ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 15 www.lancaster.ac.uk/postgrad/murphys4/ s.murphy5@lancaster.ac.uk office: LUMS C85.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL CHAPTER.
Advertisements

The Multiplier Effect.
Equilibrium in a Simple Model. Equilibrium Key concept in economics – illustrate with the simplest possible macro model Equilibrium is a point of balance.
Introduction to Macroeconomics
CHAPTER 8 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Macroeconomics 9e by Case,
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada. A voice can be a whisper or fill Toronto’s Molson Amphitheatre, depending on the amplification. A limousine with good.
Chapter Ten1 CHAPTER TEN Aggregate Demand I. Chapter Ten2 The Great Depression caused many economists to question the validity of classical economic theory.
28 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Product Markets and National Output Chapter 12. Discussion Topics Circular flow of payments Composition and measurement of gross domestic product Consumption,
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER TEN Aggregate Demand I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights.
In this chapter, you will learn:
Motivation The Great Depression caused a rethinking of the Classical Theory of the macroeconomy. It could not explain: Drop in output by 30% from 1929.
The Short – Run Macro Model
Copyright © 2006 Pearson Education Canada Expenditure Multipliers PART 8Aggregate Demand and Inflation 23 CHAPTER.
Spending and Output in the Short Run Chapter 13. Chapter 13 Learning Objectives. You should be able to: List the components of investment. Distinguish.
AE = C + I + G + NX AE = GDP = Y = C + I + G + NX
Slides for Part III-B These slides will take you through the basics of income- expenditure analysis. The following is based on Dornbusch & Fisher, Chapter.
In this chapter, you will learn:
Aggregate Supply.
mankiw's macroeconomics modules
V PART The Core of Macroeconomic Theory.
IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN:
Copyright © 2001 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run.
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Aggregate Demand I: Building the IS.
Eco 6351 Economics for Managers Chapter 12. Fiscal Policy Prof. Vera Adamchik.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics Hubbard/O’Brien UPDATE EDITION. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 23 Output and Expenditure.
Economic Instability: A Critique of the Self-Regulating Economy
© The McGraw-Hill Companies, 2002 Week 8 Introduction to macroeconomics.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 21 Chapter PART V THE GOODS.
© 2007 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics 8e by Case and Fair Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano 21 Chapter PART V THE GOODS.
Chapter 12 The Fiscal Policy Approach to Stabilization.
Lecture 5 Business Cycles (1): Aggregate Expenditure and Multiplier 1.
Aim: What can the government do to bring stability to the economy?
Capter 16 Output and Aggregate Demand 1 Chapter 16: Begg, Vernasca, Fischer, Dornbusch (2012).McGraw Hill.
Eva Hromadkova PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER TEN Aggregate Demand I macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 10: Aggregate.
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich CHAPTER TEN Aggregate Demand I macro © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights.
1 Lecture 8 The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants of Consumption Planned Investment (I) The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
1 of 33 © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. CHAPTER OUTLINE 8 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output The Keynesian Theory of Consumption Other Determinants.
The Economy in the Short-run
In this chapter, you will learn…
Income and Spending Chapter #10 (DFS)
In his classic "The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money" Keynes telling about two important things: If you find your income going up,
Topic 3: Fiscal Policy Circular Flow Keynesian Economics Taxes and Government Spending 1.
National Income Determination For more, see any Macroeconomics text book.
Chapter # 3 Keynesian Theory of Income and Employment
The Multiplier How much will NI change by when there is an increase in injections?
13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL CHAPTER.
Aggregate Expenditures
1 of 17 Principles of Economics: Econ101.  Keynes on Say’s Law  Keynes on Wage Rates and Prices  Consumption Function  Equilibrium Real GDP and Gaps.
Macroeconomics Econ 2301 Dr. Frank Jacobson Coach Stuckey Chapter 11.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Education Canada Chapter 6 Determination of National Income.
Expenditure Multipliers: The Keynesian Model CHAPTER 12.
C h a p t e r twenty-three © 2006 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien—1 st ed. Prepared by: Fernando.
Fiscal Policy Chapter 12 Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill Education.
Copyright © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 3 Income and Interest Rates: The Keynesian Cross Model and the IS Curve.
1 of 27 The level of GDP, the overall price level, and the level of employment—three chief concerns of macroeconomists—are influenced by events in three.
Economic Issues: An Introduction DE3A 34 Outcome 2 Topic 10 Multiplier Effect.
1 of 55 Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall · Macroeconomics · R. Glenn Hubbard, Anthony Patrick O’Brien, 3e. Chapter.
1 Sect. 4 - National Income & Price Determination Module 16 - Income & Expenditure What you will learn: The nature of the multiplier The meaning of the.
Expenditure Multipliers: The Keynesian Model CHAPTER 12.
Slide 0 CHAPTER 10 Aggregate Demand I In Chapter 10, you will learn…  the IS curve, and its relation to  the Keynesian cross  the loanable funds model.
1 The Keynesian Model in Action. 2 What is the purpose of this chapter? To complete the Keynesian model by adding the government (G) and the foreign sector.
Equilibrium levels of real national output (aggregate demand and supply) “If you’re not confused, you’re not paying attention” Anon
Lecture Six Short-run equilibrium Multiplier Adding the government sector Fiscal Policy and Aggregate Expenditure Model.
The Aggregate Expenditures Model What determines the level of GDP, given the nation’s production capacity? What causes real GDP to rise in one period and.
1 Chapter 22 The Short – Run Macro Model. 2 The Short-Run Macro Model In short-run, spending depends on income, and income depends on spending –The more.
The Short – Run Macro Model
MACRO REVIEW.
Presentation transcript:

