Public Choice and Public Goods

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
© 2003 Prentice Hall Business PublishingEconomics: Principles and Tools, 3/eOSullivan/Sheffrin Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano CHAPTERCHAPTER.
Advertisements

© 2013 Pearson. Can the President repeal the laws of supply and demand?
EYE ONS How powerful is the presidents pen? Can the President sign an order that caps executive pay? Or sign an order that ensures every worker gets a.
Notes appear on slides 5, 7, 8, 9, 25, and 26.
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Public Goods and Common Resources
Chapter 16 Public Goods and Public Choice © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
Market Regulation1 MARKET REGULATION Economics 2023 Principles of Microeconomics Dr. McCaleb.
The Economics of Collective Decision Making
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Ch 31: Public Choice Economic Theory Applied to Politics
Principles of Micro Chapter 11: Public Goods and Common Resources by Tanya Molodtsova, Fall 2005.
The role of government Today: Public goods; government failure; taxation.
© 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing The Economic Way of Thinking, 11/e Heyne/Boettke/Prychitko “The Economic Way of Thinking” 11 th Edition Chapter.
Public Goods and Public Choice
16 CHAPTER Public Goods and Common Resources.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Distinguish among private goods, public goods,
The U. S. Economy: Private and Public Sectors
1 Fiscal Policy CHAPTER 12 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Demand and Supply Analysis
Chapter 16 Public Goods and Public Choice © 2009 South-Western/ Cengage Learning.
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Chapter 11: Cost-Benefit Analysis Econ 330: Public Finance Dr
Public Choice Chapter 6 (Part 2).
12 MONOPOLY CHAPTER.
Imperfect Competition and Market Power: Core Concepts Defining Industry Boundaries Barriers to Entry Price: The Fourth Decision Variable Price and Output.
1 Demand and Supply Analysis CHAPTER 3 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
7 PART 3 Government Influences on Markets
Part III Ten Elements of Clear Thinking About Economic Progress and the Role of Government.
ENTREPRENEURS IN A MARKET ECONOMY
Theme 4 - Public Goods Public Economics.
Chapter 5: The Public Sector and Public Choice ECON 152 – PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Materials include content from Pearson Addison-Wesley which has.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
Ch.31 Public Choice Theory and the Economics of Taxation
Chapter 16Copyright ©2009 by South-Western, a division of Cengage Learning. All rights reserved 1 ECON Designed by Amy McGuire, B-books, Ltd. McEachern.
Externalities and Public Goods
Chapter 6 Equity and Income Distribution
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
7 Government Influences on Markets CHAPTER. 7 Government Influences on Markets CHAPTER.
Supply and Demand Chapter 3 Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
ORGANIZING PRODUCTION 9 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain what a firm is and describe the economic problems.
Ch.2sec.1 Economic System & Economic Tools The three questions that all economic systems must answer. What should the economy produce? How should this.
1 Chapter 3 Economic Decision Makers These slides supplement the textbook, but should not replace reading the textbook.
1 Resource Markets CHAPTER 11 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Economics of Crime and its Prevention How Much is too Much?
18 CHAPTER Taxation and Redistribution PUBLIC SECTOR ECONOMICS: The Role of Government in the American Economy Randall Holcombe.
Micro Chapter 29 Presentation 1- Tax Incidence. Public Choice Theory Economic analysis of government decision making, politics and elections ***majority.
MONOPOLY 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Explain how monopoly arises and distinguish between single-price monopoly.
Chapter 5 Decision Making in the Public Sector Chapter outline 1 . Differences Between the Public and Private Sectors 2 . Voting and Public Choice 3 .
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
REVIEW FOR THE ECONOMICS Semester Exam
18 | Public Economy Voter Participation and Costs of Elections Special Interest Politics Flaws in the Democratic System of Government.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Distinguish between value and price and define.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
1 Chapter 22 The Public Sector Key Concepts Key Concepts Summary Practice Quiz Internet Exercises Internet Exercises ©2002 South-Western College Publishing.
Government Influences on Markets CHAPTER 7 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1Explain.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain how a rent ceiling creates a housing shortage,
Evaluating Monopoly Comparison with Perfect Competition.
© 2012 Pearson Education. 16 PUBLIC CHOICES AND PUBLIC GOODS.
1 CH2_Part II. 2 Externalities as a Source of Market Failure Exclusivity is one of the chief characteristics of an efficient property rights structure.
16 Public Goods and Common Resources Notes and teaching tips: 13.
Markets in Action CHAPTER 7 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain how a price.
WHAT ROLE DOES THE GOVERNMENT PLAY???. WHAT DOES THE GOVERNMENT PROVIDE FOR IN A MARKET ECONOMY? The government provides goods and services such as military.
PUBLIC SECTOR ECONOMICS: The Role of Government in the American Economy Randall Holcombe 9 CHAPTER Supply and Demand in Political Markets.
Copyright © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.10-1 Chapter 10 The Public Sector.
Public Goods and Public Choice
Public Goods and Public Choice
Public Goods and Public Choice
Public Finance: Expenditures and Taxes
Presentation transcript:

Public Choice and Public Goods CHAPTER 16 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning

Introduction In most of our previous discussions, we have been talking about private goods Private goods have two important features They are rival in consumption  the amount consumed by one person is unavailable for others to consume They are exclusive  suppliers can easily exclude those who don’t pay

Public Goods Public goods, such as national defense, the Center for Disease Control, or a neighborhood mosquito-control program are Nonrival in consumption  one person’s consumption does not diminish the amount available to others  once produced, such goods are available to all in equal amount  the marginal cost of providing the good to additional consumers is zero Once a public good is produced, suppliers cannot easily deny it to those who fail to pay  it is nonexclusive

Public Goods Because they are nonrival and nonexclusive, for-profit firms cannot profitably sell public goods In this case of market failure, government can improve the situation by providing public goods and paying for them through enforced taxation

Classification of Goods An economy consists of more than just private and public goods Some goods are nonrival but exclusive For example, additional households can watch a TV show without affecting the TV reception of other viewers

Classification of Goods Along the same lines, short of the point of congestion, additional people can benefit from a golf course, swimming pools, and so on These goods, when not congested, are non rival, yet producers can, with relative ease, exclude those who don’t pay the greens fees, pool admission, etc. Once congestion sets in, these quasi-public goods become private goods

Classification of Goods Some other goods are rival but nonexclusive The fish in the ocean are rival in the sense that once caught they are not available for others to catch  are rival However, these goods are nonexclusive in the sense that it would be costly or impossible for a private firm to prevent access to these goods  open-access goods Exhibit 1 offers a matrix for all goods

Exhibit 1: Categories of Private and Public Goods Rival Nonrival Across the top, goods are either rival or nonrival. Down the left, goods are either exclusive or nonexclusive. 1.Private Goods 2.Quasi-Public Goods —pizza —Cable TV —crowded Exclusive swimming —uncrowded pool swimming pool Open-access goods are usually regulated by government, and public goods are usually provided by government. 3.Open-Access 4.Public Goods Goods —national defense Nonexclusive —ocean fish —mosquito control —migratory birds

Optimal Provision of Public Goods Because private goods are rival in consumption, the market demand for a private good is the sum of the quantities demanded by each consumer  horizontal sum of all individual demand curves The efficient quantity of a private good occurs where the market demand curve intersects the market supply curve

Optimal Provision of Public Goods But since a public good is nonrival in consumption, the good, once produced, is available to all consumers in an identical amount Therefore, the market demand curve for a public good is the vertical sum of each consumer’s demand for the public good To arrive at the efficient level of the public good, we find where the market demand curve intersects the marginal cost curve

Optimal Provision of Public Goods Suppose the public good in question is mosquito control in a neighborhood, which, or simplicity, consists of only two houses One is headed by Alan and the other by Maria Alan spends a lot of time in the yard, thus values a mosquito-free environment more than does Maria Exhibit 2 shows their demand curves

Exhibit 2: Market for Public Goods Da and Dm are the respective demand curves reflecting the marginal benefits that Alan and Maria, respectively, enjoy at each rate of output. 5 2 e Marginal cost 10 $15 Da How much mosquito spraying should the government provide? Suppose the marginal cost of spraying is a constant $15 an hour. The efficient level of output is found where the marginal benefit to the neighborhood equals the marginal cost  2 hours per week. Dollars per hour Dm D Hours of mosquito spraying per week

