Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-0 CHAPTER 16 Capital Structure: Limits to the Use.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-0 CHAPTER 16 Capital Structure: Limits to the Use."— Presentation transcript:

1 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-0 CHAPTER 16 Capital Structure: Limits to the Use of Debt

2 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-1 Chapter Outline 16.1 Costs of Financial Distress 16.2 Description of Costs 16.3 Can Costs of Debt Be Reduced? 16.4 Integration of Tax Effects and Financial Distress Costs 16.5 Signaling 16.6 Shirking, Perquisites, and Bad Investments: A Note on Agency Cost of Equity 16.7 The Pecking-Order Theory 16.8 Growth and the Debt-Equity Ratio 16.9 Personal Taxes 16.10 How Firms Establish Capital Structure 16.11 Summary and Conclusions 16.1 Costs of Financial Distress 16.2 Description of Costs 16.3 Can Costs of Debt Be Reduced? 16.4 Integration of Tax Effects and Financial Distress Costs 16.5 Signaling 16.6 Shirking, Perquisites, and Bad Investments: A Note on Agency Cost of Equity 16.7 The Pecking-Order Theory 16.8 Growth and the Debt-Equity Ratio 16.9 Personal Taxes 16.10 How Firms Establish Capital Structure 16.11 Summary and Conclusions

3 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-2 16.1 Costs of Financial Distress Bankruptcy risk versus bankruptcy cost. The possibility of bankruptcy has a negative effect on the value of the firm. However, it is not the risk of bankruptcy itself that lowers value. Rather it is the costs associated with bankruptcy. It is the stockholders who bear these costs. Bankruptcy risk versus bankruptcy cost. The possibility of bankruptcy has a negative effect on the value of the firm. However, it is not the risk of bankruptcy itself that lowers value. Rather it is the costs associated with bankruptcy. It is the stockholders who bear these costs.

4 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-3 16.2 Description of Costs Direct Costs Legal and administrative costs (tend to be a small percentage of firm value). Indirect Costs Impaired ability to conduct business (e.g., lost sales) Agency Costs Selfish strategy 1: Incentive to take large risks Selfish strategy 2: Incentive toward underinvestment Selfish Strategy 3: Milking the property Direct Costs Legal and administrative costs (tend to be a small percentage of firm value). Indirect Costs Impaired ability to conduct business (e.g., lost sales) Agency Costs Selfish strategy 1: Incentive to take large risks Selfish strategy 2: Incentive toward underinvestment Selfish Strategy 3: Milking the property

5 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-4 Balance Sheet for a Company in Distress AssetsBVMVLiabilitiesBVMV Cash$200$200LT bonds$300 Fixed Asset$400$0Equity$300 Total$600$200Total$600$200 What happens if the firm is liquidated today? AssetsBVMVLiabilitiesBVMV Cash$200$200LT bonds$300 Fixed Asset$400$0Equity$300 Total$600$200Total$600$200 What happens if the firm is liquidated today? The bondholders get $200; the shareholders get nothing. $200 $0

6 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-5 Selfish Strategy 1: Take Large Risks The GambleProbabilityPayoff Win Big10%$1,000 Lose Big90%$0 Cost of investment is $200 (all the firm’s cash) Required return is 50% Expected CF from the Gamble = $1000 × 0.10 + $0 = $100 The GambleProbabilityPayoff Win Big10%$1,000 Lose Big90%$0 Cost of investment is $200 (all the firm’s cash) Required return is 50% Expected CF from the Gamble = $1000 × 0.10 + $0 = $100 NPV = –$200 + $100 (1.10) NPV = –$133

7 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-6 Selfish Stockholders Accept Negative NPV Project with Large Risks Expected CF from the Gamble To Bondholders = $300 × 0.10 + $0 = $30 To Stockholders = ($1000 – $300) × 0.10 + $0 = $70 PV of Bonds Without the Gamble = $200 PV of Stocks Without the Gamble = $0 PV of Bonds With the Gamble: PV of Stocks With the Gamble: Expected CF from the Gamble To Bondholders = $300 × 0.10 + $0 = $30 To Stockholders = ($1000 – $300) × 0.10 + $0 = $70 PV of Bonds Without the Gamble = $200 PV of Stocks Without the Gamble = $0 PV of Bonds With the Gamble: PV of Stocks With the Gamble: $20 = $30 (1.50) $47 = $70 (1.50)

