Welfare state design: Architecture and outcomes - the New Zealand benefit system in comparative perspective Welfare Working Group Forum, Victoria University.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
No. 1 Organizing Eldercare The Danish Case in a Comparative Perspective Morten Balle Hansen, Professor, PhD Department of Political Science, Aalborg University.
Advertisements

Aging Seminar Series: Income and Wealth of Older Americans Domestic Social Policy Division Congressional Research Service November 19, 2008.
Assistance for families: An assessment of Australian family policies from an international perspective Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre,
1 The distribution of the State budget – 2008: social services are one-third of the total budget Total budget: NIS 323 billion Not including debt servicing.
Productivity Commission Mike Woods Deputy Chairman, Productivity Commission COTA National Policy Forum An Ageing Australia: Preparing for the Future.
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza Session 3(a) Inequality in Europe and the USA March
1 Reducing the Gaps in Society: Policy Challenges in the Era of Globalization Dr. Karnit Flug June 2007 Taub Center Conference.
Is Inequality Increasing? Presentation for Parliamentary Library Vital Issues Seminar, 10 October 2012 Peter Whiteford, Crawford School of Public Policy.
Inequality and Redistribution in the Australian Welfare State
1 ESPAnet The Network for European Social Policy Analysis Summer School 2007 INCOME PROTECTION Principles and practices Wim van Oorschot ESPAnet / RECWOWE.
Overview of Income Redistribution Programs
Long-run Pension System Reforms in Europe and Central Asia Anita M. Schwarz Lead Economist Human Development Department Europe and Central Asia Region.
OECD, Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs Social Policy in the OECD: what lessons for Chile? National Social Security Meeting, Santiago.
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza Session 3(a) Inequality and poverty in Europe and the USA November
Chapter 7 Labor Market Indicators Current Population Survey: Every month, the U.S. Census Bureau and Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) survey 60,000 households.
Social Welfare Policymaking Chapter 18
McTaggart, Findlay, Parkin: Microeconomics © 2007 Pearson Education Australia Chapter 18: Economic Inequality and Redistribution.
Gender Impact Assessment of Taxes and Benefits Susan Himmelweit Open University Women’s Budget Group.
Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: Lessons for Eastern Europe and Central Asia.
Chapter 33: Taxes: Equity versus Efficiency Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Employee Benefit Plans Joseph Applebaum, FSA October 4, 2002 Views expressed are those of the speaker and do not represent the views of the U.S. General.
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus Seminar presentation: Korea Institute for Health and Social Affairs 11 October, 2007, Seoul,
Distribution of income and wealth Define income Market income= wages/salaries/profit/rent Gross income= market income + transfers Disposable income= gross.
Research and Planning Administration National Insurance Institute National Insurance Institute Research & Planning Administration Herzliya Conference The.
Income support in a time of low unemployment Peter Davidson, Senior Policy Officer ACOSS Economic and social outlook conference, University of Melbourne.
EU Enlargement: Impact On The Social Policy and Labour Markets of Accession and Non- accession Countries BACKGROUND FOR ESTONIA Epp Kallaste PRAXIS Center.
Low wage work in Denmark Presentation at Lower conference at Sandbjerg Niels Westergaard-Nielsen, CCP.
The fiscal costs of ageing in the euro area: will the young have to pay the bill? Ad van Riet Head of the Fiscal Policies Division European Central Bank.
 Background – The European Social Model – Trends and challenges  The purpose of the study  Methodology  Our hypothesis  What’s next?
1 Pension Challenges and Pension Reforms in OECD Countries Peter Whiteford Social Policy Division OECD
IBIS Academy 2008 Dublin, Ireland Green Paper on Pensions Brendan Kennedy The Pensions Board IBIS Academy 2008 Dublin, Ireland.
