Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 6.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 6."— Presentation transcript:

1 Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 6

2 1  Coase: absent transaction costs, if property rights are complete and tradable, we’ll get efficiency through voluntary negotiation  So we can always get efficient outcomes “automatically”…  …provided there are no transaction costs  Leaves the question: what should we do when there are transaction costs? Property law – our story so far

3 2  Search costs  Bargaining costs  Asymmetric information/ adverse selection  Private information/not knowing each others’ threat points  Uncertainty about property rights/ threat points  Large numbers of buyers/sellers – holdout, freeriding  Hostility  Enforcement costs Different types/sources of transaction costs

4 3  Design the law to minimize transaction costs  “Lubricate private bargaining”  (Normative Coase)  Design the law to minimize dependence on bargaining  Or, minimize losses due to bargaining failures  Or, aim to allocate rights efficiently  (Normative Hobbes) Two approaches we could take

5  When transaction costs are low (and info costs are high), design the law to facilitate voluntary trade  When transaction costs are high (and info costs are low), design the law to allocate rights efficiently when possible When is each approach best?

6 What would an efficient property rights system look like?

7 6 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? Four questions we need to answer

8 77  Calabresi and Melamed (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral  Liability  Is the rancher liable for the damage done by his herd?  Property  Does the farmer’s right to his property include the right to be free from trespassing cows?  Entitlements  Is the farmer entitled to land free from trespassing animals?  Or is the rancher entitled to the natural actions of his cattle? Calabresi and Melamed treat property and liability under a common framework

9 88 Three possible ways to protect an entitlement  Property rule / injunctive relief  Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime  (Injunction: court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)  But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)

10 99 Three possible ways to protect an entitlement  Property rule / injunctive relief  Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime  (Injunction: court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)  But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)  Liability rule / damages  Violations of my entitlement are compensated  Damages – payment to victim to compensate for damage done  Inalienability  Violations punished as a crime  Unlike property rule, the entitlement cannot be sold

11 10  Injurer always prefers a damages rule  Injuree (person whose entitlement is violated) always prefers a property rule  Why? Under a property rule…  Punishment for violation is severe  If the two sides need to negotiate to trade the right, injurer’s threat point is lower  Even if both rules eventually lead to the same outcome, injurer will probably have to pay more  Under a damages rule, injurer has the option to just violate and reimburse – so a higher threat point Comparing injunctive relief to damages rule

12 11  Electric company (E) emits smoke, which dirties the laundry at laundromat next door (L)  E earns profits of 1,000  Without smoke, L would earn profits of 300  Smoke reduces L’s profits from 300 to 100  E could stop polluting at cost 500  L could prevent the damage at cost 100 Comparing injunctive relief to damages – example E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300  100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100

13 12  Polluter’s Rights (no remedy)  E earns 1,000  L installs filters, earns 300 – 100 = 200  Laundromat has right to damages  E earns 1,000, pays damages of 200  800  L earns 100, gets damages of 200  300  Laundromat has right to injunction  E installs scrubbers, earns 1,000 – 500 = 500  L earns 300 First, we consider the non-cooperative outcomes E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300  100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100

14 13 Noncooperative payoffs 8001,1001,200 Combined payoff (non-coop) 300 200 L payoff (non-coop) 5008001,000 E payoff (non-coop) InjunctionDamagesPolluter’s Rights E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300  100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100

15 14 What about with bargaining? 1,200 Combined 500350200L payoff (coop) 7008501,000E payoff (coop) 4001000Gains from Coop 8001,1001,200 Combined payoff (non-coop) 300 200 L payoff (non-coop) 5008001,000 E payoff (non-coop) InjunctionDamagesPolluter’s Rights E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300  100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100 800 + ½ (100) 300 + ½ (100) 500 + ½ (400) 300 + ½ (400)

16 15  Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer  No need for court to calculate amount of harm done  But damages are generally more efficient when bargaining is impossible Comparing injunctions to damages… 8001,100 Combined payoff (non-cooperative) 300 L payoff (non-cooperative) 500800 E payoff (non-cooperative) InjunctionDamages E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300  100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100

17 16  Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer  No need for court to calculate amount of harm done  But damages are generally more efficient when bargaining is impossible  In general, three possibilities: injurer prevents harm, injuree prevents harm, nobody prevents harm (someone pays for it)  Efficiency: cheapest of the three  Damages: injurer can prevent harm or pay for it; injurer chooses whichever is cheapest  Injunction: injurer can only prevent harm Comparing injunctions to damages…

18 17  Any rule leads to efficient outcomes when TC are low  Injunctions are cheaper to implement  Damages lead to more efficient outcomes when TC high  Leads Calabresi and Melamed to the following conclusion: When transaction costs are low, a property rule (injunctive relief) is more efficient When transaction costs are high, a liability rule (damages) is more efficient So now we know…

