Environmental Economics

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Homework #9 due Thursday Quiz #4 on Thursday Homework #10 due Dec. 2 nd Exam #4 on Dec. 2 nd Last week of class – Group Presentations.
Advertisements

Public Goods and Tax Policy
Upcoming in Class Homework #5 Due Today Homework #6 Due Oct. 25
Section 3/6/2009  VSL  Static vs. Dynamic Efficiency (Example: optimal extraction of a non-renewable resource)  Defining/ measuring scarcity  Definitions.
Non-renewable Resources: Optimal Extraction
 Homework #5 Due Monday  Homework #6 Due Oct. 22  Extra Credit Writing Assignment Oct. 17th  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 24th.
Sustainable Development – defining the concept Quest of all of us.
11 PERFECT COMPETITION CHAPTER.
Upcoming in Class Homework #5 Due Next Tuesday Oct.
Chapter 7 General Equilibrium and Market Efficiency
Chapter 14 – Efficient and Equitable Taxation
Chapter 9 © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western Profit Maximization and Supply.
 Homework #5 Due Monday  Homework #6 Due Oct. 22  Extra Credit Writing Assignment Oct. 17th  Writing Assignment Due Oct. 24th.
Economics of abiotic resources
Chapter 2 The Economic Approach:
Copyright © 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 7 The Allocation of Depletable and Renewable Resources: An Overview.
Chapter 6 Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost.
Chapter 15 Factor Markets Work is of two kinds: first, altering the position of matter at or near the earth’s surface relative to other matter; second,
Introduction to Economics Chapter 17
Efficiency and Sustainability
Part I. Principles A.Markets B.Market failure C.Discounting & PV D.Markets 2 E.Dynamic efficiency F.Pollution solutions.
Normative Criteria for Decision Making Applying the Concepts
Sustainability chapter 5. what else besides efficiency? fairness or justice should accompany efficiency concern this chapter considers one particular.
Environmental Economics Class 6. Concepts Static efficiency Dynamic efficiency Static efficiency allows us to evaluate those circumstances where time.
Chapter 2 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance © 2007 Worth Publishers Public Finance and Public Policy, 2/e, Jonathan Gruber 1 of 43 Theoretical Tools.
Investment in Human Capital Model-Part I Topic 3 Part III.
© 2009 Pearson Education Canada 5/1 Chapter 5 Intertemporal Decision Making and Capital Values.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
The Standard Trade Model
Efficient Allocation of a Non-renewable Mineral Resource Over Time Monday, March 13.
1 Consumer Choice and Demand CHAPTER 6 © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Third Edition Copyright © 2010 Worth Publishers 1 of 44 Theoretical Tools of Public Finance F ERNANDO.
Static Efficiency, Dynamic Efficiency and Sustainability Wednesday, January 25.
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization 21 C H A P T E R.
Environmental Economics Sedef Akgüngör Lecture 3.
Sustainable Development Part 1: Measuring sustainability.
Chapter 5 Dynamic Efficiency and Sustainable Development
Introduction to Economics of Water Resources. Public or private Excludability (E): the degree to which users can be excluded Subtractability (S): the.
Efficient Allocation of a Non-renewable Mineral Resource Over Time Wednesday, March 2.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
1 Chapter 22 The Short – Run Macro Model. 2 The Short-Run Macro Model In short-run, spending depends on income, and income depends on spending –The more.
Chapter 8: The Labor Market
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Chapter 19 Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
The Standard Trade Model
CASE FAIR OSTER ECONOMICS P R I N C I P L E S O F
Models of Competition Part I: Perfect Competition
Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of markets
Optimal Pricing of Renewable and Non-Renewable Energy
Chapter 15 Market Interventions McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Valuing the Environment: Concepts
The Short – Run Macro Model
Consumer Choice and Demand
Introduction to Economics of Water Resources Lecture 5
ENRE Lecture 1, Part 1 Environmental Policy Objectives
Theoretical Tools of Public Finance
CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS
Consumer Choice and Demand
Chapter 3 The Demand For Labor.
Utility Maximization Ch7
Background to Demand: The Theory of Consumer Choice
International Trade and Economic Growth
Consumer Behavior and Utility Maximization
WELFARE FOUNDATION OF CBA
Capital, Interest, and Corporate Finance
Economic Analysis, A Primer
Environmental Economics
A Summer Research Experience for Undergraduates Program in China
Presentation transcript:

Environmental Economics Fall 2017 wangsufeng927@ahjzu.edu.cn

Introduction Two specific means for identifying environmental problems: first, static efficiency for where time is not crucial; second, dynamic efficiency suitable for those where time is crucial. Remember: efficiency criteria are is a desirable attribute , but it is not the only possible one.

Introduction We will investigate one particular fairness concern – the treatment of future generations. Considering a specific, ethically challenging situation – the allocation of a depletable resource over time. Specifically, trace out the temporal allocation of a depletable resource that satisfies the dynamic efficiency criterion and show how it is affected by discount rates.

1. A two-period model Assume that we have a fixed supply of a depletable resource to allocate between two periods. Assume further that the demand function is the same in each of the two periods, the marginal willingness to pay is given by the formula P = 8 – 0.4q, and marginal cost of supplying that resource is constant at $2 per unit.

1. A two-period model Figure 5.1 The allocation of an abundant depletable resource: (a) period 1 and (b) period 2

1. A two-period model If the total supply were 30 or greater, and we were concerned only with the two periods, an efficient allocation would produce 15 units in each period, regardless of the discount rate. In this case, the static efficiency criterion is sufficient because the allocations are not temporally interdependent.

1. A two-period model Suppose the available supply equals 20. According to the dynamic efficiency criterion, the efficient allocation is the one that maximizes the present value of the net benefit. The present value of the net benefit for both periods is simply the sum of the present values in the two periods.

1. A two-period model Consider a particular allocation: 15 units in the first period, and 5 in the second. The present value in the first period would be that portion of the geometric area under the demand curve and over the supply curve - $45.

1. A two-period model Consider a particular allocation: 15 units in the first period, and 5 in the second. The present value in the second period is that portion of the area under the the demand curve and over the supply curve from the origin to the five units produced multiplied by 1/(1+r).

1. A two-period model Suppose r = 0.1, then the present value of the net benefit received in the second period is $22.73, and the present value of the net benefits for any allocation. Therefore, the present value of the net benefits for the 2 years is $67.73.

1. A two-period model We have learned how to find the present value of net benefits for any allocation. But, how does one find the allocation that maximizes present value ?

1. A two-period model The dynamically efficient allocation of this resource has to satisfy the condition that the present value of the marginal net benefit from the last unit in Period 1 equals the present value of the marginal net benefit in period 2.

1. A two-period model Look at period 1 from left to right Look at period 2 from right to left Figure 5.2 The dynamic efficient allocation

1. A two-period model First, the zero axis for period 2 net benefits is on the right. Second, the present value of the marginal benefit curve for period 2 intersects the vertical axis at a different point than does the comparable curve in period 1. Consider the discount rate. (0,6), (15,0) for period 1; (0,5.45), (15,0) for period 2. Trapezoid 梯形

1. A two-period model The efficient allocation is now readily identifiable as the point where the two curves representing present value of marginal net benefits cross (why?) The total present value of net benefits is then the area of the two trapezoids. Trapezoid 梯形

1. A two-period model Intertemporal scarcity imposes an opportunity cost that we henceforth refer to as the marginal user cost (MUC). When resources are scarce, greater current use diminishes future opportunities. MUC is the present value of these forgone opportunities at the margin.

1. A two-period model MUC With 30 or more units, the resource would not be scarce, and the MUC would be zero. With 20 units, however, scarcity emerges. The PV of the MUC, the additional value created by scarcity, is the vertical distance between the quantity (horizontal) axis and the intersection of the two PV curves.

