feedback effects Methane release & loss of carbon sinks Correct weighting of poor regions If these factors are taken into account, total costs are potentially as high as 20% of world GDP

Economics of Stabilization Today’s Carbon level: 430 ppm Pre-industrial level: 280 ppm ‘Business as usual’: 550 ppm by 2035 and 700 ppm by 2100 creating temperature changes unseen in human experience Last ice age to pre-industrial = 5 degree C temp difference

Sources: National differences Direct relationship between per capita income and carbon emissions. U.S. emits five time the world average for per person carbon emissions As populations increase, carbon emissions will increase As the large populations in Asia (India & China) continue to develop economically, carbon emissions will continue to increase.

Stabilization Goal Stabilization defined: A balance whereby emissions are equal to the Earth’s natural capacity to remove the gases. Carbon Goal to obtain stabilization: 450-550 ppm Cut of 25% of current emissions levels by 2050 Cost of abatement: Approximately 1% of world GDP Consistent with continued growth & development

Emergency Pathways Global emissions peak in 2015 Emergency Pathways Global emissions peak in 2015. Drop by 50 - 80% by 2050 Risk of exceeding 2ºC These three pathways define a band of emergency reduction trajectories The least stringent of these emergency pathways – by which we mean 50% emissions reduction by 2050 – is being supported by the most courageous politicians. This is progress. But the fact remains that this is a rather risky trajectory. So, taking seriously that the climate crisis warrants an emergency response, we take the most stringent of these pathways, the blue line, the one that has global emissions dropping by 80% by 2050, as our reference, and reckon our calculations with respect to it. Delaying the peak, or slowing the subsequent rate of reductions, increases the risk of exceeding 2ºC

What does the Emergency Pathway mean for Southern development? 80% global reductions by 2050 What’s left for the South? The blue line is our global emergency pathway – the most most stringent of the three from the previous slide The green line is 90% (below 1990) by 2050, Gore’s trajectory, but across all of the A1 countries rather than just the US The purple line is the problem. This is where the tension between climate protection and development comes in. This is where the global climate policy impasse resides. NOTE: Relaxing the blue pathway doesn’t really change our results – unless you really relax it to blow off stringency Quick CYA: This slide approximates the North with A1 and the South with NA1 90% by 2050 in the North Greenhouse Development Right Framework

Income and Capacity National income distributions showing capacity (in green) as fraction of income above the development threshold India China US The curves here represent reasonable approximations of the income distributions within these three countries. Each chart arrays people from poorest to the richest member of these three countries. (We’ve constructed such curves for all countries, using the World Bank and World Income Inequality Databases of per-capita incomes and GINI coefficients, respectively.) The first thing to notice is the horizontal line at $9,000 that represents the development threshold You can see that a very small portion of India’s population, about 4% earns more than the $9,000 development threshold. (And the income above the threshold is about 4% of the aggregate national income.) A much larger portion, nearly 95%, of the US population earns more than the development threshold. (And the income above the threshold is about 80% of the aggregate national income.) China falls of course between these two. It’s total consuming class is almost the size of the US consuming class, but has a much smaller aggregate capacity. (About China’s 22% of population, 24% of aggregate national income.) It’s these green areas – income above the threshold – that represent our definition of national capacity. If we think of the burden sharing system as a global income tax, the development threshold can be thought of as marking a “0% tax bracket”, so as to shield the resources of those who’ve not yet reached the development threshold. On thing that is plainly obvious is that the US, despite its much smaller population, has the lion’s share of the capacity – and (you’ll see in a moment) a similarly disproportionate national obligation. The obligation falling on those members of the global consuming class residing in India and China is small enough that it might be reasonable to excuse them altogether. However, as a political matter, it is probably not possible to do so. It unlikely that the working consensus to pay a large proportion of the total mitigation and adaption bill could ever emerge in the US if the “wealthy” people in the Indian and Chinese nations were not also paying their “fair shares.” Ultimately, this “Greenhouse Development Rights” approach seeks to define, in quantifiable terms, such national fair shares – fair in the sense of safeguarding the right to development, by – again – shielding those below the line from the costs of action. The precisely analogous calculation can be done for responsibility…. $9,000/capita (PPP) “development threshold”

Cost of delay Mitigating carbon emissions is a slow process Once abatement proceeds, peak emissions will still not occur for ten or more years The longer the wait, the greater the risk factors associated with drastic climate change The longer the wait, the greater the costs associated with abatement

Abatement Opportunities I Reduce non-fossil fuel emissions Land use (deforestation) Halt deforestation especially in tropics Plant new forests Require enforcement & regulatory costs Require aid from developed world Agriculture Change tilling practices Produce bioenergy crops

Abatement Opportunities II Reduce Demand for Emission-intensive goods Primarily energy use in heating, transport, & electricity Pricing signals via taxes. Costs to atmosphere should be included in purchase of offending products Change preferences via information

Abatement Opportunities III Improve energy efficiency Power generation Energy use Efficient appliances & vehicles Greatest abatement potential may lie here.

Abatement Opportunities IV Switch to lower carbon emitting energy production Wind Wave & tidal Solar Carbon capture Hydrogen Nuclear Hydroelectric Bioenergy

Policy requirements Successful policy requires three elements: 1. Carbon pricing 2. Technology policy 3. Remove barriers to change

Carbon Pricing The cost of carbon emissions must be included in the pricing of carbon emitting goods This will result in: Less of the offending activity Incentives to find non-emitting alternatives Types of pricing Taxes Pros: creates revenues Cons: unpopular, does not directly control amount of emissions Carbon trading (cap & trade) Pros: efficient, directly controls amount of emissions Cons: does not create revenue

Technology Policy Public investment in R&D R&D subsidies encourage private firms to invest in risky technology Creation of new technologies become public goods which can be dispersed globally

Remove barriers to change Standards Where carbon pricing proves ineffective, regulatory standards may be useful Education Understanding of climate change and its consequences can shape future policy

Adaptation Strategies High-quality climate information Rainfall & storm patterns critical Land-use standards Infrastructure should account for climate change Climate sensitive public goods Natural resource & coastal protection Emergency readiness Social safety nets Those who are most vulnerable and cannot afford protection (insurance)

Collective Action Climate change is a global problem which will require: Building of effective institutions Shared understanding of long-term goals Leadership and trust

Thanks ! daniel.de.la.torre.ugarte@unctad.org danieltu@utk.edu Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change http://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/+/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/sternreview_index.htm