Engels’ Pause: A Pessimist’s Guide to the British Industrial Revolution Bob Allen Department of Economics Oxford University 2007.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
DOES ECONOMIC GROWTH ALWAYS REDUCE POVERTY? MARC WUYTS INSTITUTE OF SOCIAL STUDIES ERASMUS UNIVERSITY OF ROTTERDAM.
Advertisements

The Solow Model and Beyond
The Solow Model When 1st introduced, it was treated as more than a good attempt to have a model that allowed the K/Y=θ to vary as thus avoid the linear.
ECO 402 Fall 2013 Prof. Erdinç Economic Growth The Solow Model.
Advanced Macroeconomics:
Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-1 CHAPTER 4 The Theory of Economic Growth.
Chapter 11 Growth and Technological Progress: The Solow-Swan Model
22 Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand
Dr. Imtithal AL-Thumairi Webpage: The Neoclassical Growth Model.
The Changing Economic Perspectives on the Farm Problem – BRUCE L. GARDNER Gardner looks at the farm problem model and it’s the key contributions to the.
Chapter 17 Unemployment, Inflation, and Growth. 2 Introduction In Chapter 4, 5, 6, we have studied a classical model of the complete economy, but said.
Chapter 6: Economic Growth Estimate economic growth and implications of sustained growth for standard of living. Trends in economic growth in U.S. and.
Performance of World Economies
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND GROWTH: THE BASIC SOLOW MODEL Chapter 3 – first lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
1 Research on Immigration and Integration in the Metropolis
Performance of World Economies Gavin Cameron Monday 25 July 2005 Oxford University Business Economics Programme.
Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow
Objectives today Discuss how potential sources of growth are used in theories of economic development.
Economic Growth I: the ‘classics’ Gavin Cameron Lady Margaret Hall
2b: Growth and structural change 0. Overview Stylized facts of economic structure and structural change Simple 2-sector models of economic structure &
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Malthus and Solow.
Economic Growth Chapter 17. Introduction Two definitions of economic growth (from Chapter 8) – The increase in real GDP, which occurs over a period of.
APPLIED MACROECONOMICS. Outline of the Lecture Review of Solow Model. Development Accounting Going beyond Solow Model First part of the assignment presentation.
Innovation Economics Class 3.
Classical Theory of development. Classical Economics: Political Economy The pursuit of economic growth and development as a socially desirable goal is.
Copyright  2006 McGraw-Hill Australia Pty Ltd PPTs t/a Macroeconomics 2e by Dornbusch, Bodman, Crosby, Fischer, Startz Slides prepared by Dr Monica Keneley.
Economics 216: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department.
1 Copyright  2002 McGraw-Hill Australia Pty Ltd PPTs t/a Macroeconomics by Dornbusch, Bodman, Crosby, Fischer and Startz Slides prepared by Ed Wilson.
Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 4-1 The Theory of Economic Growth: The Solow Growth Model Reading: DeLong/Olney:
Production Function and Promoting Growth. The Production Function and Theories of Growth The production function shows the relationship between the quantity.
Chapter 17: Labor Productivity: Wages, Prices, and Employment
1 ECON203 Principles of Macroeconomics Week 6 Topic: ECONOMIC GROWTH Dr. Mazharul Islam.
Of 261 Chapter 26 Long-Run Economic Growth. of 262 Copyright © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc. Learning Objectives 3. List the main elements of Neoclassical.
Chapter 4 Growth and Policy Item Etc. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Macroeconomics, 10e © 2008 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved.
Production Functions. Students Should Be Able To Use the Cobb-Douglas production function to calculate: 1. Output as a product of inputs 2. marginal and.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 6 Economic Growth: Solow Model.
David Ricardo’s theory of rent
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 CAPITAL ACCUMULATION AND GROWTH: THE BASIC SOLOW MODEL Chapter 3 – second lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
Ecological Economics Lectures 04 and 05 22nd and 26th April 2010 Tiago Domingos Assistant Professor Environment and Energy Section Department of Mechanical.
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2005 TECHNOLOGICAL PROGRESS AND GROWTH: THE GENERAL SOLOW MODEL Chapter 5 – second lecture Introducing Advanced Macroeconomics:
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 26 Long-Run Economic Growth.
1 Production and Long-Term Growth. 2 Conceptualization This conceptualization is a way to organize your thinking to understand many complex interrelated.
Economics 121: The Macroeconomics of Development Lawrence J. Lau, Ph. D., D. Soc. Sc. (hon.) Kwoh-Ting Li Professor of Economic Development Department.
Neoclassical Growth Models. The Solow Growth Model Assumptions Neo-Classical Theory of growth has been Propounded by modern economist like Solow,Meade,
Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain what determines aggregate supply  Explain what determines aggregate demand  Explain.
Udviklingsøkonomi - grundfag Lecture 4 Convergence? 1.
AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION Chapter 25 1.
Why is productivity growth so vital? To see more of our products visit our website at Ruth Tarrant, Head of Economics and Politics, Bedales.
Chapter 25: The Difference Between Short-Run and Long-Run Macroeconomics Copyright © 2014 Pearson Canada Inc.
Part IIB. Paper 2 Michaelmas Term 2009 Economic Growth Lecture 2: Neo-Classical Growth Model Dr. Tiago Cavalcanti.
7 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY CHAPTER.
Long-run Economic Growth. Real GDP per Capita Real GDP per Capita Real GDP per Capita Not a policy goal unto itself.
Macroeconomic Equilibrium
Advanced Macroeconomics:
Slides prepared by Ed Wilson
Chapter 7: Growth effects and factor market integration The Union has today set itself a new strategic goal for the next decade: to become the most.
Chapter 6: Economic Growth
The Theory of Economic Growth
Extension Chapter 5 The economics of growth
Bob Allen Department of Economics Oxford University 2007
Advanced Macroeconomics:
22 ECONOMIC GROWTH.
Two-Sector Models of Economic Growth
ECON 562 Macroeconomic Analysis & Public Policy
Chapter 6: Economic Growth
International Trade and Economic Growth
Chapter 6 ECONOMIC GROWTH.
Advanced Macroeconomics:
Classical Theory of development
AS-AD curves: how natural is the natural rate of unemployment?
Presentation transcript:

Engels’ Pause: A Pessimist’s Guide to the British Industrial Revolution Bob Allen Department of Economics Oxford University 2007

Our knowledge of the macro-economics of the British I.R. is much greater than 50 years ago: Growth rate of per capita income was low (less than 1.5% per annum) but sustained, so income rose 82% between 1760 and Investment rate rose from 6% to 12%. However, growth accounting shows productivity growth accounts for the rise in income per head. Nevertheless, it is important to remember how bad the data are!

What about inequality? We can measure it with variables in 1850s prices. Indices of real GDP, wages, and rents are used to run 1850s values back to 1760—giving series in 1850s prices. Real input series: occupied population, acres of improved farm land, and capital stock in 1850s prices. Capital income, rate of return, and factor shares computed from these figures.

Inequality followed a two-stage process as described by Kuznets and Lewis. Up to the 1840s, wages did not keep up with output per worker, the profit rate rose, and factor shares shifted against labour. After the 1840s, wages rose in pace with output, profits and factor shares stabilized. Why did the economy function like this?

Two phase development process implied by Allen’s revision of Feinstein’s real wage series: < = Wages falling behind output growthWages rising with output = > Engels’ Pause

Historical Factor Shares,

Historical Profit Rate,

How can the two phase history of inequality be explained? Lewis proposed a two sector model—many problems. –Zero marginal product of labour in agriculture? –Agriculture was only 35% of British economy in –I retain the assumption that savings come out of profits. Marx emphasized labour augmenting technical change. Malthus emphasized induced population growth.

A standard one sector macro model with savings a function of property income explains the essential facts: Alternative, Kalecki or Kaldor savings function:

Marginal products equal input prices, which are also related to shares: With the I=sY savings function, ‘growth’ and ‘distribution’ are separable. With the Kaldor function, they are interdependent.

Calibrating the Savings Function For the simple Keynesian function I = sY, s is computed as the time series of I/Y. The Kaldor function fits the data better: –Budget data show workers did not save. –The ratio of savings to property income was largely trendless.

