Agenda Benefits Overview Travel Cost Method Random Utility Models

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Valuation 9: Travel cost model
Advertisements

Session 14 Non-Market Valuation
The Economics of Ecosystem Services Steve Polasky University of Minnesota.
Section 3: Some Basics, Econometrics, & Discounting Jisung Park: February (Based in part on slides by Liz Walker and.
Preview of 4 Coming Attractions Today: Derivation of the Demand Curve –Consumers (Buyers) Next: Derivation of the Supply Curve –Firms (Sellers) Later:
A Few Basic Principles of Economic Valuation of Ecosystem Services John Loomis Dept. of Ag & Resource Economics Colorado State University’ Fort Collins,
Valuation 2 and 3: Demand and welfare theory
INWEPF 4th Steering Meeting and Symposium (5-7 July 2007)
Revealed-preference methods
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
Assessing Benefits for Environmental Decision Making
Assessing Benefits for Environmental Decision Making Chapter 8 © 2007 Thomson Learning/South-WesternThomas and Callan, Environmental Economics.
BENEFIT-COST ANALYSIS
Basic Concepts in Economics: Theory of Demand and Supply
Economics 101: How to Measure Indirect Values Benjamin S. Rashford Agricultural and Applied Economics University of Wyoming.
Stated Preference & Experimental Markets Methods for measuring non-market benefits.
Valuing the Environment What exactly do economists mean when they talk about “valuing the environment” in monetary terms?
Continuation of benefit estimation and non-renewable resources Econ 1661 Review Section February 25 th, 2011 Robyn Meeks (Based on slides from Avinash.
 Homework #2 due Thursday  Exam #1 on Thursday  Writing Assignment due Oct. 27th.
1 Travel Costs Scott Matthews Courses: and Lecture /25/2004.
Evaluating the environment Gauri-Shankar Guha. Dr. Gauri-Shankar Guha ASU - Econ Evaluating the Environment For the individual, economic values.
Measuring Environmental Benefits: Revealed Preference Approaches Travel Cost, Hedonic Price, and Household Production Methods.
CHAPTER 12 VALUING IMPACTS FROM OBSERVED BEHAVIOR: DIRECT ESTIMATION OF DEMAND CURVES.
Costs and Benefits Andrew Foss Economics 1661 / API-135 Environmental and Resource Economics.
AGEC/FNR 406 LECTURE 14 Pesticide Runoff Potential from Field Crops.
AGEC 608 Lecture 13, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 13 Objective: Discuss various ways to estimate value of impacts using revealed preference approaches, highlighting.
AGEC 608 Lecture 14, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 14 Objective: Provide overview of contingent valuation method (CVM) and review strengths and weaknesses of.
Measuring Environmental Benefits: Revealed Preference Approaches Travel Cost and Hedonic Methods.
 Group Quiz Thursday  Homework #2 Due Next Thursday  Exam #1 Next Thursday  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 27th.
The Economic Approach to Environmental and Natural Resources, 3e
1 Civil Systems Planning Benefit/Cost Analysis Scott Matthews /
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
Valuation Methods focus on conventional market approaches Session Objectives: Identify key steps in valuing the environment Use selected methods to analyze.
AGEC 608 Lecture 03, p. 1 AGEC 608: Lecture 3 Objective: Review microeconomic foundations of CBA Readings: –Boardman, Chapter 3 –Kankakee, Section III.
 Homework #8 due Next Thursday  Group Outline due Nov. 11 (next Thurs.)
Valuing Changes in Environmental Amenities When the amenity is a quality characteristic of a privately consumed good The good’s price is not affected by.
ECMB36 LECTURE NOTES MEASURING CHANGES IN SOCIAL WELFARE Townley, Chapter 5.
Econ 231: Natural Resources and Environmental Economics SCHOOL OF APPLIED ECONOMICS.
1 Chapter 3 Willingness to Pay/Demand People’s tastes and preferences determine the values that people place on goods or services SECTION II Building Blocks.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Managerial Economics & Business Strategy
Welfare economics Outline Expressing changes in human well-being (utility) in monetary terms Deciding between monetary measures that are equally theoretically.
Valuation Discussion: Motivation, Concepts and Methods Emily McKenzie and Shan Ma.
Valuing Health Effects of Air Pollution in DevelopingCountries: The Case of Taiwan* JOURNAL OF ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT 34, 107 ]
Chapter 10 CBA and valuation1 CHAPTER 10 Cost-Benefit Analysis and Valuation.
Lecture 11: Valuation of Environmental Amenities
Matthew G. Interis, Mississippi State University Timothy C. Haab, The Ohio State University Willingness to Pay for Environmental Improvements in the Presence.
What I was doing on Thursday during class.... Measuring Environmental Benefits: Revealed Preference Approaches Travel Cost and Hedonic Methods.
Part II. Environmental Valuation
Travel Cost Model: an example Sittidaj Pongkivorasin Faculty of Economics, Chulalongkorn University.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand
On visible choice set and scope sensitivity: - Dealing with the impact of study design on the scope sensitivity Improving the Practice of Benefit Transfer:
Ecosystem Valuation Social and Environmental Aspects Kathryn Benson CE 397 November 25, 2003.
Outline of presentation Travel cost method – concept, example, assumptions Consumer surplus related to TCM Visitor’s table Demand curve Concerns regarding.
Managerial Economics Demand Estimation & Forecasting.
Contingent Valuation Methods See Boardman et al., Chapter 14 Interview individuals to elicit their preferences for different states of the world. Based.
Environmental Economics Class 4. Valuing the Environment: Methods Methodologies available for quantifying benefits and costs. Valuation techniques available.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Valuing the Environment: Methods.
Presented Jan 13, 2012 By Eric Miller W2 on W3 Pricing Damages ENVS 4510: Ecological Economics.
Measuring Environmental Benefits. In principle, benefits can be represented by consumer surplus, or the area under the demand curve: Market good sold.
Assessing Benefits for Environmental Decision Making Chapter 7.
Unit 2 Seminar “Holler if you hear me!”. Microeconomics What is this? – Small look – At what? Value Preferences Costs vs. benefits – Why? To help individuals,
© 2013 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Nonmarket Values Property, ideas and experiences can have “value” even if not exchanged in a market.
Economic valuation OF NATURAL RESOURCES
Economic Valuation of Environment: Overview
Environmental Demand Theory M Rafiq. Discussion Demand curve is an information on importance of a good for individual Out of limited income, allocation.
Chris Curington Hedonic pricing.
A Quick Intro to Non-Market Valuation
Return to Home Page GEOG 370 May 5,
Presentation transcript:

Benefit Estimation Methods Andrew Foss (andrew_foss@ksg09.harvard.edu) Economics 1661 / API-135 Environmental and Resource Economics and Policy Harvard University February 27, 2009 Review Section

Agenda Benefits Overview Travel Cost Method Random Utility Models Hedonic Pricing Models Contingent Valuation

Benefits Overview: Concepts Benefits in environmental economics reflect willingness to pay for improvements in environmental quality Measures for Environmental “Goods” (e.g., Fish Protection) Total Marginal Total Benefits (TB) = Total Willingness to Pay (WTP) Marginal Benefits (MB) = Marginal Willingness to Pay (MWTP) = Demand Measures for Environmental “Bads” (e.g., Fish Kills) Total Marginal Total Damages (TD) = Total Willingness to Accept (WTA) Marginal Damages (MD) = Marginal Willingness to Accept (MWTA)

Benefits Overview: Components Benefit Component Definitions (Two-Way Taxonomy) Use Value Non-use Value Market Use Value The value to society of using an environmental resource as a market product Existence Value The value to society of knowing that an environmental resource exists Altruism Value The value to society of knowing other people can use an env. resource Non-market Use Value The value to society of using an environmental resource not as a market product Bequest Value The value to society of knowing future generations can use an env. resource Option Value The value to society of having an option to use an env. resource

Benefits Overview: Estimation Methods Benefit Estimation Methods Use Value Non-use Value Market Use Value Market quantities and prices Existence, Altruism, Bequest, and Option Values Contingent valuation (CV) Contingent ranking Choice experiments Non-market Use Value Travel cost method, aka Hotelling-Clawson-Knetsch (HCK) Discrete choice models, aka random utility models (RUMs) Hedonic pricing models Revealed Preference Methods (maybe stated preference methods here as well) Stated Preference Methods

