Reflections on Water Pricing and Tariff Design

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
PRICING WITH MARKET POWER II
Advertisements

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Overview of Working Capital Management
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Describe the effects of sales taxes and excise.
© 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley CHAPTER 1. © 2010 Pearson Addison-Wesley.
Protecting the Poor With a Carbon Tax Gilbert E. Metcalf Department of Economics Tufts University Friedrich Ebert Foundation Financing for Development.
Gender Perspectives in Introduction to Tariffs Gender Module #5 ITU Workshops on Sustainability in Telecommunication Through Gender & Social Equality.
Clicker Quiz.
Strategies for Global Value Added: Gains Comparative advantage © Professor Daniel F. Spulber.
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
Government Policies That Alter the Private Market Outcome
Supply, Demand, and Government Policies
Discussion Topics Overview of Water Rates in California Legal Framework of Water Rates Water Consumption Patterns Empirical Data – City of Fresno The.
Urban Water Conservation: Comparing Price and Non-price Policies Sheila M. Olmstead Yale University Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta June 17, 2009.
Introduction to microeconomics Demand relationships Chapter 4.
The Minimum Price Contract. Purpose of a Minimum Price Contract Minimum price contracts are one of the marketing tools available to producers to help.
GOVERNMENT ACTIONS IN MARKETS
1 CHAPTER To view a full-screen figure during a class, click the red “expand” button. To return to the previous slide, click the red “shrink” button. To.
Chapter 2 Supply and Demand.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Government Control of Prices in Mixed Systems
Effective Rate of Protection
+ Lecture 5: Price Discrimination AEM 4160: Strategic Pricing Prof. Jura Liaukonyte 1.
Trade Policy and Its Instruments
An Introduction to International Economics
PEIP Project Tariff Policy for Water and Wastewater Services.
COST REFLECTIVE TARIFFS: A Prerequisite For Financial Sustainability of a Water Utility Eng. PETER NJAGGAH WASREB, Kenya Innovative Water Sector financing.7.
Nonlinear pricing The 3 options reviewed under the heading of the regulatory dilemma can be described as linear pricing in so far as customers pay a single.
International Economics
17 International Trade and Comparative Advantage No nation was ever ruined by trade. BENJAMIN FRANKLIN International Trade and Comparative Advantage No.
Chapter 18 Pricing Policies McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 12 Capturing Surplus.
Learning Objectives After studying this chapter, you should be able to: Answer the question “What is price?” and discuss the importance of pricing in today’s.
Public Goods and Tax Policy
Who Really Pays Understanding How Cash Flows, and to Whom, Through Common Taxation Systems Understanding How Cash Flows, and to Whom, Through Common Taxation.
International Center For Environmental Finance. Series A - Course #3 Water Tariffs and Subsidies: Policy Alternatives For Decisionmakers.
The Basic of Supply and Demand Chapter 2
7 chapter: >> Taxes Krugman/Wells Economics
Copyright©2004 South-Western 12 The Design of the Tax System.
Fundamentals of Cost Analysis for Decision Making
How does the government affect us? Mixed economies = government + private sector What is the best mix???
Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 5 The Standard Trade Model.
Principles of Taxation-Chapter Two Chapter 2 Overview Raising Taxes: Income or Substitution Effect?? Desired: Neutrality or Fiscal Policy Tool? Traditional.
© 2005 Thomson C hapter 11 Price and Output in Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition, and Perfect Competition.
Chapter 14 – Efficient and Equitable Taxation
C hapter 11 Price and Output in Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition, and Perfect Competition © 2002 South-Western.
EC 355 International Economics and Finance
Tax Assignments Jorge Martinez-Vazquez Georgia State University Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations.
Fortis’ Residential Conservation Rate (RCR) How Rural Customers Are Subsidizing Lower Rates For Urban Customers.
C. Bordoy UWC Maastricht Market Failure Evaluation of policies to correct externalities.
Chapter 5: Market Failure: A Role for Government
Affordable, sustainable water and sanitation services: An OECD perspective on pricing 5 th World Water Forum, 18 March 2009 – Istanbul, Turkey Monica Scatasta.
Presentation to the Sustainable Prosperity Conference
Mixed economies = government + private sector What is the best mix???
CHAPTER 21 Taxes, Social Insurance, and Income Distribution.
KEY TERMS: Sin tax Tax loophole Sales tax Proportional tax
Sources of Government Revenue. Economic Impact of Taxes Resource Allocation Factors of production are affected Raise in production costs Higher prices.
Cost of Service Based Water and Wastewater Rates City of Lawrence, Kansas February 11, 2004 J. Rowe McKinley Keith D. Barber.
ECON chapter 9 1. __________ affect the factors of production & therefore, resource allocation.
Talha Mehmood Chapter # 5 TARIFF. Introduction The electrical energy produced by a power station is delivered to a large number of consumers. The supply.
Markets, Maximizers and Efficiency
Introduction to Economics of Water Resources. Public or private Excludability (E): the degree to which users can be excluded Subtractability (S): the.
Distribution of income. Direct and Indirect Taxation Direct taxes are paid directly to the tax authority by the taxpayer: –Personal income taxes: on all.
1 Who benefits from utility subsidies? Caroline van den Berg K. Komives, V. Foster, J. Halpern, Q. Wodon and R. Abdullah September 13, 2006.
Chapter 2 Tax Policy Issues: Standards for a Good Tax.
Elasticity. Why Economists Use Elasticity An elasticity is a unit-free measure. By comparing markets using elasticities it does not matter how we measure.
New Customer Contributions for the Water Sector: Workshop 4 August 2004.
Chapter 9 Section 1 I. Economic Impact of Taxes
Sources of Government Revenue
Presentation transcript:

Reflections on Water Pricing and Tariff Design Prof. Dale Whittington University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Prof. John Boland The Johns Hopkins University April 3, 2001

Outline of Presentation Objectives of water pricing and tariff design Alternative Tariff Structures - Definitions Observations on Increasing Block Tariffs (IBTs)

Water Tariff The set of prices, charges and taxes used to generate revenue and The rules and regulations which govern their use

Average Residential Water Tariffs - Selected Asian Cities (US$ / m3 ,1997) Price US$/m3 Cities 0.70 Jakarta Singapore, Hong Kong 0.50 Bangkok, Kuala Lumpur, Taipei Manila, Seoul 0.20 Ho Chi Minh, Colombo, Lahore Calcutta, Delhi, Beijing, Mumbai, Shanghai, Karachi, Dhaka 0.00

Functions of the Tariff Determines level and pattern of revenue Contributes to ability to attract capital Creates incentives affecting the production and use of services Influences the value of the services received and the total cost of production Allocates cost among customers, groups of customers, and over time

Purposes of the Tariff Economic Efficiency Fairness (a perception) Equity (a testable hypothesis) Revenue sufficiency Net revenue stability Simplicity and understandability Resource conservation

Additional Considerations in Tariff Design Public acceptability Political acceptability Ease of implementation Enhancement of credit rating

Criteria versus Average Tariff % who can afford a private water connection Water consumption by hh’s with private water connection Economic benefits received by hh’s with private water connection Low Medium High Very High Low Medium High Very High Low Medium High Very High US$1.00/m3 US$0.50/m3 US$0.05/m3 0.00

Criteria versus Average Tariff Revenues received by water utility Costs to water utility to deliver water supply Economic costs paid by others (e.g., subsidies needed by water utility) Medium High Low Zero Low Medium High Very High Low (None?) High Very High US$1.00/m3 US$0.50/m3 US$0.05/m3 0.00

Hierarchy of Objectives Most restrictive Least restrictive Economic Efficiency Equity Simplicity, transparency Fairness Resource conservation Net revenue stability Revenue sufficiency

Service Quality vs. Cost Recovery Asian Water Utilities Handbook,1997 Good Service Poor Service Costs Recovered Kuala Lumpur Seoul Singapore Taipei Colombo Hanoi Jakarta Lahore Costs Not Recovered Beijing Hong Kong Shanghai Kathmandu Dhaka Manila

Some Basic Tariff Options Single part tariff, consists of either: Fixed charge (not based on measured water use) Volumetric charge (based on measured water use) Two part tariff, includes both fixed and volumetric charges

Volumetric Charges Uniform price - all units of water billed at same price Block-type structures - two or more prices, each applies to use within a defined segment (block) of monthly use Decreasing block - block price falls as use rises Increasing block (IBT) - block price rises as use rises [Note: first block price usually set below cost]

Tariff Design - Uniform Price Periodic fixed (“service”) charge, e.g., US$/month/connection Single commodity price, e.g., $/m3 Example (in US$): $5.00/month for residential connection, plus $1.00/m3 for all water use

Tariff Design - Decreasing Block Periodic fixed (“service”) charge Two or more commodity prices ($/m3), decreasing with use: $5.00/month for residential connection, plus $1.50/m3 for all water used up to 15 m3/month $1.00/m3 for all water used in excess of 15 m3/month, up to 30 m3/month $0.75/m3 for all water used in excess of 30 m3/month

Tariff Design - Increasing Block (IBT) Periodic fixed (“service”) charge Two or more commodity prices ($/m3), increasing with use: $5.00/month for residential connection, plus $0.75/m3 for all water used up to 15 m3/month $1.00/m3 for all water used in excess of of 15 m3/month, up to 30 m3/month $1.50/m3 for all water used in excess of 30 m3/month

Tariff Design - Variants Increasing rate designs Combination block designs Free service allowances (form of increasing block) Seasonal water tariffs Seasonal sewer tariffs Lifeline rates

U.S. Water/Sewer Agencies 50,000+ water utilities 30,000+ wastewater utilities Urban places with 100,000+ population 300 water utilities 200 wastewater utilities