Historical Savings Rate out of Property Income

Regression with data for shows a slightly greater propensity to save out of profits than rents: I/Y =.138 φ T φ K (.013) (.014) This regression, slightly modified for , was used in simulations.

Two production functions considered. Cobb-Douglas: The problem with the Cobb-Douglas is that it imposes constant shares.

So I use the translog:

Logarithmic differentiation gives the share equations: These are the basis for calibrating the model.

The translog production function was calibrated in two stages. First a Cobb-Douglas was calibrated and used to work out the trajectory of labour augmenting technological change: – :.3% per year – : 1.5% per year – : 1.7% per year These values were used to calibrated the translog.

Calibrating the translog Substituting values for two years (1760 and 1860) gives six equations in six unknowns. The other parameters can be calculated from the restrictions.

Values of translog coefficients:

How well does the translog work? actual and simulated GDP

To test the model as a whole, we must see if it replicates the key features of the industrial revolution. The model does a good job!

Actual and Simulated Investment Rate

The model simulates the two phase pattern of British industrialization:

The model does pretty well simulating factor shares:

And the profit rate:

And the rent of land:

Why did inequality rise ( ) and then stabilize ? The answer turns on properties of the production function and savings function.

The translog production function has a special property with important implications: Elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is very low (about.2). This means that technical progress required capital accumulation to be effective. The low elasticity of substitution is also a key to explaining why inequality rose.

Translog and Cobb-Douglas Isoquants in 1810 illustrate low elasticity of substitution:

The elasticity of substitution and the process of economic growth: By itself, neither the rise in savings nor the rise in productivity growth would have caused per capita income to increase much. This is because of the low elasticity of substitution between capital and labour. Without complementary capital formation, the rise in productivity would not have raised output. The ‘sources of growth’ identified by growth accounting are artificial.

Alternative Growth Simulations

The low elasticity of substitution is also key to explaining inequality. Productivity growth accelerated after 1800 raising the ratio of augmented labour to capital. Hence, the marginal product of capital rose. Low elasticity of substitution meant that the share of capital rose. This explains the rise in inequality.

The rise in inequality was undone by the same forces. The rise in the share of capital increased saving since it depended on property income. More savings raised investment in response to the increase in its demand due to the productivity growth. Capital/augmented labour rose and converged to steady state growth with rising real wages and constant shares. This is why inequality went through two phases.

What about the explanations of Marx and Malthus? We can explore them by simulating the model. Marx’s view is tested by eliminating labour augmenting technical change. Malthus’ view is tested by eliminating population growth. Both factors were necessary for the rise in inequality.

Without the productivity growth, factor shares would have been much more stable: But there wouldn’t have been an Industrial Revolution either!

Productivity growth without population growth is the more interesting scenario: Output per worker would have risen at historical rates. The real wage would have risen at the historical rate: no Engels’ pause. Unchanged factor shares Only a modest rise in the savings rate since capital was not needed to house and equip a growing population.

Compare simulated output per worker and real wage, which now rise together:

With constant population, factor shares would also have remained constant:

Two points on Malthus & Marx It looks like Malthus was right and population growth explains wage stagnation, but population grew almost as fast after 1850 as before. The problem is that rapid population growth plus labour augmenting TC cut capital per efficiency unit of labour. This moved the economy off a steady state growth path. Rising inequality led to more investment, which brought the economy back to steady state growth even with rapid population growth. Marx was right that rising inequality and capital acccumulation were interconnected pre-1848, but the sequel was rising real wages as accumulation caught up with augmented labour—not further immiseration and revolution! The model of this paper explains history better than Malthus and Marx.

We can tell the story of the IR like this: Rise in productivity was the prime mover. It increased the demand for capital. The upsurge in population also increased the demand for capital. Rate of return rose and shifted income to capitalists since the elasticity of substitution was so low. The income shift raised savings allowing growth to occur.

The savings response was sluggish so that the real wage stagnated. Inequality and accumulation were connected because the wealthy saved so little—not because they saved so much. Rising productivity and population growth plus a sluggish supply of capital meant that Britain experienced the rising part of the Kuznets curve. Eventually enough capital was accumulated so that balanced growth proceeded with wages rising in step with productivity.