Chapter 5 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Advertisements

Price Discrimination A monopoly engages in price discrimination if it is able to sell otherwise identical units of output at different prices Whether a.
Chapter 5: Price Discrimination: Linear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing.
Modeling the Market Process: A Review of the Basics
Chapter 14 Advanced Pricing Techniques
Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Chapter Twelve Pricing.
Pricing with Market Power
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
1 Price Discrimination. 2 Introduction Price Discrimination describes strategies used by firms to extract surplus from customers.
Chapter 2: Basic Microeconomic Tools 1 Basic Microeconomic Tools.
© 2008 Pearson Addison Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter Twelve Pricing and Advertising.
Introduction A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. In this chapter, we study monopoly and contrast it with.
Monopoly - Characteristics
Departures from perfect competition
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Equilibrium and Efficiency
Chapter 15 APPLIED COMPETITIVE ANALYSIS Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
Perfect Competition & Welfare. Outline Derive aggregate supply function Short and Long run equilibrium Practice problem Consumer and Producer Surplus.
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Market Structures Monopoly. Monopoly  Defining monopoly  Only one seller  Barriers to entry  economies of scale  product differentiation and brand.
All Rights ReservedMicroeconomics © Oxford University Press Malaysia, – 1.
Monopoly. Chapter Outline ©2015 McGraw-Hill Education. All Rights Reserved. 2 Defining Monopoly Five Sources Of Monopoly The Profit-maximizing Monopolist.
Third degree price discrimination Welfare Analysis.
CHAPTER 14 Monopoly. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: The significance of monopoly, where a single monopolist is the only producer of a good How.
 Firm that is sole seller of product without close substitutes  Price Maker not a Price Taker  There are barriers to entry thru: Monopoly Resources,
The Optimal Mark-Up and Price Discrimination Outline The optimal mark-up over cost What is price discrimination? Examples of price discrimination When.
Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Topic 10: Price Discrimination
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
Econ Examples Plus Multimedia Welcome to this multimedia example. To navigate through this example you will need to click the appropriate green arrows.
Price Discrimination Price discrimination is the practice of selling different units of a good or service for different prices. To be able to price discriminate,
1 Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam Chapter 12: Pricing to Capture Surplus Value Prepared by Katharine Rockett © 2006 John.
Monopoly ETP Economics 101. Monopoly  A firm is considered a monopoly if...  it is the sole seller of its product.  its product does not have close.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Monopoly Chapter 12.
Copyright McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2002 Chapter 23: Pure Competition.
Econ 1711 Monopoly: No discrimination. Econ 1712 Marginal Revenue The only firm in the market –market demand is the firm’s demand –output decisions affect.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 14 Price Discrimination and Monopoly Practices.
Price Discrimination Monopoly Wrap-Up Chapter 15 Completion.
Chapter 11 Pricing with Market Power. Chapter 11Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Capturing Consumer Surplus Price Discrimination Intertemporal Price Discrimination.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency. What Makes a Market Competitive? Buyers and sellers have absolutely no effect on price Three characteristics: Absence.
Monopoly CHAPTER 12. After studying this chapter you will be able to Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly and price-discriminating.
Chapter 7: Pure Competition Copyright © 2007 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Lecture 3, Monopoly Price discrimination.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Chapter 14 Equilibrium and Efficiency McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Industrial Organization: Chapter 31 Chapter 3 Basic Monopoly Pricing and Product Strategies.
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 15 Monopoly. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price.
Monopoly Chapter 12. The Theory of Monopoly A firm is a monopoly if... There is one seller The single seller sells a product for which there is no close.
Chapter 11 Monopoly.
Review pages Explain what it means to say that the monopolist is a “price maker.” 2. Explain the relationship between output and price for.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior Price Discrimination Price discrimination: selling different units of output at different prices. First-degree price.
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.
Price Discrimination 1. Defined: Sellers engage in price discrimination when they charge different prices to different consumers for the same good, because.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
Pure (perfect) Competition Please listen to the audio as you work through the slides.
13 MONOPOLY. © 2012 Pearson Education A monopoly is a market:  That produces a good or service for which no close substitute exists  In which there.
Five Sources Of Monopoly
Chapter 15 Monopoly.
Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing
Lecture 6 Additional topics on monopoly
Lecture 5 Monopoly Pricing
Price Discrimination and Monopoly
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 5 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Linear Pricing

Introduction Prescription drugs are cheaper in Canada than the United States Textbooks are generally cheaper in Britain than the United States Examples of price discrimination presumably profitable should affect market efficiency: not necessarily adversely is price discrimination necessarily bad – even if not seen as “fair”?