19 18  Transactions costs low  design law to facilitate trade  Property rule does this: clarifies right, allows trade  Transaction costs high  design law to minimize losses due to failures of private bargaining  Liability rule does this: gives injurer right to violate entitlement when efficient, even without prior consent Exactly agrees with principle from last week

20 19 “Private bargaining is unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed strangers because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior is likely to occur. Large numbers of land owners are typically affected by nuisances, such as air pollution or the stench from a feedlot. In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy. On the other hand, property disputes generally involve a small number of parties who live near each other and can monitor each others’ behavior easily after reaching a deal; so injunctive relief is usually used in these cases.” (Cooter and Ulen) High transaction costs  damages Low transaction costs  injunctive relief

21 20  Cheaper for the court to administer  With low transaction costs, we expect parties to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently  But… do they really?  Ward Farnsworth (1999), Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain After Judgment? A Glimpse Inside The Cathedral  20 nuisance cases: no bargaining after judgment “In almost every case the lawyers said that acrimony between the parties was an important obstacle to bargaining… Frequently the parties were not on speaking terms... …The second recurring obstacle involves the parties’ disinclination to think of the rights at stake… as readily commensurable with cash.” Low transaction costs  injunctive relief

22 21 “When transaction costs preclude bargaining, the court should protect a right by an injunctive remedy if it knows which party values the right relatively more and it does not know how much either party values it absolutely. Conversely, the court should protect a right by a damages remedy if it knows how much one of the parties values the right absolutely and it does not know which party values it relatively more.” (Cooter and Ulen) A different view of the high-transaction-costs case…

23 22  Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable  Allocative externalities (enriched uranium) Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability

24 23  Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable  Allocative externalities (enriched uranium)  “Indirect” externalities (human organs) Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability

25 24  Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable  Allocative externalities (enriched uranium)  “Indirect” externalities (human organs)  Paternalism Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability source: http://www.shanghaidaily.com/nsp/ National/2011/06/02/Boy%2Bregrets%2Bselling %2Bhis%2Bkidney%2Bto%2Bbuy%2BiPad/

26 25  “Repugnant markets”  markets that are illegal because people find them morally or aesthetically objectionable  CA ban on serving horse and dog meat  Paying birth mother to adopt a child  Bans on dwarf tossing  Ticket scalping, price gouging, gambling, drugs, prostitution  Roth: repugnance an important constraint on markets  What people find repugnant changes over time  Charging interest used to be repugnant!  Repugnance has to be considered in practical market design Another interpretation of inalienability: bans on “repugnant markets” 2012 Nobel Prize winner Al Roth Dwarf tossing

27 26  When transaction costs are low, use injunctive relief  Either rule will lead to efficient allocation (Coase)…  …but injunctions are cheaper to implement (court doesn’t have to assess level of harm)  When transaction costs are high, use damages  If bargaining is impossible, damages  more efficient outcomes  (Example: polluter can choose to pollute and pay when that’s more efficient than preventing the damage)  Agrees with principle from last week  TC low: design law to facilitate trade (normative Coase)  TC high: design law to not rely on bargaining (normative Hobbes) Recapping our conclusions on remedies…

28 27 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? Four questions we need to answer

29 28 Public versus Private Goods Private Goods  rivalrous – one’s consumption precludes another  excludable – technologically possible to prevent consumption  example: apple Public Goods  non-rivalrous  non-excludable  examples  defense against nuclear attack  infrastructure (roads, bridges)  parks, clean air, large fireworks displays

30 29  When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited Public versus Private Goods

31 30  When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited  When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied Public versus Private Goods

32 31  When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited  When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied  Efficiency suggests private goods should be privately owned, and public goods should be publicly provided/regulated Public versus Private Goods

33 32  When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited  When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied  Efficiency suggests private goods should be privately owned, and public goods should be publicly provided/regulated Public versus Private Goods

34 33  Transaction costs low  facilitate voluntary trade  Private goods – low transaction costs  Private ownership facilitates trade  Transaction costs high  allocate rights efficiently  Public goods – high transaction costs  Public provision/regulation required to get efficient amount This also accords with the principle from last week

35 34  Clean air  Large number of people affected  transaction costs high  injunctive relief unlikely to work well  Still two options  One: give property owners right to clean air, protected by damages  Two: public regulation  Argue for one or the other by comparing costs of each  Damages: costs are legal cost of lawsuits or pretrial negotiations  Regulation: administrative costs, error costs if level is not chosen correctly A different view: transaction costs

36 35 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? How do we design an efficient property law system?

37 36  For efficiency: principle of maximum liberty  Owners can do whatever they like with their property…  …provided that doesn’t interfere with others’ property or rights  That is, you can do anything you like so long as it doesn’t impose an externality (nuisance) on anyone else  Textbook: common law often approximates rule of maximum liberty  But does it really?  What about bans on repugnant markets?  And… What can an owner do with his/her property?

