Chapter 12 Social Insurance: The New Function of Government

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
RESOURCE ALLOCATION & THE MARKET Demand, supply and the market Sources of failure in the market for health care The insurance system of funding health.
Advertisements

Optimal Contracts under Adverse Selection
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Copyright©2004 South-Western 12 The Design of the Tax System.
Chapter 37 Asymmetric Information In reality, it is often the case that one of the transacting party has less information than the other. Consider a market.
Fall 2008 Version Professor Dan C. Jones FINA 4355 Class Problem.
Chapter 14 Markets with Asymmetric Information. Chapter 17Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Quality Uncertainty and the Market for Lemons Market Signaling.
Chapter 9: Health Care Market
Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income
Chapter 22: TAXATION AND SAVINGS – THEORY AND EVIDENCE
Important Social Insurance Programs
The Economics of Information. Risk a situation in which there is a probability that an event will occur. People tend to prefer greater certainty and less.
Health Insurance October 19, 2006 Insurance is defined as a means of protecting against risk. Risk is a state in which multiple outcomes are possible and.
Market Failures.
CHAPTER 6 The Medium Run CHAPTER 6 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall.
317_L17, Feb 13, 2008, J. Schaafsma 1 Review of the Last Lecture began our discussion of the case for public health insurance basic reason => market failure.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION Copyright ©2002 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. MICROECONOMIC THEORY BASIC.
More Insurance How much insurance We started talking about insurance. Question now is “how much?” Recall that John’s expected utility involves his wealth.
Government and Health Care Roughly 15 cents of every dollar spent in US is on health care US health care spending equaled $5841 per person in 2002 Governments.
Health System Reform © Allen C. Goodman, Major Themes Lower costs, or lower growth in costs. Provision of (more) equitable access to care for.
Wrapping UP Insurance Let’s Review Moral Hazard With health insurance, the amount of expenditures may depend on whether you have insurance. Suppose that.
Copyright©2004 South-Western 12 The Design of the Tax System.
Chapter 11: Cost-Benefit Analysis Econ 330: Public Finance Dr
Distribution of Income. In a free market economy there will be unequal distribution of income. The situation in Brazil: ten percent earn more than half.
Basic Tools of Finance Finance is the field that studies how people make decisions regarding the allocation of resources over time and the handling of.
Health Care; Information Today: More topics to help you think like an economist.
Chapter 6: Health Insurance Chapter 6 Health Insurance Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Social Insurance: The New Function of Government Chapter 12
The Design of the Tax System
Chapter 9 Labor Economics. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.9-2 Learning Objectives Determine why the demand curve for labor.
Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance, and Workers’ Compensation Chapter 14 Unemployment insurance, workers’ compensation, and disability insurance.
THE HEALTH CARE MARKET Chapter 9.
Chapter 20 Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation Social efficiency is maximized at the competitive equilibrium (in the absence.
CHAPTER 13 Efficiency and Equity. 2 What you will learn in this chapter: How the overall concept of efficiency can be broken down into three components—efficiency.
1 of 22 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition General Equilibrium Analysis Allocative Efficiency and Competitive Equilibrium The.
Asymmetric Information and Agency. Overview and Background Traditional models of demand side assume that individuals have complete information about prices.
Introduction to Economics: Social Issues and Economic Thinking Wendy A. Stock PowerPoint Prepared by Z. Pan CHAPTER 21 THE ECONOMICS OF HEALTH CARE Copyright.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. “In this world nothing is certain but death and taxes.”... Benjamin Franklin Taxes paid in Ben Franklin’s.
ENTREPRENEURS IN A MARKET ECONOMY
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 12-1 CHAPTER 12 Factor Markets and the Distribution of Income PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth.
11 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair General Equilibrium.
Asymmetric Information
Insurance. Standard: Protecting and Insuring People make choices to protect themselves from the financial risk of lost income, assets, health, or identity.
Chapter 19 The Equity Implications of Taxation: Tax Incidence © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of
Asymmetric Information
CHAPTER 21 Taxes, Social Insurance, and Income Distribution.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
Chapter 5 Compensating Wage Differentials Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
11 Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair General Equilibrium.
QR 24 Economics Review Session 12/3/2009. Agenda Demand curves Supply curves Equilibrium Market failures – Moral hazard – Adverse selection Net Present.
Ch. 11 General Equilibrium and the Efficiency of Perfect Competition
Chapter 37 The Fundamentals of Risk. Risk Risk - can be thought of as the possibility of incurring a loss. There are 4 main types of Risk -  Economic.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 27 Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance,
The Design of the Tax System Chapter 12. “ In this world nothing is certain but death and taxes. ”... Benjamin Franklin Taxes paid.
Market Failures and the Role of the Government
5-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications. 5-2 This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported License.
23-1 Economics: Theory Through Applications This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 3.0 Unported.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2004 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 2 Objective and Risk Management.
ETHICS IN THE MARKETPLACE chapter 5. Competition  is part of the free enterprise system. Competition tends to produce efficiency in the market and benefits.
Adverse Selection. What Is Adverse Selection Adverse selection in health insurance exists when you know more about your likely use of health services.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 29 Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers.
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. publishing as Prentice Hall 5-1 Chapter 4 Ethics in the marketplace.
Unemployment Insurance, Disability Insurance, and Workers’ Compensation Chapter 14 Unemployment insurance, workers’ compensation, and disability insurance.
The Design of the Tax System
LECTURE VII: SOSIAL INSURANCE
©2016 by McGraw-Hill Education Limited.
Compensating Wage Differentials
The Design of the Tax System
Social Insurance: Social Security
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 12 Social Insurance: The New Function of Government Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers

