The Theory of Consumer Choice Part I. Class Business Homework 1 is due Wednesday, June 26 th. Make sure you read Chapter 1 of The Armchair Economist for.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 3 Rational Consumer Choice
Advertisements

Chapter 6 From Demand to Welfare McGraw-Hill/Irwin
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
Chapter 5 Appendix Indifference Curves
UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE
1 Labor Supply From Indifference Curves. 2 Overview In this chapter we want to explore the economic model of labor supply. The model assumes that individuals.
Rational Consumer Choice. Chapter Outline The Opportunity Set or Budget Constraint Budget Shifts Due to Price or Income Changes Consumer Preferences The.
Chapter 6 theory of Consumer behavior
Chapter 5 Demand: The Benefit Side of the Market
UNIT I: Theory of the Consumer
The Theory of Consumer Choice
Consumer Preferences chapter 4
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Calculate and graph a budget line that shows the.
Consumer Equilibrium and Market Demand Chapter 4.
12 Consumer Choice and Demand
11 PART 4 Consumer Choice and Demand A CLOSER LOOK AT DECISION MAKERS
Chapter Four Consumer Choice.
Chapter 21 - Consumer Choice
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
1 Stephen Chiu University of Hong Kong Utility Theory.
Part 2 Demand © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Theory of Consumer Behavior Basics of micro theory: how individuals choose what to consume when faced with limited income? Components of consumer demand.
Chapter 20: Consumer Choice
Schedule of Classes September, 3 September, 10 September, 17 – in-class#1 September, 19 – in-class#2 September, 24 – in-class#3 (open books) September,
Chapter 5: Theory of Consumer Behavior
CHAPTER 5 Consumer Choice Theory. CHAPTER 5 Consumer Choice Theory.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Consumer Preferences and
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Consumer Preferences, Utility Functions and Budget Lines Overheads.
1 Consumer Choice. 2 Historical Backdrop The objective of business: maximize profits, to increase the difference between incoming revenues and outgoing.
CHAPTERS 8 Utility and Demand
1.6 Theory of Consumer Behavior Blog posts: "Utility" Theory of Consumer Behavior (AP only unit) Total Utility and Marginal Utility Utility Maximization.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand Chapter 8.
Module 12: Indifference Curves and Budget Constraints
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Principles of Microeconomics
5.1 Household Behavior and Consumer Choice We have studied the basics of markets: how demand and supply determine prices and how changes in demand and.
Economic Analysis for Business Session XV: Theory of Consumer Choice (Chapter 21) Instructor Sandeep Basnyat
The Theory of Consumer Choice
BACHELOR OF ARTS IN ECONOMICS Econ 111 – ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Pangasinan State University Social Science Department – PSU Lingayen CHAPTER 7 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Economics Jonathan Gruber Public Finance and Public Policy Aaron S. Yelowitz - Copyright 2005 © Worth Publishers.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Copyright (c) 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Utility The pleasure people get from their economic activity. To identify all of the factors.
n Individual’s demand curve: Why does it slopes downward? Why does it slopes downward? n Why do people demand goods and services? Receive satisfaction.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Lecture 7 Consumer Behavior Required Text: Frank and Bernanke – Chapter 5.
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 32©2005 Pearson Education, Inc. Introduction How are consumer preferences used to determine demand? How do consumers.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Question: Mary goes to the movies eight times a month and seldom goes to a bar. Tom goes to the movies once a month and goes.
Consumer Behavior Topic 4. Utility  Like elasticity, Utility is another fancy name for satisfaction or happiness  Utility refers to satisfaction derived.
Fundamentals of Microeconomics
Consumer Behavior & Utility Maximization ECO 2023 Chapter 7 Fall 2007 Created by: M. Mari.
MICROECONOMICS: Theory & Applications By Edgar K. Browning & Mark A. Zupan John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 10 th Edition, Copyright 2009 PowerPoint prepared by.
The Theory of Consumer Choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of.
Lecture 4 Consumer Behavior Recommended Text: Franks and Bernanke - Chapter 5.
Lecture by: Jacinto Fabiosa Fall 2005 Consumer Choice.
S PP 2 T OPIC 1 I SSUE 2: C HANGE IN PRICES AFFECT CONSUMER ’ S CHOICES T HE THEORY OF CONSUMER CHOICE Xiaozhen Chen Hai Tran.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
5 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business PublishingPrinciples of Economics, 7/eKarl Case, Ray Fair Household Behavior and Consumer Choice Appendix: Indifference.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
1 © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. Consumer Decision Making In our study of consumers so far, we have looked at what they do, but not why they do what they.
Consumer Behavior: Utility Maximization
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
Presentation transcript:

The Theory of Consumer Choice Part I

Class Business Homework 1 is due Wednesday, June 26 th. Make sure you read Chapter 1 of The Armchair Economist for Monday!

