Voting, Spatial Monopoly, and Spatial Price Regulation Economic Inquiry, Jan, 1992, 29-39 MH Ye and M. J. Yezer Presentation Date: 06/Jan/14.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
5 EFFICIENCY AND EQUITY CHAPTER.
Advertisements

1 Spatial Pricing Decisions Chapter 6. 2 Transport costs and distance Delivered price (mill price + transport costs): changes with distance Uniform delivered.
Chapter Twenty-Five Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? u So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at.
By Ronald R. Braeutigam & John C. Panzar Presented by Fadhila Diversification Incentives under “price-based” and “cost-based” Regulation.
Peak load pricing in the electric utility industry John T. Wenders Date: March 28,2013 Presented by Tej Gautam.
By: John T. Wenders Ama Agyeiwaa Ferkah Eco 435. INTRODUCTION  The traditional theory of peak-load pricing argues that peak period users should bear.
12 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Monopoly.
Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition
LEON COURVILLE Regulation and Efficiency in the Electric Utility Industry.
Chapter 6 and 7 Study Guide.
Market size and tax competition Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano, Tanguy van Ypersele.
Chapter 14 Advanced Pricing Techniques
Natural Monopolies and Regulation. Natural Monopoly In markets with a natural monopoly there may be one firm. Economies of scale indicate that at marginal.
15 Monopoly.
Competition and Specialization in the Hospital Industry: An Application of Hotelling’s Location Model A paper by Paul S. Calem and John A. Rizzo Southern.
Monopoly While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered a monopoly if it is the sole seller of.
Monopoly A monopoly is a single supplier to a market
Monopoly Example 2 - Haircuts
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Figure 8.2 How a Competitive Firm Maximizes Profit
The Production Decision of a Monopoly Firm Alternative market structures: perfect competition monopolistic competition oligopoly monopoly.
Chapter 24: Monopoly Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
John R. Swinton, Ph.D. Center for Economic Education Georgia College & State University.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Economic Applications of Functions and Derivatives
CHAPTER 14 Monopoly. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: The significance of monopoly, where a single monopolist is the only producer of a good How.
Presented by: Fadhila MICHAEL C. NAUGHTON. Purpose  Develop and demonstrate a method for deriving and testing regulatory preferences within and across.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
Monopoly CHAPTER 15.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western Monopoly vs. Competition While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker. A firm is considered.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 12 Economic Efficiency and Public Policy.
Chapter 15 notes Monopolies.
The Market Economy. Learning Objectives Define Economics and Economic system Define equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity Explain why the price of.
Monopoly with Incomplete Information Eric Maskin and John Riley The RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 15, No. 2 (Summer, 1984), pp Presented by:
Monopoly and market power. 2 Introduction Definition of a monopoly Profit maximization Substitutes, elasticities and market power Suboptimal allocation.
Monopoly Demand Curve  The industry and the firm are the same  The demand curve is downsloping.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 14 Price Discrimination and Monopoly Practices.
CHAPTER 14 Monopoly PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
Principles of Economics Ohio Wesleyan University Goran Skosples Monopoly 10. Monopoly.
Industrial Organization- Matilde Machado The Hotelling Model Hotelling Model Matilde Machado.
SAYRE | MORRIS Seventh Edition Monopoly CHAPTER © 2012 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 25 Monopoly Behavior.
Parallel Trade and the Pricing of Pharmaceutical Products Frank Müller-Langer Conference on „Health Economics and the Pharmaceutical Industry“
LECTURER: JACK WU The Theory of Property Tax. Outline Topic I: What Are Property Taxes? Topic II: Property Tax Incidence Topic III: Property Tax Capitalization.
Slide 1Copyright © 2004 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited Chapter 12 Monopoly.
Copyright © 2006 Thomson Learning 15 Monopoly. Figure 1 Economies of Scale as a Cause of Monopoly Copyright © 2004 South-Western Quantity of Output Average.
1 Infrastructure Investment and Skill Distribution in a System of Cities Hesham M. Abdel-Rahman University of New Orleans Department of Economics and.
Hall & Leiberman; Economics: Principles And Applications, Market Structure Sellers want to sell at the highest possible price Buyers want to buy.
February 9, 2008 GLOPE-TCER Joint Junior Workshop 1 Interregional Mixed Duopoly, Location and Welfare Tomohiro Inoue*, Yoshio Kamijo and Yoshihiro Tomaru.
Chapter 2: The Role of Economics
Review pages Explain what it means to say that the monopolist is a “price maker.” 2. Explain the relationship between output and price for.
I borrowed some of the figures and equations in this lecture from Yohanes E. Riyanto, an associate professor at Nanyang Technological University in Singagpore.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 6 Chapter Household Behavior.
Price Discrimination 1. Defined: Sellers engage in price discrimination when they charge different prices to different consumers for the same good, because.
Chapter 25 Monopoly Behavior. How Should a Monopoly Price? So far a monopoly has been thought of as a firm which has to sell its product at the same price.
1 Product Variety under Monopoly. 2 Introduction Most firms sell more than one product Products are differentiated in different ways  horizontally goods.
Chapter: 14 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Monopoly.
Monopoly 15. Monopoly A firm is considered a monopoly if... it is the sole seller of its product. it is the sole seller of its product. its product does.
Micro Review Day 3 and 4. Perfect Competition 14 A Perfectly Competitive Market For a market to be perfectly competitive, six conditions must be met:
Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth Presenter: Dai, Qian.
Welfare Analysis of Parallel Trade Freedom 1/16 An Analysis of the Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom Frank Müller-Langer International Max Planck.
14-1 Learning Objectives  Explain why uniform pricing does not generate maximum possible total revenue and how price discrimination can generate more.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior.
Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition & Oligopoly
15 Monopoly.
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Lecture 6 Additional topics on monopoly
15 Monopoly.
Chapter 24: Pure Monopoly
Economic Problems 4/18/2019.
Presentation transcript:

Voting, Spatial Monopoly, and Spatial Price Regulation Economic Inquiry, Jan, 1992, MH Ye and M. J. Yezer Presentation Date: 06/Jan/14

Abstract Regulation often require that local public utilities engage in high rates of freight absorption These regulations are shown to arise logically as a consequence of self-interest voting behavior Consumer may change their delivered price by voting to require a rate of freight absorption Voting outcomes under a median voter model predict the high rate of freight absorption often observed in practice

I Introduction While literature on spatial monopoly and regulated firms are large, very little attention has been given to the study of regulations affecting the spatial monopolist Regulated spatial monopolies could include either public or private production of many services Indeed the analysis could be adapted to mass transportation systems providing access to a center It is common to see that regulations on the spatial monopolist require uniform delivered pricing in which the firm must absorb most or all transportation costs

Motivation It appears that regulated freight absorption by the spatial monopolist is one of those cases that everyone knows but which no one has bothered to analyze in detail

An Economic Analysis of Regulated Freight Absorption Requires The reaction of a spatial monopolist to the full range of requirements for freight absorption, from zero to full absorption, be available But no such treatment in the literature yet

The First Objective of This Paper To fill the gap by analyzing the effects of continuous variation in freight absorption on price, output, profits, consumers ’ surplus and total welfare

The Results Obtained Are Rather Surprising The unregulated profit-maximizing spatial monopolist is found to be a knife-edge case in which second-order conditions are not satisfied Welfare maximization is achieved by regulating the rate of freight absorption so that it lies between zero and the rate practiced by an unregulated firm

Construct a Voting Model Having determined the effects of alternative freight absorption regulations on the firm, this paper then construct a voting model in which spatially distributed consumer-voters choose the rate of regulated freight absorption The spatial distribution of consumer surplus is used to generate voter preferences regarding the regulated level of freight absorption

Spatial Surplus Surface Analysis This analytical approach shows that the median voter prefers a high level of freight absorption The regulatory outcome most often observed

Consumer Voters Choose These voters choose freight absorption regulations with higher required rates of freight absorption than practiced by an unregulated spatial monopolist engaged in spatial price discrimination

The Voting Outcome This outcome lowers both total welfare and total consumers ’ surplus below the levels obtained under unregulated spatial monopoly