Introduction There has been a radical change in the nature and scope of government spending in the last half century. A set of programs known as social insurance programs have become a much larger share of the federal budget. Figure 1 illustrates this.

Breakdown of Federal Government Spending Figure 1 The proportion of federal spending on defense has declined dramatically over time. Breakdown of Federal Government Spending While spending on those programs now is much more substantial. Spending on Social Security and health care was small 50 years ago. 1953 2003

Introduction Some of the more important social insurance programs include: Social Security Unemployment Insurance Disability Insurance Workers’ Compensation Medicare

Introduction These programs have several common features: Contributions are mandatory. There is a measurable, enabling event. Benefits are not related to one’s income or assets.

Introduction To discuss these programs, we need to understand the general economics of insurance markets. Why is insurance valued by consumers? What forces may cause the insurance market to fail? What is adverse selection? What happens to social efficiency? What is moral hazard? What tradeoffs must be made in designing social insurance programs?

Introduction Central to this discussion are two key concepts: Adverse selection: the fact that the insured individual knows more about her own risk level than does the insurer. Moral hazard: when you insure individuals against adverse events, you can encourage adverse behavior.

WHAT IS INSURANCE AND WHY DO INDIVIDUALS VALUE IT?: What Is Insurance? Insurance has a common structure: Individuals pay money to an insurer, called an insurance premium. In return, the insurer promises to make some payment to the insured party (or those providing services) if an adverse event occurs. Obvious examples include health insurance, automobile insurance, life insurance, and casualty and property insurance.

Why Do Individuals Value Insurance? Insurance is valuable to individuals because of the principle of diminishing marginal utility. This principle implies that if given the choice between either (a) two years of “average” consumption or (b) one year of excessive consumption and one year of starvation, individuals would prefer the former.

Why Do Individuals Value Insurance? The reason individuals prefer choice (a) is that excessive consumption does not raise their utility as much as the starvation lowers it. Thus, individuals want to smooth their consumption, or move consumption from periods when it is high to periods when it is low.