1. A two-period model MUC Notice that the PV of the MUC for period 1 is equal to the PV of the MUC for period 2. (the common value: $1.905) An efficient market would have to consider not only the marginal cost of extraction for this resource, but also the MUC.

1. A two-period model MUC In the absence of scarcity, the price would equal only the marginal cost of extraction; Whereas with scarcity, the price would equal the sum of marginal extraction cost and MUC.

1. A two-period model MUC Solve for the prices that would prevail in an efficient facing scarcity over time. Inserting the efficient quantities for the two periods (10.238 and 9.762) into the WTP function (P = 8 – 0.4q), it yields P1=3.905 and P2=4.095. Compare Figure 5.3 with Figure 5.1, you can find the impact of scarcity on price.

1. A two-period model Figure 5.3 The efficient market allocation of a depletable resource: The constant-marginal-cost case: (a) period 1 and (b) period 2

2. Defining intertemporal fairness While no generally-accepted standards of fairness or justice exist, some have more prominent support than others. One such standard concerns the treatment of future generations.

2. Defining intertemporal fairness Imagine a hypothetical meeting of all members of present and future generations. If these members are prevented by the veil of ignorance from knowing the generation to which they will belong, then a sustainability criterion may play a role.

2. Defining intertemporal fairness A sustainability criterion suggests that, at a minimum, future generations should be left no worse off than current generations. Allocations that impoverish future generations in order to enrich current generations are, according to this criterion, patently unfair.

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? In the two-period example, net benefits in the second period are lower than in the first. Sustainability does not allow earlier generations to profit at the expense of later generations. however, appearances can be deceiving. (why?)

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? Because choosing this particular extraction path does not prevent those in the first period from saving some of the net benefits for those in the second period. If the allocation is dynamically efficient, it will always be possible to set aside sufficient net benefits accrued in the first period for those in the second period.

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? Numerical example: you believe that setting aside half (10 units) of the available resources for each period would be a better allocation than the dynamic efficient allocation. Then, the net benefits to each period from this alternative scheme would be $40. Can you see why ? Q=10,P=4. The net benefits to each period is: (4-2)*10+0.5*(8-4)*10=40

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? Suppose q=10 in period 1, then P=8-0.4q=4. Net benefit:2*10+0.5*4*10=40 P 8 D 4 2 MC 10 20 q Q=10,P=4. The net benefits to each period is: (4-2)*10+0.5*(8-4)*10=40

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? Now let’s compare this to an allocation of net benefits that could be achieved with the dynamic efficient allocation. For the dynamic efficient allocation, it should produce an outcome such that each generation would be at least as well off as it would be with the equal allocation and one will be better off.

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? For the dynamic efficient allocation, it should produce an outcome such that each generation would be at least as well off as it would be with the equal allocation and one will be better off.

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? In the dynamic efficient allocation with no sharing, the net benefits to the first period were 40.466, while those for the second period were 39.512. This violates the sustainability criterion, because the second generation is worse off than it would be with equal sharing (39.512<40).

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? However, suppose the first generation was willing to share some of the net benefits with the second generation. For example, the first generation saves the extra $0.466 ($40.466-$40) at 10%, this savings would grow to $0.513=$0.466*(1+10%). Then, the second generation would receive $40.025=$39.512+$0.513.

3. Are efficient allocations fair ? This illustrates that although dynamic efficient allocation do not automatically satisfy sustainability criteria, they could be compatible with sustainability, even in an economy relying heavily on depletable resources. The prerequisite that the second period can be better off is the share between generations.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion One of the difficulties in using the sustainability criterion is its application. The guarantee of equity between generations requires us not only to know the allocation over time, but also the preferences of future generations! Thanks to the “Hartwick Rule”.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion “Hartwick Rule”: a constant level of consumption could be maintained perpetually from an environmental endowment if all the scarcity rent derived from resources extracted from that endowment were invested in capital. That level of investment should be sufficient to assure that the value of capital stock would not decline. 哈特威克规则:如果人们将环境禀赋中资源开采得到的所有稀缺租金以资本方式进行投资,那么就可以将资源的消费始终维持在一个固定水平上。投资水平应该足以保证总资本存量的价值不会降低。