Optimal Provision of Public Goods The government pays for the mosquito spray through taxes, user fees, or some combination of the two The efficient approach would be to impose a tax on each resident equal to his or her marginal valuation. There are, however, two problems with this Once people realize their taxes are based on how much the government thinks they value the good, people tend to understate their true valuation

Optimal Provision of Public Goods Why admit you really value the good if, as a result, you get a higher tax bill? Taxpayers are reluctant to offer this information, creating what is called the free-rider problem The free-rider problem occurs because people try to benefit from a public good without paying for it For example, all will benefit from the mosquito abatement program, whether they pay or not Even if the government had accurate information about marginal valuations, some households earn much more than others  a greater ability to pay taxes Taxing people according to their marginal valuations may be efficient, but it may not be considered fair or equitable

Public Choice in Representative Democracy Government decisions about the provision of public goods and the collection of tax revenues are public choices In a democracy, public choices usually require approval by a majority of voters We can frequently explain the choice of the electorate with majority rule by focusing on the preferences of the median voter

Median-Voter Model The median voter is the one whose preferences lie in the middle of the set of all voters’ preferences The median-voter model predicts that under certain circumstances, the preference of the median, or middle voter will dominate other choices To see the logic of this, consider the following situation

Median-Voter Model Suppose we have three individuals who are trying to decide whether to buy a TV and, if so, of what size The problem is that each of the individuals have different preferences Suppose we let N = no TV, S = small TV, and L = large TV, and p  preferred Person 1: N p S p L Person 2: L p S p N Person 3: S p L p N

Median-Voter Model All agree to make the decision by voting on two alternatives at a time, then pairing the winner against the remaining alternative until one dominates the other When the small set is paired against the no-TV option, the small set wins by getting the vote of individuals 2 and 3 Then when the small set is paired against the large TV it also wins because individuals 1 and 3 approve

Median-Voter Model Person 3, the median voter in this case, gets his most preferred choice In fact, even if person 3 had preferred the large TV, he would have gotten his choice This same principle often holds in public choices  political candidates try to get elected by appealing to the median voter

Median-Voter Model This is one reason why candidates often seem so much alike Other voters are required to go along with what the median voter wants Thus other voters usually end up paying for what they consider to be either too much or too little of the public good  welfare cost of public goods

Public Choices Rather than make decisions by direct referenda, voters elect representatives In theory, these representatives make public choices that reflect their constituents’ views Under certain conditions, the resulting public choices reflect the preferences of the median voter

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance What do governments attempt to maximize? There is no common agreement about what governments maximize or, more precisely, what elected officials maximize, if anything One theory that parallels the rational self-interest assumption employed in private choices is that elected officials attempt to maximize their political support

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance It is possible that elected representatives will cater to special interests rather than serve the interests of the majority The problem arises because of the asymmetry between special interests and the public interest Consider only one of the thousands of decisions that are made by elected representatives: funding wool production

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance Under the wool-subsidy program, the federal government guarantees that a floor price to sheep farmers that costs taxpayers over $75 million per year The only person the testify before Congress in support of this program was a representative of the National Wool Growers Association, who claimed that the subsidy was vital to the nation’s economic welfare Why didn’t single taxpayer challenge the subsidy?

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance Households consume so many different public and private goods and services that they have neither the time nor the incentive to understand the effects of public choices on every one of those products What’s more, voters realize that each of them has only a tiny possibility of influencing the outcome of public choices

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance Finally, even if an individual voter is somehow able to affect the outcome, the impact on that voter is likely to be small For example, in the case of the wool subsidy, the average taxpayer would save less than 60 cents per year in federal income taxes

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance Therefore, unless voters have a special interest in the legislation, they adopt a stance of rational ignorance Rational ignorance  that they remain largely oblivious to the costs and benefits of the thousands of proposals considered by elected officials The cost to the typical voter of acquiring and acting on such information is usually greater than any expected benefits