8 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-7 Selfish Strategy 2: Underinvestment Consider a government-sponsored project that guarantees $350 in one period Cost of investment is $300 (the firm only has $200 now) so the stockholders will have to supply an additional $100 to finance the project Required return is 10% Consider a government-sponsored project that guarantees $350 in one period Cost of investment is $300 (the firm only has $200 now) so the stockholders will have to supply an additional $100 to finance the project Required return is 10% Should we accept or reject? NPV = –$300 + $350 (1.10) NPV = $18.18

9 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-8 Selfish Stockholders Forego Positive NPV Project Expected CF from the government sponsored project: To Bondholder = $300 To Stockholder = ($350 – $300) = $50 PV of Bonds Without the Project = $200 PV of Stocks Without the Project = $0 Expected CF from the government sponsored project: To Bondholder = $300 To Stockholder = ($350 – $300) = $50 PV of Bonds Without the Project = $200 PV of Stocks Without the Project = $0 $272.73 = $300 (1.10) PV of Bonds With the Project: – $100 $54.55 = $50 (1.10) PV of Stocks With the Project:

10 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-9 Selfish Strategy 3: Milking the Property Liquidating dividends Suppose our firm paid out a $200 dividend to the shareholders. This leaves the firm insolvent, with nothing for the bondholders, but plenty for the former shareholders. Such tactics often violate bond indentures. Increase perquisites to shareholders and/or management Liquidating dividends Suppose our firm paid out a $200 dividend to the shareholders. This leaves the firm insolvent, with nothing for the bondholders, but plenty for the former shareholders. Such tactics often violate bond indentures. Increase perquisites to shareholders and/or management

11 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-10 16.3 Can Costs of Debt Be Reduced? Protective Covenants Debt Consolidation: If we minimize the number of parties, contracting costs fall. Protective Covenants Debt Consolidation: If we minimize the number of parties, contracting costs fall.

12 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-11 Protective Covenants Agreements to protect bondholders Negative covenant: Thou shalt not: Pay dividends beyond specified amount. Sell more senior debt & amount of new debt is limited. Refund existing bond issue with new bonds paying lower interest rate. Buy another company’s bonds. Positive covenant: Thou shall: Use proceeds from sale of assets for other assets. Allow redemption in event of merger or spinoff. Maintain good condition of assets. Provide audited financial information. Agreements to protect bondholders Negative covenant: Thou shalt not: Pay dividends beyond specified amount. Sell more senior debt & amount of new debt is limited. Refund existing bond issue with new bonds paying lower interest rate. Buy another company’s bonds. Positive covenant: Thou shall: Use proceeds from sale of assets for other assets. Allow redemption in event of merger or spinoff. Maintain good condition of assets. Provide audited financial information.

13 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-12 16.4 Integration of Tax Effects and Financial Distress Costs There is a trade-off between the tax advantage of debt and the costs of financial distress. It is difficult to express this with a precise and rigorous formula. There is a trade-off between the tax advantage of debt and the costs of financial distress. It is difficult to express this with a precise and rigorous formula.

14 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-13 Integration of Tax Effects and Financial Distress Costs Debt (B) Value of firm (V) 0 Present value of tax shield on debt Present value of financial distress costs Value of firm under MM with corporate taxes and debt V L = V U + T C B V = Actual value of firm V U = Value of firm with no debt B*B* Maximum firm value Optimal amount of debt

15 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-14 The Pie Model Revisited Taxes and bankruptcy costs can be viewed as just another claim on the cash flows of the firm. Let G and L stand for payments to the government and bankruptcy lawyers, respectively. V T = S + B + G + L The essence of the M&M intuition is that V T depends on the cash flow of the firm; capital structure just slices the pie. Taxes and bankruptcy costs can be viewed as just another claim on the cash flows of the firm. Let G and L stand for payments to the government and bankruptcy lawyers, respectively. V T = S + B + G + L The essence of the M&M intuition is that V T depends on the cash flow of the firm; capital structure just slices the pie. S G B L

16 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-15 16.5 Signaling The firm’s capital structure is optimized where the marginal subsidy to debt equals the marginal cost. Investors view debt as a signal of firm value. Firms with low anticipated profits will take on a low level of debt. Firms with high anticipated profits will take on high levels of debt. A manager that takes on more debt than is optimal in order to fool investors will pay the cost in the long run. The firm’s capital structure is optimized where the marginal subsidy to debt equals the marginal cost. Investors view debt as a signal of firm value. Firms with low anticipated profits will take on a low level of debt. Firms with high anticipated profits will take on high levels of debt. A manager that takes on more debt than is optimal in order to fool investors will pay the cost in the long run.