Why Do Individuals Value Insurance? When outcomes are uncertain, individuals wish to smooth their consumption over possible states of the world. For example, two states of the world for next year might be “getting hit by a car” or “not getting hit.” The goal is to make a choice today that determines consumption in the future in each of these states of the world.

Why Do Individuals Value Insurance? Individuals choose across consumption in states of the world by using some of their income today to buy insurance against an adverse outcome tomorrow. By buying insurance, individuals commit to make a payment if the uncertain outcome is positive (no accident), in return for getting a benefit in the negative outcome case (the insurance payout).

Why Do Individuals Value Insurance? Basic insurance theory suggests that individuals will demand full insurance in order to fully smooth their consumption across states of the world. That is, the level of consumption is the same regardless of whether the accident occurred or not.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model Let p stand for the probability of an adverse event. Then expected utility is: Where C0 and C1 stand for consumption in the good and bad states of the world, respectively.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model This model can be used to examine the individual’s demand for insurance. Imagine, for example, that there was a 1% chance that Sam will get into an accident that caused $30,000 in damages. Sam can insure some, none, or all of these medical expenses. The policy costs m¢ per $1 of coverage. If Sam buys a policy that pays him $b in an accident, his premium is $mb. Full insurance in this case would cost m x $30,000. In the state of the world where Sam does get hit, he will be $b-$mb richer than if he hadn’t bought insurance. If he doesn’t get hit by the car, he will be $mb poorer than he otherwise would have been.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model That is, the insurance policy translates Sam’s consumption from periods when it is high to periods when it is low. Sam’s desire to buy the policy depends on the price that is charged. An actuarially fair premium sets the price charged equal to the expected payout.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model In this case, the expected payout is $30,000 x 1%, or $300 per policy. So a $300 premium is actuarially fair. With actuarially fair pricing, individuals will want to fully insure themselves to equalize consumption in all states of the world.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model Consider the case, for example, when the utility function is: Also assume that C0=30,000. Then expected utility without insurance is:

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model If, instead, you bought actuarially fair insurance for $300, expected utility is: Utility is higher, even though the odds are that the premium was paid for nothing. This is because you would rather have equal consumption regardless of the accident, rather than a very low level in the bad state of the world. This is illustrated in Table 1.

The expected utility model Table 1 The expected utility model If Sam … And Sam is … Consumption Utility √C Expected utility Doesn’t buy insurance Not hit by a car (D=99%) $30,000 173.2 0.99x173.2 + 0.01x0 = 171.5 Hit by a car (D=1%) Buys full insurance (for $300) $29,700 172.3 0.99x172.3 + 0.01x172.3 = 172.3 Buys partial insurance (for $150) $29,850 172.8 0.99x172.8 + 0.01x121.8 = 172.2 $14,850 121.8

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model The central result of expected utility theory is that with actuarially fair pricing, individuals will want to fully insure themselves to equalize consumption in all states of the world. Clearly Sam’s utility is higher in row 2, with full insurance, than in row 1, with no insurance. Yet, Sam also prefers full insurance to any other level of benefits. Row 3, which shows coverage for half of the costs of the accident, gives lower expected utility.

Formalizing This Intuition: Expected Utility Model Thus, even if insurance is expensive, so long as the price (premium) is actuarially fair, individuals will want to fully insure themselves against adverse events. The implication: the efficient market outcome is full insurance and thus full consumption smoothing.

The role of risk aversion Risk aversion is the extent to which an individual is willing to bear risk. Risk averse individuals have a rapidly diminishing marginal utility of consumption; they are very afraid of consumption falling. Individuals with any degree of risk aversion will buy insurance when it is priced actuarially fairly. But when the insurance is not fair, some will choose to not buy insurance.

WHY HAVE SOCIAL INSURANCE?: Asymmetric Information Insurance markets are characterized by informational asymmetry between individuals and their insurers. The individual knows more about his likelihood of an accident than does the insurer.