4. Applying the sustainability criterion First, it is possible to judge the sustainability of an allocation by examining whether or not the value of total capital stock is declining. This test can be performed each year without knowing anything about future allocations or preferences. Second, the degree of sharing to produce a sustainable outcome is that, all scarcity rent must be invested.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion Suppose a grandparent left you an inheritance of $10,000 and you put it in a bank where it earns 10% interest. If you withdrew $1,000 per year, the amount in the bank would remain $10,000 and the income would last forever; you spend only the interest, leaving the principal intact. But ,if you spend more than $1,000 per year, then …

4. Applying the sustainability criterion If you spend more than $1,000, your principal would decline over time and the balance would go to zero eventually. Therefore, spending $1,000 per year or less would satisfy the sustainability criterion, while spending more would violate it.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion In this context, what does the Hartwick Rule mean? It suggests that one way to tell whether an allocation (spending pattern) is sustainable or not, is to examine what is happening to the value of the principal over time. The allocation (spending pattern) is sustainable only if the principal is increasing or remaining constant.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion (for environment) The Hartwick Rule suggests that the current generation has been given an endowment, including environmental and natural resources. Sustainable use of this endowment implies that, we should keep the principal intact and live off only the flow of services provided.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion In addition, sustainable use of this endowment also implies that, we should not chop down all the trees and use up all the oil, leaving future generations to fend for themselves. Fend:谋生

4. Applying the sustainability criterion The desirability of this version of the sustainability criterion depends crucially on how substitutable of the two forms of capital are. If physical capital can readily substitute for natural capital, then maintaining the value of the sum of the two is sufficient. If not, this can not assure sustainability.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion Unfortunately, the complete substitution is untenable for certain categories of environmental resources. Therefore, we should find better way for intergenerational compensation. An allocation is sustainable if it maintains the value of the stock of natural capital.

4. Applying the sustainability criterion Weak sustainability: the maintenance of the value of total capital. Strong sustainability (more restrictive): the maintenance of the value of natural capital. Environmental sustainability: the maintenance of certain physical flows of certain key individual resources.

5. Implications for environmental policy Sustainability and efficiency criteria, are neither synonymous nor incompatible. Not all efficient allocations are sustainable, and not all sustainable allocations are efficient. Yet some sustainable allocations are efficient, and some efficient allocations are sustainable.

5. Implications for environmental policy Its policy implications lie in that, among possible uses for resources that fulfill the sustainability criterion, we choose the one that maximizes either dynamic or static efficiency as appropriate. This implies that the sustainability criterion acts as an overriding constraint on social decisions.

5. Implications for environmental policy The combination of efficiency with sustainability are very helpful in guiding policy. Correcting the inefficiency can either restore sustainability or move the economy a long way in that direction. Further, correcting inefficiency can frequently produce win-win situations.

Summary Efficiency is concerned mainly with eliminating waste in the use of resources, while ethical considerations is concerned with assuring the fair treatment of all parties. Earlier generations should be free to pursue their own well-being as long as in so doing they do not diminish the welfare of future generations.

Summary Three definitions of sustainable allocations: Weak sustainability: the value of the capital stock should not decline. Strong sustainability: the value of the remaining stock of natural capital should not decrease. Environmental sustainability: the physical flows of individual resources should be maintained.

Summary According to the theorem of “Hartwick Rule”, if all of the scarcity rent from the use of scarce resources is invested in capital, the resulting allocation will satisfy the first definition of sustainability.

Summary In general, not all efficient allocations are sustainable and not all sustainable allocations efficient. Market allocations can be (1)efficient, but not sustainable; (2)sustainable, but not efficient; (3)inefficient and unsustainable; and (4)efficient and sustainable. The “win-win” situations provides an opportunity to increase simultaneously the welfare of all parties.

Self-Tests 1 and 2 (dictation in next class).

Thanks The end of Chapter 5