The Right Thing to Do

The Trolley Problem Suppose you find yourself near some train tracks. A trolley is racing down the tracks, and next to you is a lever that will switch the tracks and send the trolley down another path. Playing on the tracks are some kids. If you pull the lever, the trolley will go down a track with only one kid on it. There is no doubt that if you pull this lever, that one kid will die. If you do not pull the level, the trolley will go down a track with five kids on it. There is no doubt that if you do not pull this lever, all five kids will die. What do you do?

The Trolley Problem Part 2 Suppose that you are standing on top of a bridge, watching as a trolley is racing toward some kids playing on the tracks. On the bridge with you is a very fat man. If you push the fat man off the bride, onto the tracks, he will surely die, but he will also surely stop the trolley, for he is a very fat man. If you do not push the fat man, the trolley will continue past the bridge and kill five children playing in the trolleys path. What do you do?

The Trolley Problem Part 3 Suppose that you are a doctor with five very sick patients. Each patient is in need of a transplant. One needs a heart, the second a kidney, the third a liver, the fourth a lung, and the fifth also needs a kidney. A man walks into your office with a minor health issue, but while running some tests you realize that he would be a viable donor for all five of your other patients. If you cure this man of his minor health issue and send him on his way, there is no doubt your other five patients will die. If you kill this man and take his organs, all five of your other patients will surely live. What do you do?

Ethics There are two prominent theories about how one ought to act: Deontology: Decisions should be made according to a set of rules. Categorical Imperative: A proposition that declares a certain action to be necessary. Act only according to that maxim whereby you can at the same time will that it should become a universal law without contradiction. Contractarianism: We must construct a social contract that governs behavior. John Rawls: Do the constructing behind a veil of ignorance in the original position. Natural Rights: Human beings have absolute, natural rights. John Locke: Natural right to defend Life, health, Liberty, or Possessions. Consequentialism: Morality depends on the outcome. Utilitarianism: Maximize happiness and reduce suffering. Jeremy Bentham: It is the greatest happiness of the greatest number that is the measure of right and wrong.

Hedonic Calculus The philosopher Jeremy Bentham ( ), and his student John Stuart Mill ( ) are considered the fathers of Utilitarianism. Bentham suggested counting up units of pleasure and pain based on the following dimensions: Intensity: How strong is the pleasure? Duration: How long will the pleasure last? Uncertainty: How likely is it that the pleasure will occur? Propinquity: How soon will the pleasure occur? Fecundity: The probability that the action will be followed by sensations of the same kind. Purity: The probability that it will not be followed by sensations of the opposite kind. Extent: How many people will be effected? Benthamite Francis Edgeworth imagined the intensity could be measured by a machine, which he called the hedonometer.

No Relic of the Past Daniel Kahneman and his co- authors have tried to estimate how much people enjoy various activities.

Fun with Jeremy Bentham Benthams will requested that his head be mummified and his skeleton preserved, and put on display. His wished were granted and you can see him at University College London.

Modern Economics Most consider the birth of economics as a field of study to be Adam Smiths The Wealth of Nations. Smith was a moral philosopher concerned with how people ought to behave. His studies led him to evaluate why some had more than others. Economics remained closely associated with moral philosophy through the 19 th century. I think it is a great error that the authors of our textbook decided not to mention any of this. There is no such thing as philosophy-free science; there is only science whose philosophical baggage is taken on board without examination. – Daniel Dennett

Utility In modern parlance, Utilitarianism asks us to maximize utility. What exactly is utility measuring? In economics, utility is synonymous with happiness or well-being. We assume that people know what makes them happy, and how happy it makes them. The burgeoning field of neuroeconomics has been looking for something more concrete than these abstract concepts. Many studies have looked at neurochemical responses to economic decisions. Some postulate that were talking about surges in neurotransmitters like dopamine.