A presentation for the Women’s Institute for a Secure Retirement February 28, 2008 Barbara D. Bovbjerg Director Education, Workforce, and Income Security.
Chapter 3 section 4 Providing a Safety Net Income and Poverty In a Market economy, income depends primarily on earnings, which depend on the value of each.
Comparing SPI and SSI Data Formats The case of Sri Lanka Ruwanthi Elwalagedara Joint ADB / ILO / OECD Korea Policy Centre Technical Workshop on Social.
The Role of the Fiscal Policy in Poverty Reduction Youngsun Koh Korea Development Institute.
Welfare Reform and Lone Parents Employment in the UK Paul Gregg and Susan Harkness.
Information on public family supports in the OECD Family database ECEC Network meeting Paris, 21-22, 2010 Willem Adema Senior Economist, OECD Social Policy.
Module 6: Quantifying gaps and measuring coverage ILO, 2013.
Cumulative impacts of austerity measures and the distribution of economic outcomes John Hills Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, London School of.
Additional analysis of poverty in Scotland 2013/14 Communities Analytical Services July 2015.
2 H i g h e r E d u c a t i o n © Oxford University Press, All rights reserved. Chapter 8: Insurance: Unemployment, sickness, and disability Barr:
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza Session 3(a) Inequality in Europe and the USA March
Spending on children in the OECD and well-being outcomes: a question of how much or how? Dominic Richardson OECD ELS/SPD ISCI conference, York, July 2011.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright  2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Who Gets What? The Distribution of Income Who Gets What? The.
 Goal of Equity in Income distribution: is to have a more equitable (fairer) distribution of income. That means productive income is divided among the.
Providing a Safety Net. Why Households Differ One of the main reasons why household income differs is because the number of household members who work.
Transformation of the Public Sector Changes in the Social Policy Ing. Katarina Poluncova Department of Public Economy.
Comparing welfare systems Week 18 Comparative Sociology.
Fighting child poverty across the OECD: is work the answer? Presentation: Joint OECD/Korea Regional Centre on Health and Social policy July 2006, Seoul.
Implications of the 2015 Intergenerational Report Peter McDonald Crawford School of Public Policy The Australian National University and ARC Centre of.
 Income: the acquisition of economic resources over time (earned income and unearned income, factor income and transfer payments).  Equality of Income.
INCOME INEQUALITY IN INDIA
Ageing and the Changing Nature of Intergenerational Flows in Thailand
Assessing the impacts of policies on children
Changing employment relations & reforms of social security systems.
Women, Work, and the Economy: Macroeconomic Gains from Gender Equity The views expressed in this presentation are those of the authors and should not be.
Family and Children policy in an international perspective presentation: Ministry for Health, Welfare and Family Affairs, 23 November 2009, Seoul Willem.
1 Law and Economic Justice Jon Forman Alfred P. Murrah Professor of Law University of Oklahoma Central Oklahoma Association of Legal Assistants Oklahoma.
Promoting social cohesion in Korea. Social spending is low but increasing rapidly Rising income inequality and relative poverty and the factors behind.
Fighting child poverty across the OECD: is work the answer?
Public policy and European society University of Castellanza
Seminar presentation:
Social Expenditure across OECD countries: concepts and indicators
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus
Pension Challenges and Pension Reforms in OECD Countries
1.7.3 Government Policies to Alleviate Poverty and to Influence the Distribution of Income and Wealth Proverb: “Give a man a fish and you feed him for.
Family Policy : an International Perspective
Social Policy : Trends in spending, recipiency and policy focus
REDUCING INEQUALITY FOR GREATER SOCIAL COHESION IN THE WESTERN BALKANS
Changing employment relations & reforms of social security systems
Presentation transcript:

Welfare state design: Architecture and outcomes - the New Zealand benefit system in comparative perspective Welfare Working Group Forum, Victoria University of Wellington, 9-10 June 2010 Peter Whiteford, Social Policy Research Centre, University of New South Wales 1

2 Outline  Nature and limitations of the approach  The design of benefit systems  Targeting, progressivity and redistribution  How New Zealand compares – particularly to Australia  Summary and some conclusions  Sources and additional material

3 Caveats and limitations Approach is descriptive and based on statistical calculations. Most analysis is static. The counterfactual effectively assumes that the welfare state has had no incentive effects, or at least is the same in all countries. Some welfare state features treated as if they are produced by market mechanisms (e.g. minimum wages). Does not include non-cash benefits (health care, education, social housing, child care); indirect taxes – VAT, employer social security contributions also not included. Employer social security contributions are paid by businesses direct to government and do not pass through the household sector. Particularly problematic as they are one of main sources of funding for the welfare state. Employer provided fringe benefits not included. The distribution of wealth, including owner-occupied housing makes a difference.

A framework for assessing social protection Many analyses focus only on government provided social protection, but this needs to be seen within a broad framework In addition to government cash benefits, assistance can be provided through allowances or concessions in the tax system or through direct service provision. (e.g. child care). The tax system can also offset or reinforce the objectives of social protection. Occupational social welfare can be provided on a voluntary or mandatory basis. In New Zealand and Australia, labour force regulation has a long history – since the 19 th century. Private social welfare can be provided by churches, NGOs, family and friends or purchased in the market (insurance). 4

Social security design The New Zealand and the Australian social security systems differ from those in most other countries In Europe, the United States and Japan, most government benefits are financed by contributions from employers and insured employees, and benefits are often related to past earnings, so that higher income workers receive higher absolute levels of benefits if they become unemployed or incapacitated or when they retire. In contrast, in New Zealand and Australia, most government benefits are flat-rate entitlements financed from general government revenue, and there are no explicit social security taxes. In addition, in both countries – but more so in Australia – most benefits are income-tested or asset-tested, so that entitlements reduce as resources increase. Because these systems are not contributory, eligibility is based on residence and coverage of the population is broad. Duration of payment receipt is not time limited, with income support payments being paid indefinitely subject to the continued meeting of eligibility criteria. 5

Social security design Because the New Zealand and Australian systems are income-tested and not contributory, there is a tendency for overseas commentators to see them as residual, rather like vast forms of social assistance. This view is mistaken. Benefits are legal entitlements and there is very limited discretion in the system, and recipients have the right to appeal to administrative and judicial tribunals in case of disagreements about administrative decisions. The social security system is also a national system, with entitlements and conditions being uniform across the country. While income support payments are means-tested, these assets tests are much more generous than those typically applying in social assistance schemes in other countries. In a sense, the New Zealand and Australian systems are hybrids falling between a social insurance system and a social assistance system, being less “generous” than some social insurance systems, but more “generous” than most social assistance systems. 6

Who benefits under different welfare states? A “pure” social insurance system is status maintaining – contributors get out what they have put in, and you have to be a contributor to benefit. On average, social insurance systems are more expensive and therefore appear more “generous”, but this can be generosity to the middle classes and the well-off. Universal and income-tested schemes are therefore likely to be relatively more generous to the lifetime poor and to those who have not contributed or been able to contribute to social insurance schemes, particularly young people, women and migrants. However, one of the central issues in the literature is that more encompassing welfare states provide higher levels of benefits because the middle class have a stake in the system. Does targeting undercut political support for generosity to the poor?

Incentives – general considerations Different forms of assistance and financing have different implications for incentives:  Contributory systems may enhance incentives to participate in the labour market Paid maternity/parental leave with right to return to work promotes labour force attachment, but if parental leave is too long (> 6 months) may be associated with loss of earnings potential.  Child care support encourages employment, particularly if targeted to employed families or those looking for work;  Family allowances likely to have a small income effect, discouraging employment;  More generous, joint income-tested payments for the low paid likely to have stronger work disincentives;  Family-based taxation likely to discourage employment of second earners; Practically all OECD countries have income-tested payments for low income families, which dominate the effects of the tax unit.  Generous income support for the non-employed may act as work disincentive, unless associated with active job search requirements; Generosity needs to take account of ease of access and potential duration of benefits, not just benefit levels.  Specific eligibility conditions are important, e.g. Early retirement provisions  Expectations are likely to be important.

9 Types of redistribution in social security systems The design features of social protection differ in important respects - two of the most important features relate to the funding – i.e. the different ways in which programmes are financed – and structure of benefits – i.e. the relationship between benefits received and the past or current income of beneficiaries. Redistribution can be between rich and poor (Robin Hood) or across the lifecycle (the piggy bank) – risk insurance (against unemployment, disability, sickness etc.), savings (for retirement). All welfare states are a mix of the two, but the mix varies. Other types of redistribution – notably between men and women and also across regions. Behavioural effects may undercut redistribution; private provision also redistributes across the lifecycle. Point in time, static analysis implicitly treats all measured redistribution as if it were between rich and poor. Taking account of redistribution across the life course, the level of redistribution between rich and poor is less than it appears, but is still strongly associated with progressivity of benefit structure.