ECON 100 Tutorial: Week 15 www.lancaster.ac.uk/postgrad/murphys4/ s.murphy5@lancaster.ac.uk office: LUMS C85

Keynesian Cross Diagram Last week we calculated GDP using the expenditure method where GDP = Aggregate Expenditure (AE) = C + I + G + NX. By definition, GDP is total output, i.e. GDP = Y. So we call “Y = C + I + G” the product market equilibrium because we are setting total production equal to aggregate expenditure. The Keynesian cross diagram graphs total output and aggregate expenditure as two separate lines. GDP = AE = C+I+G = f(Y) GDP = Aggregate Expenditure (note: sometimes we say Aggregate Demand, AD) Y* Where the two lines cross, Y*, is the equilibrium level of income in the economy. The 45° line is where GDP = Y Or GDP = total Output, Some texts call this the Aggregate Supply curve. AE Lecture 41 (Coskeran Lecture 2) starts with this. Coskeran also calls the Keynesian Cross Diagram the 45-degree cross Note: I call it Aggregate Expenditure in this slide; I believe that in Lecture it’s called Aggregate Demand, so later slides may talk about AD. I’m referring to the same thing. The first half of Chapter 33 in Mankiw & Taylor corresponds with this tutorial material.

Why is the Keynesian Cross Diagram relevant? Keynes published work in 1936, that tried to explain short-run economic fluctuations in general and the Great Depression in particular. His primary message is that recessions and depressions can occur because of inadequate aggregate demand for goods and services. So, he advocated policies that increased aggregate demand, in particular government spending on public works. The Keynesian Cross Diagram and the Keynesian Multiplier build on classical economics theory to illustrate his theory. Read through Chapter 33 of the Mankiw and Taylor textbook for more info.

Question 1 (a) The economy is described as follows: Y = C + I + G G = 150 C = 60 + 0.6(Y – T) T = 100 I = 250 Derive the equilibrium level of income for the economy. For problems like this, the first step is usually to plug values into the equilibrium equation: Y = C + I + G Y = 60 + 0.6(Y-T) + 250 + 150 Y = 60 + 0.6(Y – 100) + 250 + 150 Y = 460 + 0.6Y – 60 Y = 400 + 0.6Y This is the equation for the AD line that we graph in (b). 0.4Y = 400 Y = 1000 This is the equilibrium value of Y (or Y*) where the two lines will cross. (note: the coefficient on Y in the AD equation is the MPC)

Question 1(b) Illustrate the equilibrium on an appropriate diagram. This graph is called the Keynesian Cross (Fig. 33.1 Mankiw) The 45⁰ line connects all points where consumption spending is equal to national income. The economy is in equilibrium where the C+I+G (GDP=AE) line cuts the 45⁰ (GDP=Y) line. Aggregate Expenditure Y = 0.56Y + 450

1(c) Find the equilibrium value of Y if G = 200 Y = C + I + G Y = 60 + 0.6(Y – T) + 250 + 200 Y = 60 + 0.6(Y – 100) + 250 + 200 Y = 510 + 0.6Y – 60 Y = 0.6Y + 450 This is the AD line that we will graph. Y – 0.60Y = 450 0.40Y = 450 Y = 1,125 This is Y* Y = C + I + G G = 150 C = 60 + 0.6(Y – T) G = 200 I = 250 T = 100

Question 1(d) What is the value of the multiplier in the economy? We increased G from 150 to 200 and as a result, Y went from 1,000 to 1,125. First, how do we find the multiplier? Multiplier = ∆Y / ∆G =(1125 – 1000)/(200 – 150) = 125/50 = 2.5. Also, as a check, Multiplier = 1/(1 – MPC) = 1 /(1 – 0.6) = 1/0.4 = 2.5. A side note: MPC: marginal propensity to consume. The fraction of extra income that a household consumes rather than saves. i.e. if MPC = .6, then for every £1 earned, £0.60 is spent. How do we find MPC? It is the coefficient on Y in the equation of the Aggregate Demand line.