The Economic Concept of Utility

An Example of Utility

Indifference Different combinations of goods can make us equally as well off. We might calculate that our well-being is just as higher whether we go for pizza or for Chinese food. We might be just as happy buying 3 oranges and 2 apples as we are buying 1 orange and 6 apples. Evaluating where people are indifferent cant help us to determine how people end up choosing what they get.

Every Combination J o h n W i l l i a m s Billy Joel We can graph this function at a constant utility to see all of the possible consumption bundles that make us that happy.

Changing Utility John Williams Billy Joel

Indifference Curves Indifference Curves plot all of the market baskets (combinations of goods) a consumer views as being equally satisfactory. ICs hold utility constant, but allow the composition to change. Due to the laws of mathematics, the same composition cannot yield two different utilities. 2.5 hours of John Williams and 2.5 hours of Billy Joel always gives utils. The important conclusion of this proposition is that indifference curves cannot cross. W B W B W B

Trade-Offs In order to maintain a constant level of well-being, every loss must come with a corresponding gain. The rate at which we replace losses is called the marginal rate of substitution, and it measures our willingness to trade one good for another. UtilityBW

Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate at which we would give up hours of John Williams to get hours of Billy Joel is 9 hours of Joel for 7 hours of Williams. From a starting point of 2.5 hours spent on each, we would be just as well off listening to 1.29 hours more of Billy Joel and 1 hour less of John Williams This is the slope of the indifference curve. UtilityBW

Slope of the Curve The rate at which we are willing to trade one good for another marks the slope of our indifference curve. This will turn out to be a big help later on. UtilityBW J o h n W i l l i a m s Billy Joel Slope = 9/7

Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is a measure of an individuals willingness to trade one good for another. The MRS represents our marginal benefit of consuming a particular good. We value 1 hour of John Williams at 1.29 hours of Billy Joel. Value is determined relative to our other options. This value represents our benefits of gaining additional units of a good. Most indifference curves exhibit a diminishing marginal rate of substitution. When you have something in abundance, you are not willing to give up much to get more of it. When you dont have much of something you want, you will give up a lot to get it.

The Utility Approach

BWUtility BWUtility

Indifference Curves Applications and Examples

Introducing the Composite Good A composite good is a number of goods treated as a group. Usually we use this to express all off the other opportunities that we have. Ex. If we are evaluating how much pizza to buy, the composite good represents all of the other things we could spend that same money on. This is a clever convention that allows us to analyze how we choose without restraining ourselves to a single alternative.

Changing Attitudes We all have different tastes that can be represented by indifference curves. When we really like something, we need a lot of something else to get us to give some of it up. This makes the MRS very steep, and the indifference curve tilts towards our favored good. Jurassic Park U1U1 X

Worthless Things As we become less and less concerned about one of the goods we are consuming, the IC becomes flatter. Jurassic Park 2 U2U2 X

A Deep Dislike There are some goods which we may actually dislike. In order to offset getting more of the economic bad, we need more of the economic good. Jurassic Park 3 U3U3 X

Perfect Substitutes The shape of our indifference curve can be inferred by what we know about the relationship between two goods. What would an indifference curve between two perfect substitutes look like? Shell Gas U1U1 For most people, gas stations are perfect substitutes for each other. What does this trade-off look like?

Perfect Compliments Perfect compliments are consumed in equal proportion to each other. We only get utility from one if we a matching unit of the other. Left Shoe U1U1 Getting an additional right shoe affords us no additional utility. We are indifferent between 2 pairs of shoes and 2 pairs of shoes plus one extra right shoe.

Indifference Curve Basics Indifference curves visualize our preferences for certain things. By comparing them to composite goods, we see what trade-offs we have to make. We gain utility as an indifference curve moves away from the origin. Higher utility means we are better off. Importantly, though, indifference curves for the same person cannot cross. The slope of the indifference curve, the marginal rate of substitute, measures the marginal benefit of our consumption.

The Budget Constraint

Our choices depend not only on our preferences, but also on our wealth.