38 37  Ruling a few years ago by a Dane County judge  Plaintiffs argued they had a “fundamental right to own a cow, and to use their cows in a manner that does not cause harm to a third party”  Judge responded: “Plaintiffs do not have a fundamental right to own and use a dairy cow or a dairy herd Plaintiffs do not have a fundamental right to consume the milk from their own cow Plaintiffs do not have a fundamental right to board their cow at the farm of a farmer The private contract does not fall outside the scope of the States’ police power Plaintiffs do not have a fundamental right to produce and consume the foods of their choice DATCP has jurisdiction to regulate the Plaintiffs’ conduct” “Maximum liberty” vs. government’s right to regulate

39 38 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? How do we design an efficient property law system?

40 39  Hammonds v. Central Kentucky Natural Gas Co.  Central Kentucky leased land lying above natural gas deposits  Geological dome lay partly under Hammonds’ land  Central Kentucky drilled down and extracted the gas  Hammonds sued, claiming some of the gas was his  (Anybody see “There Will Be Blood”?) Fugitive property HammondsCentral KY

41 40  First Possession  nobody owns fugitive property until someone possesses it  first to “capture” a resource owns it  Central Kentucky would own all the gas  Tied Ownership  ownership of fugitive property tied to something else (here, surface)  so ownership already determined before resource is extracted  Hammonds would own some of the gas, since under his land  principle of accession – a new thing is owned by the owner of the proximate or prominent property Two principles for establishing ownership

42 41  First Possession  simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first  incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership  example: $100 of gas, two companies drilling fast or slow  drilling slowly costs $5, drilling fast costs $25  drill same speed  each gets half the gas, one drills fast  75/25 First Possession versus Tied Ownership 45, 4520, 50 50, 2025, 25 SlowFast Slow Fast Firm 2 Firm 1

43 42  First Possession  simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first  incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership  Tied Ownership  encourages efficient use of the resource  but, difficulty of establishing and verifying ownership rights First Possession versus Tied Ownership 45, 4545, 25 25, 4525, 25 SlowFast Slow Fast Firm 2 Firm 1

44 43 Rules that link ownership to possession have the advantage of being easy to administer, and the disadvantage of providing incentives for uneconomic investment in possessory acts. Rules that allow ownership without possession have the advantage of avoiding preemptive investment and the disadvantage of being costly to administer. This brings us to the following tradeoff:

45 44  “Fast fish/loose fish” and “the guy who kills a fox, owns it” are examples of a first possession rule  You can’t own a resource until you physically possess it  “Iron holds the whale” and “the guy chasing a fox owns it” are examples of a tied ownership rule  You can establish ownership of something before you actually possess it  (A harpoon, or chasing a fox, gives you a right to it)  More complicated/costly to enforce  “if the first seeing, starting, or pursuing such animals… should afford the basis of actions against others for intercepting and killing them, it would prove a fertile source of quarrels and litigation”  But avoids incentive to poach someone else’s resource We’ve already seen two examples of this

46 45  Meant to encourage settlement of the Western U.S.  Citizens could acquire 160 acres of land for free, provided  head of a family or 21 years old  “for the purpose of actual cultivation, and not… for the use or benefit of someone else”  had to live on the claim for 6 months and make “suitable” improvements  Basically a first possession rule for land – by living on the land, you gained ownership of it  Friedman: caused people to spend inefficiently much to gain ownership of the land Another nice historical example: the Homestead Act of 1862

47 46 “The year is 1862; the piece of land we are considering is… too far from railroads, feed stores, and other people to be cultivated at a profit. …The efficient rule would be to start farming the land the first year that doing so becomes profitable, say 1890. But if you set out to homestead the land in 1890, you will get an unpleasant surprise: someone else is already there. …If you want to get the land you will have to come early. By farming it at a loss for a few years you can acquire the right to farm it thereafter at a profit. Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862

48 47 How early will you have to come? Assume the value of the land in 1890 is going to be $20,000, representing the present value of the profit that can be made by farming it from then on. Further assume that the loss from farming it earlier than that is $1,000 a year. If you try to homestead it in 1880, you again find the land already taken. Someone who homesteads in 1880 pays $10,000 in losses for $20,000 in real estate – not as good as getting it for free, but still an attractive deal. …The land will be claimed about 1870, just early enough so that the losses in the early years balance the later gains. It follows that the effect of the Homestead Act was to wipe out, in costs of premature farming, a large part of the land value of the United States.” Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862

49 48  What things can be privately owned?  Private goods are privately owned, public goods are publicly provided  What can owners do with their property?  Maximum liberty  How are property rights established?  (Tradeoff between first possession and tied ownership; more examples to come)  What remedies are given?  Injunctions when transaction costs are low; damages when transaction costs are high So, what does an efficient property law system look like?


Download ppt "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 6."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google