Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency. More Seriously Learning costs, indivisibilities giving rise to sizable fixed costs. Information and knowledge.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Advertisements

11 CHAPTER Perfect Competition.
The Closed Economy How the real interest rate keeps the goods market in equilibrium Y = C + I(r) + G.
How the real exchange rate keeps the goods market in equilibrium.
MACROECONOMICS What is the purpose of macroeconomics? to explain how the economy as a whole works to understand why macro variables behave in the way they.
 Meaning and Characteristic  Demand and Cost Curves  Product differentiation  Price determination (short and long periods)  Group Equilibrium  Selling.
Perfect Competition 12.
Chapter Nineteen Profit-Maximization.
PERFECT COMPETITION Economics – Course Companion
Equity, Efficiency and Need
General Equilibrium and Efficiency. General Equilibrium Analysis is the study of the simultaneous determination of prices and quantities in all relevant.
Market size and tax competition Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano, Tanguy van Ypersele.
Microeconomics General equilibrium Institute of Economic Theories - University of Miskolc Mónika Kis-Orloczki Assistant lecturer.
Unit 1: Trade Theory Standard Trade Model 2/6/2012.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
Neoclassical Revival 1920s and “Empty Economic Boxes” debate Developments in the 1930s –Demand Theory –Theory of Production and Cost –Welfare Economics.
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Chapter 5 A Closed- Economy One-Period Macro- economic Model Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.
Chapter 5 A Closed- Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
Who Wants to be an Economist? Part II Disclaimer: questions in the exam will not have this kind of multiple choice format. The type of exercises in the.
Differences in technology
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
Ch. 11: Perfect Competition.  Explain how price and output are determined in perfect competition  Explain why firms sometimes shut down temporarily and.
Ch. 11: Perfect Competition.  Explain how price and output are determined in perfect competition  Explain why firms sometimes shut down temporarily and.
The Theory of Aggregate Supply
1 General Equilibrium APEC 3001 Summer 2006 Readings: Chapter 16.
Endogenous Product Cycles Gene M. Grossman and Elhanan Helpman Economic Journal 101 (September 1991):
Consumption, Saving, and Investment
A Closed- Economy One-Period Macro-economic Model
The Theory of Aggregate Supply Chapter 4. 2 The Theory of Production Representative Agent Economy: all output is produced from labor and capital and in.
Tools of Analysis for International Trade Models
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
Chapter 9 Perfect Competition In A Single Market
General Equilibrium Analysis A Technological Advance: The Electronic Calculator Market Adjustment to Changes in Demand Formal Proof of a General Competitive.
© 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc Chapter 13 Competitive General Equilibrium.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright © 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.
ECON 6012 Cost Benefit Analysis Memorial University of Newfoundland
General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
The labor is worthy of his hire. —The Gospel of St.Luke
Chapter 6 Production. ©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Chapter 62 Topics to be Discussed The Technology of Production Production with One Variable Input.
 General Equilibrium and Welfare.  Partial vs. General equilibrium analysis  Partial Equilibrium: narrow focus  General equilibrium: framework of.
Production Chapter 6.
6.1 Chapter 7 – The Theory of Consumer Behavior  The Theory of Consumer behavior provides the theoretical basis for buyer decision- making and the foundation.
The Gains from Trade: A General Equilibrium View Between a good and a bad economist this constitutes the whole difference–the one takes account of the.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of 43 Theoretical Tools.
Chapter 3: Individual Markets: Demand & Supply
PERFECT COMPETITION 11 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Define perfect competition  Explain how price and output are.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behaviour: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization Copyright © 2010 Pearson Education Canada.
LECTURER: JACK WU The Theory of Property Tax. Outline Topic I: What Are Property Taxes? Topic II: Property Tax Incidence Topic III: Property Tax Capitalization.
1 Chapters 6 & 19.1 & 19.2: Exchange Efficiency, and Prices.
Slide 1 Copyright © 2002 by O. Mikhail, Graphs are © by Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
CHAPTER 31 PRODUCTION. The Robinson Crusoe Economy One consumer and one firm; The consumer owns the firm; Preference: over leisure and coconuts; Technology:
1 Chapter 4 Prof. Dr. Mohamed I. Migdad Professor in Economics 2015.
Perfect Competition CHAPTER 11. What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which  Many firms sell identical products to many.
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
Consumer Choice Theory Public Finance and The Price System 4 th Edition Browning, Browning Johnny Patta KK Pengelolaan Pembangunan dan Pengembangan Kebijakan.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Chapter 4 Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization.
Models of Competition Part I: Perfect Competition
Eco 3311 Lecture 12 One Period Closed Economy Model - Equilibrium
The Basics of Supply and Demand
Chapter 8 & 9 Pure Competition
EFFICIENCY, MARKETS, AND GOVERNMENTS
The Market System Choices Made by Households and Firms
Chapter 5 Theory of Consumer Behavior
Long-Run Analysis In the long run, a firm may adapt all of its inputs to fit market conditions profit-maximization for a price-taking firm implies that.
THE FIRM AND ITS CUSTOMERS
AS-AD curves: how natural is the natural rate of unemployment?
Presentation transcript:

Increasing Returns and Economic Efficiency

More Seriously Learning costs, indivisibilities giving rise to sizable fixed costs. Information and knowledge in production makes IR prevalent (Wilson 1975, Radner & Stiglitz 1984, Arrow 1995). Empirical evidence for IR (Ades & Glaeser 1999, Antweiler & Trefler 2002).

IR and Economic Analysis Largely ignored in the core, esp. in GE analysis. Frequently discussed in IO, development economics, international trade. Surveys: Yang & S. Ng (1998); Yang (2001), Cheng & Yang (2003). Reading: G. Sun (forthcoming).

One clear conclusion is that there are many important areas of economics in which the recognition of increasing returns makes a big difference, and changes the established wisdom significantly. …we have not yet reached the point of diminishing returns in the study of increasing returns: there is a long way to go, and the results of the work yet to be completed will be interesting (Geoffrey Heal, 1999).

Different Types of IR IR at the firm level, economies of scale. IR at the industry level due to external economies (Marshall 1920, Chipman 1970, Romer 1986). IR at the economy level due to economies of specialization (ES)/division of labour (DL) (Smith, Young, Rosen, Yang, Buchanan). IR at the world level (Ethier 1979, Chandra et al. 2002).

Different Analytical Sources of IR Property of the production function; indivisibilities. External economies due to knowledge transmission, economies internal to another industry, etc. Higher productivity from the use of more intermediate inputs (Ethier 1979, 1982). ES at the individual level (Smith, Yang).

Many Traditional Results Have to be Drastically Revised Significant IR at the firm level is inconsistent with perfect competition. Perfect competition also inconsistent with the virtually omnipresent product differentiation. But allowing for non-perfect competition play havocs to many traditional results.

A.Neutrality of money may not hold Even no time lags, money illusion, and other frictions, just non-perfect competition may make a change in nominal aggregate demand affect either the price level (the monetarist case) or the real output (the Keynesian case). Expectation wonderland (outcome depends on expectation which will be self-fulfilling) and cumulative expansion/contraction are also possible, partly explaining some real-world phenomena like business cycles, importance of confidence, and difficulties of prediction (Ng 1977, 1980, 1986, 1992, 1998, 1999; Ng & Wu 2002).

In the non-traditional cases, there exists an interfirm macroeconomic externality where the expansion by each firm benefits other firms apart from the familiar income multiplier effects. This is an area where welfare economics, macroeconomics and its micro-foundation intersect, an area still not adequately studied.

The crux of the difference Demand Side: A horizontal demand curve cannot shift left or right, only up or down. But an upward shift means an increase in price. With no time lags, money illusion, this leads to a similar shift in MC. Supply Side: MC upward-sloping under perfect competition; may be horizontal or downward sloping (esp. with IR) under non- perfect competition.

The analysis is based on a representative firm but it takes account of the influence of macro variables and the interaction (including infinite number of feedback loops) with the rest of the economy, using a simplified general-equilibrium method.

Moreover, a fully general-equilibrium analysis is used to show (1) for any (exogenous) change in cost or demand, there exists a hypothetical representative firm whose response accurately represents that of the whole economy in aggregate output and average price; (2) a representative firm defined by a simple weighted average can be used as a good approximation of the whole economy to any economy-wide change in demand and/or costs that does not result in drastic inter-firm changes. (See Ng 1986, App. 3I.)

B. Pecuniary external effects may have real efficiency implications Even where the supply/demand analysis is still applicable, if the supply curve is downward sloping due to whatever source of IR, the traditional analysis showing the absence of inefficiency of pecuniary ext. effects is no longer valid.