+1 Graphing our Budget Constraint Imagine we are at the grocery store deciding how much Diet Wild Cherry Pepsi to buy. Pepsi costs $3 a 12-pack. The composite good costs $1. 12-Packs of Pepsi All other goods (X) Total money spent Pepsi X 15 5 The Budget Constraint represents all of the affordable bundles of goods. -3

The Price Ratio The Price Ratio is the slope of the budget constraint. A price ratio of -3 tells us that if we want to get one 12-pack of Pepsi, we have to give up three units of the composite good. The price ratio measures the marginal cost of getting one more unit of a good in terms of the value of the alternatives. Because prices are usually fixed, the budget constraint is often a straight line. This is not always true, however, and some of the most interesting problems involve unusual budget constraints.

Changes in Income The budget constraint holds income constant. Therefore, when income changes, the budget constraint shifts. The intercepts of this line are always income divided by price. Pepsi X

Changes in Price Suppose Pepsi goes on sale, and now costs only $2 a 12- pack. 12-Packs of Pepsi All other goods (X) Total money spent Pepsi X 15 5

Price Change Suppose Pepsi goes on sale, and now costs only $2 a 12- pack. 12-Packs of Pepsi All other goods (X) Total money spent Pepsi X Packs of Pepsi All other goods (X) Total money spent

Changes in Price Price increases slide the intercept toward the origin. Price decreases slide the intercept away from the origin. Note that the intercept for a good whose price is not changing remains the same. Pepsi X

Changes in the Price Ratio Changes to income do not change the price ratio. Changes to prices do change the price ratio. Pepsi X

Changes in the Price Ratio Changes to income do not change the price ratio. Changes to prices do change the price ratio. Pepsi X

Budget Constraint Basics Budget Constraints visualize every affordable bundle of goods. We are constrained by prices and our income. We can only choose what we can afford. As income rises, budget constraints move away from the origin. However, the slope of the budget constraint remains the same. As prices rise, budget constraints tilt inwards, finding a new intercept at the maximum number of that good we can afford. Price changes change the slope of the budget constraint. The slope of the budget constraint represents the marginal cost of purchasing another unit of a good.

The Consumers Choice

Back to the Beginning Our goal is to maximize our utility. Unfortunately, we are constrained by prices and income. Utility increases as our indifference curve moves away from the origin. We can only afford consumption baskets on or below our budget constraint. So where do we choose?

Sweet Spot Pepsi X At this level of utility, we have an array of affordable options. At this level of utility, we have only one affordable option. At this level of utility, we no affordable options. P* X*

The Greatest Good Pepsi X P* X*

By the Numbers This chart shows affordable consumption bundles. XPCostUtility We can afford 10 Pepsis if we buy 0 of the composite good, but our utility function doesnt like this. As we get a mix of the goods our utility rises. But it is this particular bundle that we like the most. XPUtilit y ΔUΔU XPUtilit y ΔUΔU

The Greatest Good Pepsi X P* X* 5 10

5 Graphical Analysis It is where the slopes of our two lines are equal at the highest affordable utility that the consumers choice is made. At this point marginal benefit (MRS) is equal to marginal cost (PR). Pepsi X Slope = 1/2 Slope = 1/2

Alternative Logic Imagine that you are starting with $10, and you are deciding how much of it you want to spend on candy, and how much of it you want to spend on Star Wars action figures. CandyUtilityΔUΔU SWAFUtilityΔUΔU For simplicity, lets pretend that both candy and Star Wars action figures cost $1 each. How should we spend our first dollar? How should we spend our second dollar? How should we spend our third dollar? How should we spend our fourth dollar? How should we spend our fifth dollar? How should we spend our sixth dollar? How should we spend our money?

Marginal Utility Per Dollar

Breaking it Down MU C : The utility gained per unit of candy. P C : The price of candy. MU C /P C : The utility gained per dollar spent on candy. MU S : The utility gained per action figure. P S : The price of action figures. MU S /P S : The utility gained per dollar spent on action figures.

The Answer to All of the Questions Marginal BenefitMarginal Cost

A Users Guide to Consumer Theory This framework of indifference curves and budget constraints offers us some relatively simple tools for prediction. We can examine how people will respond to all kinds of changes in their environment, from price changes to complex public policy. It finds the utilitarian consequences of various actions. This framework also provides with the raw materials we need to understand demand.

Next Time on Microeconomics Well take a closer look at the math behind consumer theory. Then well start using consumer theory to answer some questions.