Targeting, progressivity and redistribution Targeting is a means of determining either eligibility for benefits or the level of entitlements for those eligible. In a sense, all benefit systems – apart from a universal “basic income” or “guaranteed minimum income” scheme – are targeted to specific categories of people, such as the unemployed, people with disabilities or those over retirement age. Income and asset-testing is a further form of targeting that can be applied once people satisfy categorical eligibility criteria. Progressivity refers to the profile of benefits when compared to market or disposable incomes – how large a share of benefits is received by different income groups – e.g. do the poor receive more than the rich from the transfer system? Redistribution refers to the outcomes of different tax and benefit systems – how much does the benefit system actually change the distribution of household income? Effectiveness measured by how much redistribution is achieved; efficiency by the resources used to achieve this redistribution. 10

New Zealand’s distinctive tax/benefit system Total NZ spending on social protection (cash benefits, health care, social services) at 18.5% of GDP in 2005 was about 90% of the OECD average – but this is mainly due to lower than average spending on age pensions; health and disability spending are a little higher than average and cash benefits for people of working age about 20% higher; spending on non-health services about 2/3rds of average. (Australia spent 17.1% of GDP.) Direct taxation paid by benefit recipients is higher than average, but indirect taxation of benefits is a little lower – in Australia direct and indirect taxes on benefits are amongst the lowest in the OECD. NZ tax expenditures are very low. Australian pension tax expenditures are the highest in the OECD, but other tax expenditures below average. Mandatory private social benefits are very low in New Zealand, but in Australia (sick pay and superannuation) they are amongst highest. Thus, net expenditure – after direct and indirect taxes paid on benefits – is even closer to average – and tax expenditures and mandatory private social expenditure increase Australia’s ranking but reduce New Zealand’s ranking. Net total social expenditure is 16.4% of GDP in New Zealand, but 19.3% of GDP in Australia – the rankings are reversed (in addition, Denmark falls from 26.9% of GDP to 21.6%, while USA rises from 15.9 to 25.3% of GDP). To assess distributional impacts it is necessary to look at all components of the system together – ideally. 11

Australia and New Zealand rely on income- testing more than any other OECD countries % of GDP spent on income-tested benefits,

13 Australia and New Zealand have the most progressive benefit systems in the OECD Ratio of benefits received by poorest quintile to benefits received by richest quintile, total population, 2005

14 Progressivity of transfers, 2005 Concentration coefficient of transfers

Australia and New Zealand have low levels of churning Churning as % of equivalent household disposable income 15

The progressivity of direct taxes is highest in the English speaking countries and lowest in the Nordic countries Concentration coefficient for direct taxes around

17 Direct taxes on public transfers % of public social benefits paid in direct taxes

18 Indirect taxes on public transfers Implicit average indirect tax rate (%)

OUTCOMES 19

20 Levels of inequality, OECD countries, 2005 Gini coefficient for disposable income

Income poverty rates and poverty gaps In most international comparisons, income poverty is measured by reference to median household income “after” taxes and benefits, adjusted by household size (either 40, 50 or 60%). The poverty rate or headcount is the % of the population with incomes below the benchmark; the poverty gap is the difference between the average income of the poor and the benchmark – a measure of distance (and possibly exclusion?). Household surveys do not include many of the most disadvantaged – people who are homeless, in nursing homes, boarding houses or in prison (about 2% of the Australian population). Measured at 50% of median income, New Zealand is almost exactly at the OECD average, with the equal lowest poverty rate among the population aged 65 years and over in the OECD (2%). Poverty among the working age population is a little higher than average (11% compared to 9%), and child poverty is higher (15% compared to 12%) Australia has more people between 40% and 50% of median income than any other OECD country. Using a 50% of median income poverty line, the poverty gap is the 6 th lowest in the OECD and a little lower than in Denmark. So Australia has a relatively high share of the population in poverty, but close to the poverty line. New Zealand has more households between 50% and 60% of median income than any other OECD country. At 60% of median income, New Zealand has the fifth highest poverty rate in the OECD. The poverty gap is the 8 th highest in the OECD. 21