Asymmetric Information For example, in the health insurance market, it is likely that the person buying coverage knows more about his health problems and expected utilization than does the insurance company. The insurer will be reluctant to sell the person a policy at an actuarially fair price, since they are likely to be a “high risk.”

Asymmetric Information Assume there are 2 groups, each with 100 people. The first group has 5% chance of getting injured, and the second group has a 0.5% chance. The payout is $30,000 when injured. Table 2 shows how information affects the insurance market in this context.

Insurance pricing with separate groups of consumers With full information, the insurance company can tell the high risks from the low risks. It therefore charges separate prices to each group; competition forces it to charge an actuarially fair price. The premium to the accident prone is therefore 5% x $30,000. For the careful, it is 0.5% x $30,000. The insurance company collects $1500 x 100 from the accident prone, and $150 x 100 from the careful. Total premiums of $165,000 equal expected costs. Table 2 Now imagine the insurance company cannot tell people apart. This is a case with asymmetric information. It could continue to charge separate premiums to the different groups, taking the person’s word that they are either careful or accident prone. The insurance company collects $150 x 100 from the accident prone, and $150 x 100 from the careful. Total premiums of $30,000 are $135,000 less than expected costs. In this case, the company loses money, so it will not offer insurance. Thus, the market fails; individuals will not be able to obtain the optimal amount of insurance. Insurance pricing with separate groups of consumers Premium per: Information Pricing approach Careless (100 people) Careful Total premiums paid Total benefits paid out Net profits to insurers Full Separate $1,500 $150 $165,000 (100 x $1,500 + 100 x $150) Asymmetric $30,000 (0 x $1,500 + 200 x $150) -$135,000 Average $825 $82,500 (100 x $825 + 0 x $825) $150,000 -$67,500 The accident prone have no incentive to tell the company, however; they pay 10 times as much if they reveal truthfully about their status. Another potential alternative is that the insurance company understands it cannot tell consumers apart. Thus, it charges a uniform premium for all customers. The average cost for the population as a whole would be $165,000 in claims divided by 200 people, or $825 per person. Again, the company loses money, so it will not offer insurance. Thus, the market fails again with a pooling equilibrium. With this price structure, none of the careful people buy the policy. The company collects $825 x 100 people, but pays $1,500 x 100 people in benefits.

Asymmetric Information This example illustrates how the problem of adverse selection plagues the insurance market. People have the option of buying insurance, and will only do so if it is a fair deal for them. Only the high risks take-up the policy so it loses money.

The Problem of Adverse Selection The insurance market failed because of adverse selection–the fact that insured individuals know more about their risk level than does the insurer. This might cause those most likely to have an adverse outcome to select insurance, leading insurers to lose money if they offer insurance. Only those for whom insurance is a fair deal will buy that insurance.

The Problem of Adverse Selection For example, in the 1980s, the California health insurer HealthAmerica Corporation was rejecting all applicants to its individual health insurance enrollment program who lived in San Francisco. The company’s belief was that AIDS was too prevalent there. The company would pretend to review the applications, but would actually place them in a drawer for several weeks before sending rejection letters. This is a market failure because, with full information, individuals were likely to buy insurance at the actuarially fair premium, even if the premium were higher due to AIDS.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? Will adverse selection always lead to market failure? Not if: Most individuals are fairly risk averse, such that they will buy an actuarially unfair policy. The policy entails a risk premium, the amount that risk-averse individuals will pay for insurance above and beyond the actuarially fair price. This leads to a pooling equilibrium, which is a market equilibrium in which all types buy full insurance even though it is not fairly priced to all individuals.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? Will adverse selection always lead to market failure? In addition, the insurance company can offer separate products at separate prices, causing consumers to reveal their true types (careless or careful). This leads to a separating equilibrium, which is a market equilibrium in which different types buy different kinds of insurance products.