U.S. Government-Owned Water Utilities 80 percent of total 85-90 percent of large systems Very few subject to tariff regulation by State Only 12 of 50 states with laws restricting pricing practices

U.S. Investor-Owned Water Utilities 10-15 percent of large systems Subject to tariff regulation by State agency, based on rate-of-return

U.S. Water Tariffs

Commonly Overlooked Facts I Water and sewer services are bundled commodities Users respond to the sum of water and sewer tariffs Developing tariffs separately according to different criteria is illogical

Commonly Overlooked Facts II Prices determine water use, not tariff design Each user responds to his/her last block price regardless of what other prices may be, or what other users may do. Block type rates permit price discrimination, individual users respond to the price in specific block(s)

Increasing Block Tariffs (IBTs) Still actively promoted in developing countries Water pricing is an important instrument for stimulating efficient use of water. A basic amount could be used at a relatively low rate, while water consumption beyond that amount could be charged with progressively higher rates. (Urban Water Resources Management, UN, 1993, p 19). Widely used in OECD countries

IBT Example: La Paz, Bolivia

Examples of IBTs

What is Rationale for IBTs? Claimed to transfer income from rich to poor Claimed to transfer income from firms to poor HHs Very high prices in top blocks claimed to discourage “extravagant” and “wasteful” use IBTs are said to implement marginal cost pricing principles IBTs are said to reflect assumed rising marginal cost curves

IBT Rationale Revisited I Rich subsidize the poor Average price rises with HH use. Therefore, to the extent that water use is correlated with income, subsidy occurs. Maximum possible subsidy is small (typically US$1 to US$3 per month) Subsidy is regressive within the lower blocks

IBT Rationale Revisited II Firms subsidize poor households IBTS produce such a subsidy Subsidy is regressive within the lower blocks If subsidy were desirable, it could be achieved more easily by sectorally differentiated prices Subsidy may not be desirable: large users may exit system, increasing average costs for residential users

IBT Rationale Revisited III IBTs discourage “extravagant” or “wasteful” use No clear what “extravagant” means If “wasteful” means uses that do not justify the resource cost of the water, then: Setting price equal to marginal cost means that every customer pays to replace every unit of water taken, regardless of the type of use No further incentive is necessary or desirable

IBT Rationale Revisited IV IBTs are consistent with marginal cost pricing There is only one marginal cost for a given class of customers at a given time IBTs result in different customers within the class paying different prices at any given time, based on their total monthly use At most one of these prices can equal marginal cost; all others represent a divergence from marginal cost pricing principles

IBT Rationale Revisited V IBTs track rising marginal costs Marginal cost is not necessarily rising, even in developing countries If marginal cost is rising, it rises as a function of aggregate water use; it does not change perceptibly with changes in water use by a single HH Prices are meant to reflect the costs imposed by additional water use by the HH. These are the same for all HHs in a given class at any given time. Marginal cost may rise over time; then prices should also rise over time, but for all uses

Limitations of IBTs in Practice Difficulty in limiting size of the first block Difficult to provide proper economic incentives to most customers Difficult to meet revenue target without large departures from marginal cost Lack of transparency and difficulty of administration In the case of shared connections, or where connected HHs resell water to vendors, IBTs increase cost to the very poor

An Alternative to Increasing Block Tariffs Use lump-sum transfers for income redistribution and other fairness objectives This allows the choice of a uniform price design, preferable according to all other criteria Lump-sum transfers can lead to negative fixed charges for some users

A Practical Alternative to IBTs: Uniform Price with Rebate (UPR)

Household Water Bill: UPR vs. IBT Household’s Monthly Water Use (m3) Uniform Price with Rebate Increasing Block Tariff 5 US$2.50 10 US$3.31 US$5.00 15 US$8.31 US$7.50 20 US$13.31 US$12.50 25 US$18.31 US$17.50

Two-Part Tariff: Evaluation Both tariffs produce the same revenue Two-part tariff provides improved incentives: More HHs face full marginal cost with a UPR than with a IBT. Only the smallest, most price inelastic HHs face a zero incremental price Two-part tariff more effective in transferring income: Per-HH transfer is larger Transfer is not regressive

Two-Part Tariff: Evaluation Two-part tariff is simple and transparent Two-part tariff is more equitable Advantages of two-part tariff even greater when compared to a multi-step IBT

Conclusions Usual rationales for employing IBTs are either incomplete or incorrect There are significant practical difficulties with the application of IBTs in developing countries If the purpose of an IBT is to redistribute revenue, alternative tariff designs can do so more effectively IBTs, on the other hand, introduce inefficiency, inequity, complexity, lack of transparency, revenue instability, and forecasting difficulties

Conclusions (cont.) Properly designed tariffs are powerful management tools Comparisons of alternative designs can be complex No single design fits all circumstances Increasing block designs, though widely used, have many disadvantages Better tariff design is possible