Feasibility of price discrimination Two problems confront a firm wishing to price discriminate identification: the firm is able to identify demands of different types of consumer or in separate markets easier in some markets than others: e.g tax consultants, doctors arbitrage: prevent consumers who are charged a low price from reselling to consumers who are charged a high price prevent re-importation of prescription drugs to the United States The firm then must choose the type of price discrimination first-degree or personalized pricing second-degree or menu pricing third-degree or group pricing

Third-degree price discrimination Consumers differ by some observable characteristic(s) A uniform price is charged to all consumers in a particular group – linear price Different uniform prices are charged to different groups “kids are free” subscriptions to professional journals e.g. American Economic Review airlines the number of different economy fares charged can be very large indeed! early-bird specials; first-runs of movies

The pricing rule is very simple: consumers with low elasticity of demand should be charged a high price consumers with high elasticity of demand should be charged a low price Example 1 Demand: United States: PU = 36 – 4QU Europe: PE = 24 – 4QE Marginal cost constant in each market MC = $4 Let’s Consider no price discrimination case first. Suppose that the same price is charged in both markets.

Use the following procedure: calculate aggregate demand in the two markets identify marginal revenue for that aggregate demand equate marginal revenue with marginal cost to identify the profit maximizing quantity identify the market clearing price from the aggregate demand calculate demands in the individual markets from the individual market demand curves and the equilibrium price

The example 1 (npd cont.) United States: PU = 36 – 4QU Invert this: QU = 9 – P/4 for P < $36 Europe: PU = 24 – 4QE Invert At these prices only the US market is active QE = 6 – P/4 for P < $24 Aggregate these demands Q = QU + QE = 9 – P/4 for $36 < P < $24 Q = QU + QE = 15 – P/2 for P < $24 Now both markets are active

The example 1(npd cont.) Invert the direct demands $/unit P = 36 – 4Q for Q < 3 36 P = 30 – 2Q for Q > 3 Marginal revenue is 30 MR = 36 – 8Q for Q < 3 17 MR = 30 – 4Q for Q < 3 MR Demand Set MR = MC MC Q = 6.5 6.5 15 Quantity Price from the demand curve P = $17

The example 1 (npd cont.) Substitute price into the individual market demand curves: QU = 9 – P/4 = 9 – 17/4 = 4.75 million QE = 6 – P/4 = 6 – 17/4 = 1.75 million Aggregate profit = (17 – 4)x6.5 = $84.5 million

Example 2: with price discrimination The firm can improve on this outcome Check that MR is not equal to MC in both markets MR > MC in Europe MR < MC in the US the firms should transfer some books from the US to Europe This requires that different prices be charged in the two markets Procedure: take each market separately identify equilibrium quantity in each market by equating MR and MC identify the price in each market from market demand

The example 2: (pd cont.) Demand in the US: PU = 36 – 4QU $/unit Demand in the US: 36 PU = 36 – 4QU Marginal revenue: 20 MR = 36 – 8QU Demand MR MC = 4 4 MC Equate MR and MC 4 9 Quantity QU = 4 Price from the demand curve PU = $20

The example 2: (pd cont.) Demand in the Europe: PE = 24 – 4QU $/unit Demand in the Europe: 24 PE = 24 – 4QU Marginal revenue: 14 MR = 24 – 8QU Demand MR MC = 4 4 MC Equate MR and MC 2.5 6 Quantity QE = 2.5 Price from the demand curve PE = $14

The example 2 (pd cont.) Aggregate sales are 6.5 million books the same as without price discrimination Aggregate profit is (20 – 4)x4 + (14 – 4)x2.5 = $89 million $4.5 million greater than without price discrimination The above example assumes constant marginal cost How is this affected if MC is non-constant? Example 3 Suppose MC is increasing Recall No price discrimination procedure Calculate aggregate demand Calculate the associated MR Equate MR with MC to give aggregate output Identify price from aggregate demand Identify market demands from individual demand curves

Example 3 Applying this procedure assuming that MC = 0.75 + Q/2 gives: 5 10 20 30 40 D U MR 17 4.75 Price (a) United States Quantity 5 10 20 30 40 D E MR 1.75 17 Price (b) Europe Quantity 5 10 15 20 30 40 D MR MC 24 6.5 17 Price (c) Aggregate Quantity

Example 4 Price discrimination: non-constant cost With price discrimination the procedure is Identify marginal revenue in each market Aggregate these marginal revenues to give aggregate marginal revenue Equate this MR with MC to give aggregate output Identify equilibrium MR from the aggregate MR curve Equate this MR with MC in each market to give individual market quantities Identify equilibrium prices from individual market demands

Example 4 Applying this procedure assuming that MC = 0.75 + Q/2 gives: Price (a) United States Quantity 5 10 20 30 40 D U MR 4 Price (b) Europe Quantity 4 5 10 20 30 40 D E MR 1.75 14 Price (c) Aggregate Quantity 5 10 15 20 30 40 MR MC 24 6.5 17 4

Some additional comments Suppose that demands are linear price discrimination results in the same aggregate output as no price discrimination price discrimination increases profit For any demand specifications two rules apply marginal revenue must be equalized in each market marginal revenue must equal aggregate marginal cost