Does Asymmetric Information Necessarily Lead to Market Failure? The separating equilibrium still represents a market failure. Insurers can force the low risks to make a choice between full insurance at a high price, or partial insurance at a lower price. Although insurance is offered to both groups in this case, the low risks do not get full insurance, which is suboptimal.

Adverse selection and health insurance “death spirals” Application One fascinating example of adverse selection is a study of Harvard University employees by Cutler and Reber (1998). Before 1995, the out-of-pocket cost to employees was very similar across generous and less generous health insurance plans. In 1995, Harvard moved to a system where the employee was responsible for much more of the costs of the generous plans. This greatly increased the extent of adverse selection–the healthy individuals moved into less generous plans.

Adverse selection and health insurance “death spirals” Application This corresponded to moving from a pooling equilibrium to a separating equilibrium. The remaining employees in the generous plan were less healthy; this ultimately lead to an adverse selection “death spiral” where premiums increased, leading to even more switches, leading to even higher costs.

How Does The Government Address Adverse Selection? The government can help correct this kind of market failure. It could: Impose an individual mandate that everyone buy insurance at $825 per policy from the private company. It could offer the insurance directly, which would have similar effects. Both policies would lead to the low risks subsidizing the high risks.

OTHER REASONS FOR GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS Although adverse selection is a compelling motivation for government intervention in insurance markets, there are also motivations related to: Externalities Administrative costs Redistribution Paternalism

Externalities and Administrative Costs For example, there are negative externalities from underinsurance, such as the health externalities discussed in Lesson 1. There are also economies of scale in administrative costs, such as for the Medicare program. Of course, this just suggests that one large firm, not necessarily the government, should provide the coverage.

Redistribution and Paternalism Perhaps more interesting are the notions of redistribution and paternalism. With full information, insurance premiums are vastly different across individuals. For example, genetic testing may ultimately allow insurers to more accurately predict health care costs. This raises various questions related to fairness.

Redistribution and Paternalism A final motivation relates to paternalism. Individuals may simply not adequately insure themselves unless the government forces them to do so. The market failure here is the government’s own inability to commit to not helping a person who is in trouble.

SOCIAL INSURANCE VERSUS SELF-INSURANCE: HOW MUCH CONSUMPTION SMOOTHING? There are ways for individuals to consumption-smooth in the absence of insurance markets. Self-insurance is a private means of smoothing consumption over adverse events, such as one’s own savings, labor supply of family members, or borrowing from friends.

Example: Unemployment Insurance Consider unemployment insurance (UI), which provides income to workers who have lost their jobs. Although private unemployment insurance does not exist to smooth consumption, a person could: Draw on their savings Borrow, either in collateralized forms or uncollateralized forms. Have other family members increase their earnings Receive transfers from outside their extended family, friends, or local organizations.

Example: Unemployment Insurance Once we have mechanisms like these, we run into the problem that public intervention can crowd out private provision. If social insurance simply crowds out these other mechanisms, there may be no consumption smoothing gain or justification for government intervention. This is important, since there are efficiency costs of raising government revenue.

Example: Unemployment Insurance The UI replacement rate is the ratio of unemployment insurance benefits to pre-unemployment earnings. Figure 2a shows some examples of the possible relationship between the UI replacement rate and the drop in consumption when a person becomes unemployed. A larger fall in consumption means less consumption smoothing.

% Change in Consumption These 3 figures relate the UI replacement rate to consumption smoothing. In all of these cases, it is desirable to have no fall in consumption (0%). Figure 2a When no other forms of insurance are offered, and no UI is offered, consumption falls to 0. UI plays a full consumption smoothing role here. There is no crowd out. The middle panel show the case with imperfect insurance (such as a working spouse). Consumption falls by less (50%), but each $1 of UI increase consumption by less than $1. UI plays a partial consumption smoothing role here; it crowds out spousal labor supply, too. With full insurance, UI plays no consumption smoothing role. E.g., UI may crowd out savings. Perfect Insurance 0% Imperfect Insurance No Other Insurance -50% % Change in Consumption -100% 100% 100% 100% UI Replacement Rate

Example: Unemployment Insurace Panel A shows the scenario in which a person has no self-insurance (e.g., no savings, credit cards, or friends who can loan money to her). With no UI, consumption falls by 100%. Each percent of wages replaced by UI benefits reduces the fall in consumption by 1%, shown by the slope equal to 1 in panel A. In this case, UI plays a full consumption smoothing role: there is no crowd-out of self-insurance (because there is no self-insurance). Each $1 of UI goes directly to reducing the decline in consumption from unemployment.