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Ruritania is a country with three cities and a beautiful park at its center Environmental economists in Ruritania have collected the following data on park visitors from the three cities The environmental economists want to estimate the recreational value (i.e., non-market use value) of the park to the people of Ruritania Origin Population Visitors Travel Cost 1 100,000 15,000 $12.50 2 750,000 75,000 $25.00 3 1,000,000 50,000 $37.50

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem First calculate the visitation rate for each origin Origin Population Visitors Visit Rate Travel Cost 1 100,000 15,000 0.15 $12.50 2 750,000 75,000 0.10 $25.00 3 1,000,000 50,000 0.05 $37.50

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Next plot the relationship between visitation rate and travel cost and express it in an equation TC = - (50 / 0.20) * R + 50 = -250 * R + 50 or R = - (0.20 / 50) * TC + 0.2 = -0.004 * TC + 0.2

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Suppose a fee were charged to enter the park Calculate the relationship between Origin 1’s visitation rate and the hypothetical fee R = -0.004 * (TC + Fee) + 0.2 TC1 = 12.5 R1 = -0.004 * (12.5 + Fee) + 0.2 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.15 or Fee = -250 * R1 + 37.5

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between Origin 2’s visitation rate and the hypothetical fee R = -0.004 * (TC + Fee) + 0.2 TC2 = 25 R2 = -0.004 * (25 + Fee) + 0.2 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.10 or Fee = -250 * R2 + 25

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between Origin 3’s visitation rate and the hypothetical fee R = -0.004 * (TC + Fee) + 0.2 TC3 = 37.5 R3 = -0.004 * (37.5 + Fee) + 0.2 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.05 or Fee = -250 * R3 + 12.5

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between all three origins’ visitation rate and the hypothetical fee R = -0.004 * (TC + Fee) + 0.2 R1 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.15 R2 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.10 R3 = -0.004 * Fee + 0.05

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between the number of visitors from Origin 1 and the hypothetical fee If Fee = 0, Q1 = 15,000 (status quo without any fee) If Fee = 37.5, Q1 = 0 (max fee anyone would pay) Q1 = - (15,000 / 37.5) * Fee + 15,000 Q1 = -400 * Fee + 15,000

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between the number of visitors from Origin 2 and the hypothetical fee If Fee = 0, Q2 = 75,000 (status quo without any fee) If Fee = 25, Q2 = 0 (max fee anyone would pay) Q2 = - (75,000 / 25) * Fee + 75,000 Q2 = -3,000 * Fee + 75,000

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between the number of visitors from Origin 3 and the hypothetical fee If Fee = 0, Q3 = 50,000 (status quo without any fee) If Fee = 12.5, Q3 = 0 (max fee anyone would pay) Q3 = - (50,000 / 12.5) * Fee + 50,000 Q3 = -4,000 * Fee + 50,000

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the relationship between the number of visitors from all three origins and the hypothetical fee Aggregate curve (from horizontal summation) represents total recreational demand as a function of hypothetic park fee Q1 = -400 * Fee + 15,000 Q2 = -3,000 * Fee + 75,000 Q3 = -4,000 * Fee + 50,000 Aggregate demand calculated by horizontal summation

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate recreational value as area under the aggregate curve The recreational value of the park is $1,531,250 Area A = ½ * (37.5 - 25) * 5,000 = 31,250 Area B = ½ * (25 - 12.5) * (5,000 + 47,500) = 328,125 Area C = ½ * (12.5 - 0) * (47,500 + 140,000) = 1,171,875 Total Area = 1,531,250

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate recreational value as area under each of the origin-specific demand curves (alternative method) The recreational value of the park is $1,531,250 Area 1 = ½ * 37.5 * 15,000 = 281,250 Area 2 = ½ * 25 * 75,000 = 937,500 Area 3 = ½ * 12.5 * 50,000 = 312,500 Total Area = 1,531,250