C. Market equilibrium no longer Pareto Optimal Well-known that IR may give rise to efficiency problems (e.g. Arrow 1987, 2000, Guesnerie 1975, Heal 1999, Quinzii 1992, Villar 1996). Pigou (1920) advocated tax/subsidy on goods with up/downward sloping supply curves. Further discussion (reprinted in AEA 1952) revealed problems. Pigous example: a non-congested, wide but uneven road and a congested, narrow but good road, to illustrate the over-use of the narrow road with increasing costs. Knight (1924): failure of pricing the congested road. With optimal pricing, no overuse.

Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) show that no general conclusion can be made. The more specific models of Heal (1980, 1999) show that the combination of imperfection competition and IR leads to the over-serving of large markets and under-serving of small markets. See also Spence 1976 on optimal product variety.

Even abstracting from monopolistic output restriction by assuming AC-pricing from contestability, Section 2 shows that goods with higher degrees of IR are under-expanded. Subsidies on goods with (high degrees of) IR financed by taxes on goods with non and lower IR may increase efficiency. But may open up a flood-gate of rent-seeking activities. Perhaps it is optimal to continue to pretend that IR do not exist. Ha! Unlikely true for all issues; otherwise, policies like encouraging the development of the great western region in China does not make sense.

Existence of AC-Pricing Equilibria with IR Theorem 1 (Brown-Heal generalized): A productively efficient AC-pricing equilibrium exists. Proof: While the production possibility set need not be convex, the production possibility frontier (super-surface) is topologically equivalent to a compact and convex set. From Brouwers fixed point theorem, any continuous mapping of a set homeomorphic to a compact and convex set onto itself possess a fixed point. Thus, any continuous mapping of the PPF has a fixed point.

Consider the following continuous mapping Ф of PPF into PPF: (G 1, …, G g ) 0 (W 1 /W R, …, W R- 1 /W R ) 0 ; (P 1, …, P G ) 0 (G d 1, …, G d g ) 1 (G 1, …, G g ) 2, where (i)(G 1, …, G g ) 0 is an arbitrary point on the PPF. (ii) (W 1 /W R, …, W R-1 /W R ) 0 is the set of relative resource prices determined by the common (to all firms using the same pair of resources) marginal rates of technical substitution as specified in (2.7) above at the point G g (R 1g, …, R Rg ) = G 0 g ; g = 1, …, G, i.e. the same point as (G 1, …, G g ) 0.

(iii)(P 1, …, P G ) 0 = product prices at AC, i.e. P 0 g = C g (W 1, …, W R, G g )/G g ;g = 1, …, G, at the given production levels given by (G 1, …, G g ) 0. (iv)(G d 1, …, G d g ) 1 is the market demand for the various goods, i.e. G d g = G 1 g + …, G I g ; g = 1, …, G, where each G i g is the individual utility-maximization quantity of the g good demanded by individual i at the set of product prices (P 1, …, P G ) 0 and resource prices (W 1 /W R, …, W R-1 /W R ) 0. (v)(G 1, …, G g ) 2 is the intersection of the ray through the point (G d 1, …, G d g ) 1 and the PPF.

Since the mapping Ф is continuous and the PPF is homeopmorphic to a compact and convex set, the mapping has a fixed point which is denoted as (G 1, …, G g )*. At this fixed point, (G 1, …, G g ) 0 = (G d 1, …, G d g ) 1 = (G 1, …, G g ) 2 = (G 1, …, G g )*. Hence, demand for goods (G 1, …, G g ) 1 equals supply (G 1, …, G g ) 0 at the product prices (P 1, …, P G )*, the AC of producing the various goods at (G 1, …, G g ) 0. The equilibrium relative resource prices (W 1 /W R, …, W R-1 /W R )* is the common MRTS specified in (2.7). This production point gives equilibrium values of resource demand R rg ; r = 1, …, R; g = 1, …, G satisfying (2.11). Finally, the individual demands for products G i g ; i = 1, …, I; g = 1, …, G total to satisfy (2.10). Since the production point is on the PPF, it is productively efficient. This completes the proof.