Special Interest and Rational Ignorance In contrast, consumers have more incentive to gather and act on information about decisions they make in private markets because they benefit directly from such information Since information and the time required to acquire and digest it are scarce, consumers concentrate on private choices rather than public choices because the payoff in making wise private choices is usually more immediate, direct, and substantial

Distribution of Costs and Benefits The possible combinations of benefits and costs yield four categories of distributions Widespread benefits and widespread costs Concentrated benefits and widespread costs Widespread benefits and concentrated costs Concentrated costs and concentrated benefits

Distribution of Costs and Benefits Traditional public-goods legislation Widespread benefits and widespread costs  nearly everyone benefits and nearly everyone pays Usually has a positive impact on the economy because total benefits exceed total costs Special-interest legislation Benefits are concentrated but costs widespread Program’s costs are spread across nearly all consumers and taxpayers Generally harms the economy, on net, because total costs often exceed total benefits

Distribution of Costs and Benefits Populist legislation Widespread benefits but concentrated costs Usually has a tough time getting approved because the widespread group that benefits typically remains rationally ignorant of the proposed legislation  voters provide little political support The concentrated group adversely affected will object strenuously Tort reform is one example that would benefit the economy as a whole by limiting product liability. However trial lawyers, the group most harmed by such limits, have blocked passage

Distribution of Costs and Benefits Competing-interest legislation Involves both concentrated benefits and costs Example: relative market position of Microsoft versus AOL Exhibit 3 arrays the four categories of distributions

Exhibit 3: Categories of Legislation Distribution of Benefits Widespread Concentrated 1. Traditional Public Goods - National Defense 2. Special Interest - Farm Subsidies Widespread Distribution of Costs 3. Populist - Tort Reform 4. Competing Interest - Labor Union Issues Concentrated

Rent Seeking An important feature of representative democracy is the incentive and political power it offers participants to employ legislation that increases their wealth either through direct transfers or through favorable public expenditures and regulations Special-interest groups try to persuade elected officials to approve measures that provide special interest with some market advantage or outright transfer or subsidy

Rent Seeking Such benefits are sometimes called rents The term in this context means that the government transfer or subsidy constitutes a payment to the resource owner that exceeds the earnings necessary to call forth that resource  payment exceeding opportunity cost The activity that interest groups undertake to elicit these special favors from government is called rent-seeking

Rent Seeking The government frequently bestows some special advantage on a producer group or group of producers, and abundant resources are expended to secure these rights Political action committees, PACs, contribute millions to congressional campaigns

Rent Seeking To the extent that special-interest groups engage in rent-seeking, they shift resources from productive endeavors that create output and income to activities that focus more on transferring income to the special interest Resources employed to persuade government to redistribute income and wealth are unproductive because they do nothing to increase output and usually end up reducing it

Rent Seeking Often firms compete for the same government advantage, thereby wasting still more resources If the advantage conferred by government on some special-interest group requires higher income taxes, the net return individuals expect from working and investing will fall  they may work and invest less

Rent Seeking As a firm’s profitability becomes more and more dependent on decisions made in Washington, resources are diverted from productive activity to rent seeking, or lobbying efforts, to gain special advantage Special-interest groups have little incentive to make the economy more efficient In fact, they will usually support legislation that transfers wealth to them even if overall efficiency declines

Rent Seeking Think of the economy’s output in a particular period as a pie where the pie represents the total value of goods and services produced In answering the “what,” “how,” and “for whom” questions policy makers have three alternatives They can introduce changes that increase the size of the pie  positive sum game

Rent Seeking They can decide simply to carve up the existing pie differently  redistribute income They can start fighting over the how the pie is carved up, causing some of it to end up on the floor  negative sum game

Underground Economy It is reasonably accurate to say that when government taxes productive activity, less production gets reported The underground economy is a term used for all market activity that goes unreported to the government to either avoid taxes or because the activity itself is illegal

Underground Economy The introduction of a tax on productive activity has two effects First, resource owners may supply less of the taxed resource since the after-tax wage declines Second, to evade taxes, some people will shift from the formal, reported economy to an underground, “off-the-books” economy

Underground Economy Must distinguish between Tax avoidance: a legal attempt to arrange one’s economic affairs so as to pay the least possible tax Example: buying municipal bonds because they yield tax-free interest Tax evasion : illegal Takes the form of either failing to file a tax return or filing a fraudulent return by understating income or overstating deductions