Question 1(e) Y = C + I + G Y = 60 + 0.6(Y-T) + 250 + 100 What would be the effect on equilibrium income if the government reversed policy and introduced an “austerity” budget in which it reduced G to equal T? Again, the first step is to plug values into the equilibrium equation: Y = C + I + G Y = 60 + 0.6(Y-T) + 250 + 100 Y = 60 + 0.6(Y – 100) + 250 + 100 Y = 410 + 0.6Y – 60 Y = 0.6Y + 350 0.4Y = 350 Y = 875 The new equilibrium income would be 875. Y = C + I + G G = T C = 60 + 0.6(Y – T) T = 100 I = 250

A second, alternate, way to find Y is to use the multiplier. Question 1(e) What would be the effect on equilibrium income if the government reversed policy and introduced an “austerity” budget in which it reduced G to equal T? A second, alternate, way to find Y is to use the multiplier. Income falls from original income by the drop in G times the multiplier. Initial G was 150 and Y was 1000 Final G was 100, a fall of 50 from the initial G. So income falls by 50*2.5 = 125 So final Y = 1000 – 125 = 875

What are the limitations of the analysis using this model? Question 1(f) What are the limitations of the analysis using this model? The model ignores a number of features of the economy. These include prices, which are implicitly assumed fixed in the model. This is an obvious weakness, despite Friedman’s view that the realism of assumptions should not matter. Friedman himself, of course, thought this assumption was too much.   Interest rates are not included in the model, an assumption that will be addressed in later lectures. Also, government spending has to be financed. This is not allowed for in either a) or c) where the government is running a deficit. The long-term implications of such a (deficit) policy are not considered. Nor does the model include a supply-side. Everything goes through demand and capacity constraints are ignored. Some of these limitations are addressed in developing the model beyond this simple representation.

Question 2: Deflationary Gap If there is a deflationary gap, then that means that there is spare capacity in the economy that unemployment will rise. (here: Y1 < Yf ) The deflationary gap is the difference between full employment output and the expenditure required to raise the equilibrium employment output to the point that it equals full employment output. To remove or get rid of the deflationary gap, we then have to raise government spending in order to raise the equilibrium employment output. So what we want to do here is find the multiplier. To remove the deflationary gap, the government should increase government spending by the deflationary gap amount divided by the multiplier. For more on deflationary gap and inflationary gap: Figure 33.1 and pgs. 707 and 708 in Mankiw & Taylor 2nd Ed. For more on deflationary gap: Figure 33.1 and pgs. 707 and 708 in Mankiw & Taylor. If you want to google it, search for “Keynesian deflationary gap” and “Keynesian inflationary gap”.

Question 2 ctd. First, let’s find MPC: The deflationary gap in an economy is calculated to be $700 billion. The marginal propensity to save is 0.1 The marginal propensity to import is 0.15 The marginal rate of taxation is 0.1. By how much would the government need change its spending on goods and services to eliminate the deflationary gap? First, let’s find MPC: MPC = 1-(marginal propensity to save + marginal propensity to import + marginal rate of taxation) MPC = 1-(MPS + MPM + MPT) MPC = 1 – (0.1 + 0.15 + 0.1) MPC = 1 - 0.35 We can plug MPC into our equation for the value of the multiplier: multiplier = 1/(1-MPC) 1/(1- (1- 0.35) = 1/0.35 = 2.857 So, the rise in G required is 700/Multiplier = 700/2.857 = $245 billion. MPS = 0.1 MPM = 0.15 MPT = 0.1 For more on deflationary gap: Figure 33.1 and pgs. 707 and 708 in Mankiw & Taylor.

Question 2 ctd. The deflationary gap in an economy is calculated to be $700 billion. The marginal propensity to save is 0.1 MPS = 0.1 The marginal propensity to import is 0.15 MPM = 0.15 The marginal rate of taxation is 0.1. MPT = 0.1 By how much would the government need change its spending on goods and services to eliminate the deflationary gap? Alternatively, pgs. 711 – 713 of Mankiw talks about the Marginal Propensity to Withdraw, MPW. MPW = MPS + MPT + MPM The multiplier is = 1/MPW So, we can ignore all of the 1- ‘s in the previous slide and just use MPW: MPW = 0.1 + 0.1 + 0.15 MPW = 0.35 Multiplier = 1/MPW Multiplier = 1/0.35 Multiplier = 2.857 So, to remove the deflationary gap, the government should increase government spending by the deflationary gap divided by the multiplier: Spending increase = 700/ 2.857 Spending increase = $245 billion. For more on deflationary gap: Figure 33.1 and pgs. 707 and 708 in Mankiw & Taylor.