Efficiency of Encouraging Goods with High Degrees of IR (3.1)P g = A g for all good g, Define the (local) degree of IR (3.2)I g - ( A g / G g )G g /A g (3.5)U i g /U i h = P g /P h (Utility max.) Pareto optimality:U i g /U i h = F g /F h = M g /M h From (3.1) and (3.5), a market equilibrium: (3.8)U i g /U i h = A g /A h (3.9)I g - ( A g / G g )G g /A g = 1 – M g /A g (3.10)I g > I h iff A g /A h > M g /M h.

From (3.8) and (3.10): For any market equilibrium P: (3.11)MRS gh > M g /M h iff I g > I h. The (absolute) slope of PPF in the g/h plane equals M g /M h (with good g on the horizontal axis). If good g has a higher degree of IR than good h, the market-equilibrium MRS gh > slope of PPF. A movement down the (downward-sloping) PPF involving more good g and less good h must reach a higher indifference curve/surface. Theorem 2A: At an AC-pricing market equilibrium, if the degree of IR for good g is larger than that for good h, a point of higher efficiency (Pareto-superior) could be reached by increasing good g and decreasing h.

Next, a cost-benefit analysis is used to show Theorem 2B: At an AC-pricing market equilibrium, if the production/consumption of a good with a lower IR is decreased to allow for a corresponding increase in the production/consumption of another good with a higher IR, holding the consumption/production of other goods unchanged, the aggregate net benefits of the change is positive. A specific example confirms the above results. But, Information; rent-seeking.

Joint paper with D.S. Zhang The analysis of economies of specialization at the individual level by Yang & Shi (1992) and Yang & Ng (1993) is combined with the Dixit & Stiglitz (1977) analysis of monopolistic-competitive firms to show that, even if both the home and the market sectors have IR and there are no pre-existing taxes, it is still efficient to tax the home sector to finance a subsidy on the market sector to offset the under- production of the latter due to the failure of price-taking consumers to take account of the effects of higher consumption in reducing the average costs and hence prices, through IR or the publicness nature of fixed costs. But offset by environmental concerns.

Average-cost pricing, increasing returns, and optimal output in a model with home and market production Yew-Kwang Ng Dept. of Economics, Monash University Dingsheng Zhang Dept. of Economics, Monash University Institute for Advanced Economic Studies, Wuhan University

The Model Consider an economy with M identical consumers. Each of them has the following decision problem for consumption, working, and home production. Max: s.t.

The above optimization problem gives the following solutions:

We assume that the market structure is monopolistic competition. The production function of good r is: The first-order condition for the monopolist to maximize profit with respect to output level or price implies that

The general equilibrium values of the various variables are :

Comparative statics analysis:

Equilibrium utility value:

To analyse the welfare properties, we introduce the government to the model Assume that the tax rate of per unit home labor is, and then consumer s problem is S.t.

In addition, denoting the subsidy rate per unit of market product as, the zero- profit condition for each firm is Governments budget constrain is

we can get the equilibrium level of utility as

where

The effect of a change in tax rate on the equilibrium value of utility with respect to the tax rate, and with the subsidy rate at whatever level that is allowed by the government budget constraint as varies, evaluated at, is given by

This means that, starting from the original position without any tax/subsidy, a tax on home production which finances for a subsidy on market production increases utility, ignoring administrative costs and any possible side effects, such as rent-seeking activities triggered by the subsidy. Since all firms just break-even in equilibrium, we may base our welfare comparisons simply on the utility levels alone. We thus have,

Proposition 1: In our model with both home and market production under the conditions of increasing returns and average-cost pricing, a subsidy, if not excessive, on market production financed by a tax on home production improves efficiency even if the initial position involves no tax distortion, ignoring administrative costs and any possible side effects.

We extend the above model to allow for different sectors of market goods that may have different degrees of elasticity of substitution and different degrees of increasing returns (through different values of the fixed cost and marginal cost), we have similar results.

Proposition 2: In our model with both home and market production under the conditions of increasing returns and average-cost pricing with two sectors of different fixed costs, elasticities of substitution, and degree of importance in preference, it is efficient to tax the sector with lower fixed costs, higher elasticity of substitution and/or higher degree of importance in preference and subsidize the other.

Concluding Remarks Our conclusions applicability to the real economy is subject to important qualifications. First, the government may not have the information to differentiate which goods should be taxed (and by how much) and which subsidized. Secondly, we have not considered other factors (including rent seeking) causing imperfect efficiency in the real economy.