22 Poverty gap and composite measure of income poverty, mid-2000s

23 Benefit recipiency in New Zealand is below average % of working age population in receipt of income replacement benefits, full-time equivalents, 2004

24 Reliance on benefits has increased, most rapidly in New Zealand (from a low base) % of working age population in receipt of income replacement benefits, full-time equivalents, 1980 and 2004

Relative to their high overall employment, the UK and Australia do worst for joblessness among families with children – with New Zealand not far behind Percentage point difference between actual and predicted joblessness among families with children

Reduction in inequality due to public cash transfers and household taxes Point reduction in the concentration coefficient

Australia is the most efficient country in the OECD in reducing poverty Point change in mean poverty gap per unit of transfer spending 27

28 Net redistribution to the poor Net transfers received by poorest quintile as % of household disposable income

Summary New Zealand relies on income testing more than any other OECD country except Australia, and has one of the most progressive structure of benefits of all OECD countries. New Zealand has lower churning than most other OECD countries, and the third highest level of transfer efficiency in reducing poverty. Australia (and Ireland) prove to be nearly as effective in reducing inequality as the Nordic countries, while New Zealand is above average in reducing inequality. But these are measures of programme efficiency, not economic efficiency. Efficiency is a means to an end – the goal is more effectiveness. 29

Conclusions The broad architecture of the New Zealand system has considerable strengths. Broadly speaking, in looking at reform options you can consider refurbishment and modernisation, or demolition and rebuilding. Despite impressive design features of tax and transfer systems, disposable income inequality in New Zealand is above the OECD average; this means that income inequality before taxes and transfers is higher than in most countries with better inequality outcomes. If New Zealand wants to be more effective it could either increase its high level of progressivity, or tax and spend more while at least maintaining effective progressivity, or identify the factors associated with its relatively high level of market income inequality and address these problems more directly. 30

ADDITIONAL MATERIAL 31

Australia has the most progressive direct taxes on retirement age households – New Zealand the least progressive Concentration coefficient for direct taxes on retirement age households 32

33 Effective contributions to public pensions, redistributive and actuarial components, mid-1990s % of wages

34 Net incomes of social assistance recipients, 2005 % of median equivalent household income, with and without housing benefits

Effective tax rates for parents seeking part- time work are lower in Australia than most other countries AETR from zero to 33% APW, 2004

Effective tax rates can be high for parents seeking full-time work, but are lower in Australia than most other countries AETR from zero to 67% APW, 2004

Child care costs can increase effective tax rates AETR from zero to 67% APW, plus child care costs, 2004

Effective marginal tax rates can be high in Australia but over specific income ranges 38

In contrast, the Nordic approach has much higher EMTRs at lower income levels 39

Social insurance does not necessarily reduce EMTRs (for lone parents and single people) 40

Why are we interested in the design of benefit systems? “The tax-transfer system is the principal means of expressing societal choices about equity. The tax-transfer system is a reflection of the kind of society we aspire to be.” Ken Henry, ACOSS National Conference, (2009). 41

Working-age recipients of selected social security payments, Australia,

Trends in receipt of government benefits, to % of households whose principal income source is government benefits 43

Household reliance on income support, to

Inequality of earnings among households of working age, 2005 Gini coefficients for different earnings measures 45

46 Sources OECD Family database OECD Social Expenditure database _1_1_1_1,00.html _1_1_1_1,00.html Net Social Expenditure – Adema and Ladaique (2005) - _1_119684_1_1_1,00.html _1_119684_1_1_1,00.html OECD, Benefits and Wages - _1_1_1_1,00.html _1_1_1_1,00.html OECD study of income distribution (2005) Benefit recipiency - Employment Outlook (2003) OECD Social Indicators - _1_1_1_1,00.html _1_1_1_1,00.html