Underground Economy Research around the world indicates that the underground economy grows more when Government regulations increase The tax rate increases Government corruption is more widespread U.S. Commerce Department estimates that official figures capture only 90% of U.S. income while the Internal Revenue Service estimates only 87% of taxable income gets reported

Summary Those who pursue rent-seeking activities and those involved in the underground economy view government from opposite sides Rent seekers want government to become actively involved in transferring wealth to them Those in the underground economy want to avoid government contact

Bureaucracy Elected representatives approve legislation However, the task of implementing that legislation is typically left to bureaus Bureaus are government departments and agencies whose activities are financed by appropriations from legislative bodies

Ownership and Funding of Bureaus Taxpayers are in a sense the “owners” of government bureaus in the jurisdiction in which they live If the bureau earns a “profit,” taxes may decline; if it operates at a “loss,” as most do, this loss must be covered by taxes Each taxpayer has just one vote, regardless of the taxes paid and ownership is not transferable

Ownership and Funding of Bureaus Bureaus are typically financed by a budget appropriation from the legislature which comes from taxpayers Becomes of the differences in the forms of ownership and in the sources of revenue, bureaus have different incentives than do for-profit firms  they are likely to behave differently

Ownership and Behavior A central assumption of economics is that people behave rationally and respond to economic incentives The more closely compensation is linked to individual incentives, the more people will behave in accordance with those incentives A private firm receives a steady stream of consumer feedback

Ownership and Behavior If the price is too high or too low to clear the market, surpluses or shortages will become obvious Not only is consumer feedback abundant, but the firm’s owners have a profit incentive to act on that information to satisfy consumer wants The promise of profits also creates incentives to minimize costs

Ownership and Behavior Since public goods and services are not sold in markets, government bureaus receive less consumer feedback and have less incentive to act on any feedback they do receive There are usually no prices and no obvious shortages or surpluses They also have less incentive to act on the information available

Ownership and Behavior Because any “profits” or “losses” arising in the bureau are spread among all taxpayers, and because there is no transferability of ownership, bureaus have less incentive to satisfy customers or to produce their output using the least-cost combination of resources Some pressure may be communicated by voters to their elected representatives and thereby to bureaus. However, even this is not very precise

Ownership and Behavior Voters can leave a jurisdiction if they believe government is inefficient This mechanism, whereby people “vote with their feet,” does promote some efficiency and consumer satisfaction at the state and local level However, voters dissatisfied with the biggest spender, the federal government, cannot easily vote with their feet

Bureaucratic Objectives What sort of objectives will bureaus pursue? The traditional view is that bureaucrats are “public servants,” who try to serve the public the best they can Is this a realistic assumption for bureaucrats in a general sense  that is, why should we assume self-sacrificing behavior by public sector employees?

Bureaucratic Objectives One widely discussed theory of bureaucratic behavior claims that bureaus try to maximize the bureau’s budget According to this view, bureaus are monopoly suppliers of their output to the legislature Rather than charge a price per unit, bureaus offer the legislature the entire amount as a package deal in return for the requested appropriation

Bureaucratic Objectives The legislature has only limited ability to dig into the budget and cut particular items If the legislature does try to cut the bureau’s budget, the bureau will threaten to make those cuts as painful to the legislature and constituents as possible Budget maximization results in a larger budget than that desired by the median voter

Private versus Public Production Simply because some goods and services are financed by the government does not mean that they must be produced by the government Profit-making firms now provide everything from fire protection to prisons in certain jurisdictions Elected officials may also use some combination of bureaus and firms to produce the desired output

Private versus Public Production The trend is toward increased privatization  production by the private sector of government provided goods and services When governments produce public goods and services, they are using the internal organization of the government – the bureaucracy – to supply the product as opposed to using the market

Private versus Public Production Legislators might prefer dealing with bureaus rather than firms for two reasons In situations where it is difficult to specify a contract that clearly spells out all the possible contingencies, the internal organization of the bureau may be more responsive to the legislature’s concerns than the manager of a firm would be Bureaus provide legislators with opportunities to reward friends and supporters with government jobs