Price discrimination and elasticity Suppose that there are two markets with the same MC MR in market i is given by MRi = Pi(1 – 1/hi) where hi is (absolute value of) elasticity of demand From rule 1 (above) MR1 = MR2 so P1(1 – 1/h1) = P2(1 – 1/h2) which gives Price is lower in the market with the higher demand elasticity

Often arises when firms sell differentiated products hard-back versus paper back books first-class versus economy airfare Price discrimination exists in these cases when: “two varieties of a commodity are sold by the same seller to two buyers at different net prices, the net price being the price paid by the buyer corrected for the cost associated with the product differentiation.” (Phlips) The seller needs an easily observable characteristic that signals willingness to pay The seller must be able to prevent arbitrage e.g. require a Saturday night stay for a cheap flight

Product differentiation and price discrimination Suppose that demand in each submarket is Pi = Ai – BiQi Assume that marginal cost in each submarket is MCi = ci Finally, suppose that consumers in submarket i do not purchase from submarket j “I wouldn’t be seen dead in Coach!” “I never buy paperbacks.” Equate marginal revenue with marginal cost in each submarket Pi = (Ai + ci)/2 Ai – 2BiQi = ci  Qi = (Ai – ci)/2Bi  It is highly unlikely that the difference in prices will equal the difference in marginal costs  Pi – Pj = (Ai – Aj)/2 + (ci – cj)/2

Other mechanisms for price discrimination Impose restrictions on use to control arbitrage Saturday night stay no changes/alterations personal use only (academic journals) time of purchase (movies, restaurants) “Crimp” the product to make lower quality products Mathematica® Discrimination by location Suppose demand in two distinct markets is identical Pi = A - BQi But suppose that there are different marginal costs in supplying the two markets cj = ci + t

Third-degree rice discrimination and welfare Profit maximizing rule: equate MR with MC in each market as before  Pi = (A + ci)/2; Pj = (A + ci + t)/2  Pj – Pi = t/2  cj – ci difference in prices is not the same as the difference in marginal cost Third-degree rice discrimination and welfare Does third-degree price discrimination reduce welfare? not the same as being “fair” relates solely to efficiency so consider impact on total surplus

Price discrimination and welfare Suppose that there are two markets: “weak” and “strong” The discriminatory price in the weak market is P1 The discriminatory price in the strong market is P2 Price Price The maximum gain in surplus in the weak market is G D2 The minimum loss of surplus in the strong market is L The uniform price in both market is PU MR2 D1 P2 PU PU G L P1 MR1 MC MC ΔQ1 Quantity ΔQ2 Quantity

Price discrimination and welfare cannot increase surplus unless it increases aggregate output D1 MR1 D2 MR2 MC P1 P2 ΔQ1 ΔQ2 Price Quantity PU G L It follows that ΔW < G – L = (PU – MC)ΔQ1 + (PU – MC)ΔQ2 = (PU – MC)(ΔQ1 + ΔQ2)

Price discrimination and welfare (cont.) Previous analysis assumes that the same markets are served with and without price discrimination This may not be true uniform price is affected by demand in “weak” markets firm may then prefer not to serve such markets without price discrimination price discrimination may open up weak markets The result can be an increase in aggregate output and an increase in welfare

New markets: an example Demand in “North” is PN = 100 – QN ; in “South” is PS = 100 - QS Marginal cost to supply either market is $20 North South Aggregate $/unit $/unit $/unit 100 100 Demand MC MC MC MR Quantity Quantity Quantity

The example: continued Aggregate demand is P = (1 + )50 – Q/2 provided that both markets are served $/unit Aggregate Quantity MC Demand MR Equate MR and MC to get equilibrium output QA = (1 + )50 - 20 Get equilibrium price from aggregate demand P = 35 + 25 P QA

The example: continued $/unit Aggregate Quantity MC Demand MR Now consider the impact of a reduction in  Aggregate demand changes Marginal revenue changes PN It is no longer the case that both markets are served The South market is dropped D' Price in North is the monopoly price for that market MR'

The example again Previous illustration is too extreme Quantity $/unit Aggregate MC Demand MR MC cuts MR at two points So there are potentially two equilibria with uniform pricing At Q1 only North is served at the monopoly price in North PN At Q2 both markets are served at the uniform price PU PU Switch from Q1 to Q2: decreases profit by the red area increases profit by the blue area If South demand is “low enough” or MC “high enough” serve only North Q1 Q2

Price discrimination and welfare (cont.) In this case only North is served with uniform pricing Quantity $/unit Aggregate MC Demand MR Q1 PN But MC is less than the reservation price PR in South So price discrimination will lead to South being supplied PR Price discrimination leaves surplus unchanged in North But price discrimination generates profit and consumer surplus in South So price discrimination increases welfare

Price discrimination and welfare again Suppose only North is served with a uniform price Also assume that South will be served with price discrimination Welfare in North is unaffected Consumer surplus is created in South: opening of a new market Profit is generated in South: otherwise the market is not opened As a result price discrimination increases welfare.