17 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-16 16.6 Shirking, Perquisites, and Bad Investments: The Agency Cost of Equity An individual will work harder for a firm if he is one of the owners than if he is one of the “hired help”. Who bears the burden of these agency costs? While managers may have motive to partake in perquisites, they also need opportunity. Free cash flow provides this opportunity. The free cash flow hypothesis says that an increase in dividends should benefit the stockholders by reducing the ability of managers to pursue wasteful activities. The free cash flow hypothesis also argues that an increase in debt will reduce the ability of managers to pursue wasteful activities more effectively than dividend increases. An individual will work harder for a firm if he is one of the owners than if he is one of the “hired help”. Who bears the burden of these agency costs? While managers may have motive to partake in perquisites, they also need opportunity. Free cash flow provides this opportunity. The free cash flow hypothesis says that an increase in dividends should benefit the stockholders by reducing the ability of managers to pursue wasteful activities. The free cash flow hypothesis also argues that an increase in debt will reduce the ability of managers to pursue wasteful activities more effectively than dividend increases.

18 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-17 16.7 The Pecking-Order Theory Theory stating that firms prefer to issue debt rather than equity if internal finance is insufficient. Rule 1 Use internal financing first. Rule 2 Issue debt next, equity last. The pecking-order Theory is at odds with the trade-off theory: There is no target D/E ratio. Profitable firms use less debt. Companies like financial slack Theory stating that firms prefer to issue debt rather than equity if internal finance is insufficient. Rule 1 Use internal financing first. Rule 2 Issue debt next, equity last. The pecking-order Theory is at odds with the trade-off theory: There is no target D/E ratio. Profitable firms use less debt. Companies like financial slack

19 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-18 16.8 Growth and the Debt-Equity Ratio Growth implies significant equity financing, even in a world with low bankruptcy costs. Thus, high-growth firms will have lower debt ratios than low-growth firms. Growth is an essential feature of the real world; as a result, 100% debt financing is sub-optimal. Growth implies significant equity financing, even in a world with low bankruptcy costs. Thus, high-growth firms will have lower debt ratios than low-growth firms. Growth is an essential feature of the real world; as a result, 100% debt financing is sub-optimal.

20 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-19 16.9 Personal Taxes: The Miller Model The Miller Model shows that the value of a levered firm can be expressed in terms of an unlevered firm as: B T TT VV B SC UL           1 )1()1( 1 Where: T S = personal tax rate on equity income T B = personal tax rate on bond income T C = corporate tax rate

21 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-20 Personal Taxes: The Miller Model The derivation is straightforward: )1()1()( receive firm levered ain rsShareholde SCB TTBrEBIT  )1( receive sBondholder BB TBr  )1()1()1()( is rsstakeholde all toflowcash total theThus, BBSCB TBrTTBrEBIT           B SC BBSC T TT TBrTT 1 )1()1( 1)1()1()1( asrewritten becan This

22 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-21 Personal Taxes: The Miller Model (cont.)          B SC BBSC T TT TBrTTEBIT 1 )1()1( 1)1()1()1( The first term is the cash flow of an unlevered firm after all taxes. Its value = V U. A bond is worth B. It promises to pay r B B×(1- T B ) after taxes. Thus the value of the second term is: The total cash flow to all stakeholders in the levered firm is: The value of the sum of these two terms must be V L B T TT VV B SC UL           1 )1()1( 1

23 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-22 Personal Taxes: The Miller Model (cont.) Thus the Miller Model shows that the value of a levered firm can be expressed in terms of an unlevered firm as: In the case where TB = TS, we return to M&M with only corporate tax: Thus the Miller Model shows that the value of a levered firm can be expressed in terms of an unlevered firm as: In the case where TB = TS, we return to M&M with only corporate tax: B T TT VV B SC UL           1 )1()1( 1 BTVV CUL 

24 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-23 Effect of Financial Leverage on Firm Value with Both Corporate and Personal Taxes Debt (B) Value of firm (V) VUVU V L = V U +T C B when T S =T B V L < V U + T C B when T S < T B but (1-T B ) > (1-T C )×(1-T S ) V L =V U when (1-T B ) = (1-T C )×(1-T S ) V L < V U when (1-T B ) < (1-T C )×(1-T S ) B T TT VV B SC UL           1 )1()1( 1

25 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-24 Integration of Personal and Corporate Tax Effects and Financial Distress Costs and Agency Costs Debt (B) Value of firm (V) 0 Present value of tax shield on debt Present value of financial distress costs Value of firm under MM with corporate taxes and debt V L = V U + T C B V = Actual value of firm V U = Value of firm with no debt B* Maximum firm value Optimal amount of debt V L < V U + T C B when T S < T B but (1-T B ) > (1-T C )×(1-T S ) Agency Cost of EquityAgency Cost of Debt