Question 3 The marginal propensity to consume in an economy is equal to 0.8. It also equals the average propensity to consume. In addition, I = 300; X = 100; M = 150 and G = 100. What is the equilibrium level of national income in the economy? Let’s start with Y = C + I + G + X - M We have I, G, X and M, so we can plug those in. To find C, the hint here is that we are told about the Average propensity to consume. It equals MPC. So, C = average propensity to consume * Y, so C = MPC *Y = 0.8Y. So we can plug in to Y = C + I + G + X - M Y = 0.8Y + 300 + 100 + 100 – 150 Y = 0.8Y + 350 0.2Y = 350 Y = 1,750

Question 3 If the full-employment level of national income is 2,000, what would the government need to do to its spending to achieve this level of national income? We found Y* = 1,750, and want to increase it to 2,000. To do so, we need Government spending to increase by the deflationary gap ÷ the multiplier. The deflationary gap is the difference between equilibrium income and the full-employment level of income, 250. The multiplier is 1 /(1 – MPC). MPC = 0.8 (from prev. slide) So, Multiplier = 1/0.2 = 5 So to raise income to 2,000 requires an increase of 250. Thus G needs to increase by: deflationary gap ÷ the multiplier = 250 ÷ 5 = 50.

Question 4 Consider the following model Y = C + I + G C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) T = 0.2Y I = 100 G = 120 where Y, C, I, G and T respectively denote income, consumption, planned investment, government spending, and tax revenues. The equilibrium level of income is:   700 750 800 850

Question 4 Consider the following model Y = C + I + G C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) T = 0.2Y I = 100 G = 120 where Y, C, I, G and T respectively denote income, consumption, planned investment, government spending, and tax revenues. Y = 50 + 0.8(Y-0.2Y) + 100 + 120 Y = 270 + 0.8Y-0.16Y Y = 270 + 0.64Y 0.36Y = 270 Y = 270/0.36 Y = 750 This is the equation for the AD line, and from here, the coefficient on Y gives us our MPC = 0.64

Question 5 Consider the model in question (4) above, but suppose that G rises to 125. The new equilibrium level of income is: 714 728 764 880 Y = C + I + G C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) T = 0.2Y I = 100 G = 120 G = 125

Question 5 Y = C + I + G C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) T = 0.2Y I = 100 G = 120 G = 125 Y = 50 + 0.8(Y-0.2Y) + 100 + 125 Y = 275 + 0.8Y-0.16Y Y = 275 + 0.64Y 0.36Y = 275 Y = 275/0.36 Y = 764

Question 6 Using the results obtained in questions (4) and (5) above, the multiplier is: 1.5 2.3 2.6 2.8 Q(4) Q(5) Y = C + I + G G = 125 C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) Y* = 764 T = 0.2Y I = 100 G = 120 Y* = 750

Question 6 Multiplier = Change in Y/Change in G = (764 – 750)/(125 – 120) = 14/5 = 2.8. Alternatively: Multiplier = 1/(1-MPC) = 1/(1 – 0.64) = 1/0.36 = 2.78 So an increase in G of 5 increases Y by 5*2.78 = 14 Y = C + I + G Q(4) Q(5) C = 50 + 0.8(Y-T) G = 120 G = 125 T = 0.2Y Y* = 750 Y* = 764 I = 100

Question 7 A change in an injection causes a change in income over time in an economy as follows: +100 + 70 + 49 + 34.3 + …   What is the value of the multiplier? 0.3 1.43 3 3.33

Question 7 Hmm, So the pattern is: A change in an injection causes a change in income over time in an economy as follows: +100 + 70 + 49 + 34.3 + …   What is the value of the multiplier? Hmm, So the pattern is: 100 + 0.7*100 + 0.7*0.7*100 + 0.7*0.7*0.7*100 + … = 100 + 0.7*100 + 0.72 *100 + 0.73 *100 + … = (An example of what is happening here is: I get £100 buy something from you for £70, You take the £70 I paid you, spend 0.7 of it on something your neighbor is selling, they take the £49 you paid them, and spend 0.7 of that on something, etc. ) So, 0.7 is the MPC. So our equation says the multiplier is: 1/1-MPC = 1/(1-0.7) = 1/.3 = 10/3 = 3.33 Khan academy about summing infinite series: https://www.khanacademy.org/math/trigonometry/seq_induction/infinite-geometric-series/v/infinite-geometric-series

Next Week Check Moodle for a worksheet and work through it before coming to tutorial. Read through Chapter 33 in Mankiw & Taylor.