II Model of the Spatial Monopolist: Assumptions A given linear market characterized by location along X A single plant located at point 0 Producing and distributing a homogenous product, q, to consumers distributed at uniform density across the market Resale is not possible

Demand side Total quantity demanded at distance r is given by P(r) is the delivered price, P(r) = P(0)+etr

Cost side

The voting behavior The voting behavior of consumers is motivated by an attempt to maximize their personal consumer surplus

III standard results on the behavior of the spatial monopolist First consider the production and pricing decision of the unregulated spatial monopolist maximizing profit The monopolist chooses a market radius R, selects P(0) and determines e

Producer surplus

Consumer surplus

Well-known result For linear demand, the level of e which maximizes profit is 0.5 Welfare maximization implies maximization of  +S, which has been shown to required e =1 Other well-understood results involve the case of e = 0, which is often prompted by regulation

IV regulating freight absorption by the spatial monopolist The major object of this study is the effect of regulations controlling the level of transportation cost absorption Given that welfare is maximized at e=1,and firm profit is maximized at e=0.5, it is curious that regulations commonly require that the monopolist set e=0. Our analysis is designed to determine if voter self- interest and knowledge of the effects of e on consumer surplus can lead to regulations requiring low values of e

To determine the effect of variation in e Treat e as a parameter and use standard maximizing techniques For purposes of comparison with results already in the literature, outcomes obtained for specific values of e=0.5, e=1, and e=0 will be noted using subscripts 0.5, 1, and 0 respectively and w will indicate a result that maximizes welfare

Proposition1 A single-plant spatial monopolist under transportation cost absorption regulation will charge the choke price at r = R if regulated e is relatively large; otherwise it will charge a price less than the choke price at r = R if regulated e is relatively small

Proposition 2 Regarding the maximum market radius of the single-plant spatial monopolist under transportation cost absorption regulation

Figure 1

Proposition 3 Concerning total output,

Proposition 4 Total consumer surplus generated by the single-plant spatial monopolist under alternative transportation cost regulations follows

Figure 2

Proposition 5 Profit of the single-plant spatial monopolist under alternative transportation cost regulations ranges from

Proposition 6 Welfare associated with the regulated single- plant spatial monopolist varies as

Figure 3

V consumer voting and regulated transportation cost absorption Mueller(1989), if consumer welfare can be reduced to a single metric, voting outcomes on regulation are determined by the median voter The spatial distribution of consumer ’ s surplus for different values of transportation cost absorption is given by s( r, e ), displayed in Figure 4

Figure 4

Consumer-voters Voting behavior of consumers located at a particular r is motivated by an attempt to maximize surplus generated by different rate of transportation cost absorption Finding e*( r ),which maximizes consumer surplus for voters at a given r Conceptually, slicing the spatial surplus surface along a given r and determining the level of e

Median voter The median voter preference is for e = 0.33 While voters consider only their own self interest, the final outcome appears to have an obvious element of cross-subsidy. Voters living from 0 to are forced to subsidize those living past 0.357

Figure 5

Surprising voting outcome The high rate of freight absorption selected by the median voter is inconsistent with a maximum of profit, welfare, or consumers ’ surplus Indeed consumers ’ surplus is lower at the e = 0.33 level selected by voters than when the unregulated profit-maximizing firm engages in spatial price discrimination and sets e =0.5 The median voter selects such high freight absorption that consumers near the maximum market radius are cut off from service

VI Summary and Conclusions It is common to find a regulatory requirement that spatial monopolists absorb most transportation cost, i.e. that they engage in uniform delivered pricing Given this is a clear departure from marginal cost pricing, the conclusion that it is not consistent with welfare maximization follows easily

contribution The results presented here extend in several ways and provided a voting model which explains the political pressure for uniform pricing schemes Merging theoretical models of the spatial firm with regulatory and voting analysis in a manner not previously reported in the literature, this paper obtain a variety of original and interesting results

Results Analysis of the effect of varying e over the entire choice set shows that uniform pricing minimize both firm profits and total consumer surplus Internal welfare maximization is achieved with fairly low levels of transportation cost absorption The spatial distribution of consumer surplus generated by alternative levels of transportation cost absorption is such that the median voter prefers regulations requiring very high levels of absorption

Suggestions