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the number of visitors and consumer surplus if no fee were charged to enter the park Total park visitation is 15,000 + 75,000 + 50,000 = 140,000 CS is equal to recreational value: $1,531,250

Travel Cost Method: Example Problem Calculate the number of visitors and consumer surplus if a fee of $20 were charged to enter the park Total park visitation is 7,000 (Or. 1) + 15,000 (Or. 2) = 22,000 CS is area below demand curve and above price: $98,750 Area A = ½ * (37.5 - 25) * 5,000 = 31,250 Area D = ½ * (25 - 20) * (5,000 + 22,000) = 67,500 Total Area = 98,750

Random Utility Models (RUMs) In RUMs for recreational fishing, anglers choose whether to go fishing, how many days to go fishing, where to go fishing, and what to fish for so as to maximize their utility Frank Lupi, “Case Study of a Travel-Cost Analysis: The Michigan Angling Demand Model,” 2001 (link)

Random Utility Models (RUMs) Increases in recreational fishing benefits due to environmental policies can be estimated from fish values derived from RUMs Frank Lupi, “Case Study of a Travel-Cost Analysis: The Michigan Angling Demand Model,” 2001 (link)

Hedonic Pricing Models Hedonic pricing models use the attributes of market products, including their environmental attributes, to explain variations in product prices P = f (x, z, e) P: price of market product (e.g., house) x: vector of non-env. product attributes (e.g., lot size, bedrooms) z: vector of non-env. local attributes (e.g., crime rate) e: environmental attribute (e.g., local air pollution) Marginal implicit price of environmental attribute or marginal willingness to pay for environmental attribute:

Hedonic Pricing Models Suppose we wanted to study the variation in housing prices due to proximity to an airport (which generates noise, a negative environmental externality) Price = β0 + β1*Bedrooms + β2*Bathrooms + β3*Airport + β4*Crime + β5*Scores + β6*Sold2008 + error Price: Sale price of house in dollars Number of Bedrooms Number of Bathrooms Near Airport: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the house is near the airport and 0 otherwise (so coefficient is not a slope in this case) Crime Rate: Annual number of incidents per 10,000 population Test Scores: Average test scores at public high school (out of 100) Sold in 2008: Dummy variable equal to 1 if the house sold this year

Hedonic Pricing Models Results of multiple regression On average, a house near the airport sells for $49,198 less than a house not near the airport, all else equal Fictional data

Hedonic Pricing Models Issues and problems Simultaneity: Prices are determined by both supply and demand, but these models treat supply as exogenous (i.e., unaffected by environmental attributes) Selection: Individuals differ in their tolerance of negative environmental attributes Information: Individuals’ perceptions of environmental attributes may differ from measurements Omitted variable bias: Coefficients are too large or small if an explanatory variable associated with the dependent variable and correlated with other explanatory variables is left out Scope: Relatively narrow range of applications

Contingent Valuation (CV) CV studies use carefully designed surveys to elicit from individuals the value they place on a change in an environmental amenity or service To perform CV studies well requires lots of time and money (and even then they may still be inaccurate) Clear definition of environmental amenity or service and change Clear identification of geographic scope of non-use value Focus groups Pretesting Sampling Analysis of results for reliability and validity

Contingent Valuation (CV) Example: Closed-Ended Question Ronald C. Griffin and James W. Mjelde, “Valuing Water Supply Reliability,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 82, No. 2 (2000), pp. 414-426

Contingent Valuation (CV) Example: Open-Ended Questions

Contingent Valuation (CV) NOAA Guidelines and Kerala CV Study Ronald C. Griffin et al., “Contingent Valuation and Actual Behavior: Predicting Connections to New Water Systems in the State of Kerala, India,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 9, No. 3 (1995), pp. 373-395

Contingent Valuation (CV) NOAA Guidelines and Kerala CV Study (continued)

Contingent Valuation (CV) Issues and problems Information: Respondents may not know much about the environmental amenity or service or the change Artificiality: Respondents may not give accurate values because the payment or acceptance is hypothetical Strategy: Respondents may not give accurate values because they want to influence environmental policy Anchoring: Responses may be sensitive to starting points Warm glow: Respondents may give accurately high values to make themselves feel good about their environmentalism