26 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-25 16.10 How Firms Establish Capital Structure Most Corporations Have Low Debt-Asset Ratios. Changes in Financial Leverage Affect Firm Value. Stock price increases with increases in leverage and vice-versa; this is consistent with M&M with taxes. Another interpretation is that firms signal good news when they lever up. There are Differences in Capital Structure Across Industries. There is evidence that firms behave as if they had a target Debt to Equity ratio. Most Corporations Have Low Debt-Asset Ratios. Changes in Financial Leverage Affect Firm Value. Stock price increases with increases in leverage and vice-versa; this is consistent with M&M with taxes. Another interpretation is that firms signal good news when they lever up. There are Differences in Capital Structure Across Industries. There is evidence that firms behave as if they had a target Debt to Equity ratio.

27 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-26 Factors in Target D/E Ratio Taxes If corporate tax rates are higher than bondholder tax rates, there is an advantage to debt. Types of Assets The costs of financial distress depend on the types of assets the firm has. Uncertainty of Operating Income Even without debt, firms with uncertain operating income have high probability of experiencing financial distress. Pecking Order and Financial Slack Theory stating that firms prefer to issue debt rather than equity if internal finance is insufficient. Taxes If corporate tax rates are higher than bondholder tax rates, there is an advantage to debt. Types of Assets The costs of financial distress depend on the types of assets the firm has. Uncertainty of Operating Income Even without debt, firms with uncertain operating income have high probability of experiencing financial distress. Pecking Order and Financial Slack Theory stating that firms prefer to issue debt rather than equity if internal finance is insufficient.

28 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-27 16.11 Summary and Conclusions Costs of financial distress cause firms to restrain their issuance of debt. Direct costs Lawyers’ and accountants’ fees Indirect Costs Impaired ability to conduct business Incentives to take on risky projects Incentives to underinvest Incentive to milk the property Three techniques to reduce these costs are: Protective covenants Repurchase of debt prior to bankruptcy Consolidation of debt Costs of financial distress cause firms to restrain their issuance of debt. Direct costs Lawyers’ and accountants’ fees Indirect Costs Impaired ability to conduct business Incentives to take on risky projects Incentives to underinvest Incentive to milk the property Three techniques to reduce these costs are: Protective covenants Repurchase of debt prior to bankruptcy Consolidation of debt

29 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-28 16.11 Summary and Conclusions Because costs of financial distress can be reduced but not eliminated, firms will not finance entirely with debt. Debt (B) Value of firm (V) 0 Present value of tax shield on debt Present value of financial distress costs Value of firm under MM with corporate taxes and debt V L = V U + T C B V = Actual value of firm V U = Value of firm with no debt B* Maximum firm value Optimal amount of debt

30 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-29 16.11 Summary and Conclusions If distributions to equity holders are taxed at a lower effective personal tax rate than interest, the tax advantage to debt at the corporate level is partially offset. In fact, the corporate advantage to debt is eliminated if (1-T C ) × (1-T S ) = (1-T B ) Debt (B) Value of firm (V) 0 Present value of tax shield on debt Present value of financial distress costs Value of firm under MM with corporate taxes and debt V L = V U + T C B V = Actual value of firm V U = Value of firm with no debt B* Maximum firm value Optimal amount of debt V L < V U + T C B when T S < T B but (1-T B ) > (1-T C )×(1-T S ) Agency Cost of EquityAgency Cost of Debt

31 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-30 16.11 Summary and Conclusions Debt-to-equity ratios vary across industries. Factors in Target D/E Ratio Taxes If corporate tax rates are higher than bondholder tax rates, there is an advantage to debt. Types of Assets The costs of financial distress depend on the types of assets the firm has. Uncertainty of Operating Income Even without debt, firms with uncertain operating income have high probability of experiencing financial distress. Debt-to-equity ratios vary across industries. Factors in Target D/E Ratio Taxes If corporate tax rates are higher than bondholder tax rates, there is an advantage to debt. Types of Assets The costs of financial distress depend on the types of assets the firm has. Uncertainty of Operating Income Even without debt, firms with uncertain operating income have high probability of experiencing financial distress.


Download ppt "McGraw-Hill/Irwin Corporate Finance, 7/e © 2005 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. 16-0 CHAPTER 16 Capital Structure: Limits to the Use."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google