Example: Unemployment Insurance Consider the other extreme, in panel C. A person has full insurance (perhaps private UI or rich parents). With no UI, consumption falls by 0%. Each percent of wages replaced by UI benefits does not reduce the fall in consumption at all, as shown by the slope equal to 0 in panel C. In this case, UI plays no full consumption smoothing role, and plays only a crowd-out role. Each $1 of UI simply means that there is one less dollar of self-insurance.

Example: Unemployment Insurance In a middle-ground case (Panel B), UI plays a partial consumption-smoothing role. It is both smoothing consumption and crowding out the use of self-insurance. Figure 2b summarizes these lessons. The UI consumption smoothing and crowding-out effects depend on the availability of self-insurance.

50% Partial self-insurance Figure 2b Availability of self-insurance 0% No self-insurance 50% Partial self-insurance 100% Full self-insurance UI Effects Consumption smoothing effects 100% 50% Crowding out effects

Lessons for Consumption-Smoothing Role of Social Insurance In summary, the importance of social insurance programs for consumption smoothing depends on: The predictability of the event. The cost of the event. The availability of other forms of consumption smoothing.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD When governments intervene in insurance markets, the analysis is complicated by moral hazard, the adverse behavior that is encouraged by insuring against an adverse event.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD Consider the Worker’s Compensation program, for example. Clearly, getting injured on the job is the kind of event we want to insure against. It is difficult, however, to determine whether the injury was really on-the-job or not. The insurance payouts include both medical costs of treating the injury, and cash compensation for lost wages. Under these circumstances, being “injured” on the “job” starts to look attractive.

THE PROBLEM WITH INSURANCE: MORAL HAZARD By trying to insure against a legitimate event, the program may actually encourage individuals to fake injury. Nonetheless, moral hazard is an inevitable cost of insurance, either private or social. Because of optimizing behavior, we increase the incidence of bad events simply by insuring against them.

What Determines Moral Hazard? The factors that determine moral hazard include how easy it is to detect whether the adverse event happened and how easy is it to change one’s behavior to establish the adverse event.

Moral Hazard Is Multidimensional Moral hazard can arise along many dimensions. In examining the effects of social insurance, four types of moral hazard play a particularly important role: Reduced precaution against entering the adverse state. Increased odds of entering the adverse state. Increased expenditure when in the adverse state. Supplier responses to insurance against the adverse state.

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: OPTIMAL SOCIAL INSURANCE There are four basic lessons: First, individuals value insurance and would ideally like to smooth consumption. Second, insurance markets may fail to emerge, primarily because of adverse selection. Third, private consumption smoothing mechanisms may be available; to the extent they are, one must examine new consumption smoothing versus crowding out of existing self-insurance. Fourth, expanding insurance encourages moral hazard.

PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER: OPTIMAL SOCIAL INSURANCE These lessons have policy implications. First, social insurance should be partial. Full insurance will almost always encourage adverse behavior. Second, social insurance should be more generous for unpredictable, long-term events where there is less room for private consumption smoothing. Third, more moral hazard should lead to less insurance.

Recap of Social Insurance: The New Function of Government What is Insurance and Why Do Individuals Value it? Why Have Social Insurance? Social Insurance versus Self Insurance: How Much Consumption Smoothing The Problem with Insurance: Moral Hazard Putting it All Together: Optimal Social Insurance