Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

MBMC The Economics of Information The Economics of Information.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "MBMC The Economics of Information The Economics of Information."— Presentation transcript:

1 MBMC The Economics of Information The Economics of Information

2 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 2 Introduction The invisible hand theory assumes that buyers are fully informed. People who don’t know what they are buying. Given that consumers are not fully informed, they must employ strategies for gathering information. Consumer report Amazon.com review Talk to family and friends

3 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 3 How the Middleman Adds Value Example How should a consumer decide which pair of skis to buy?  Skis R Us has a.......  knowledgeable sales staff  and a large inventory  They Recommend Salomon X-Scream 9 skis for $600  The skis can be purchased on the Internet for $400 Question facing the buyer Is spending $600 on the right skis better than $400 on the wrong ones?

4 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 4 How the Middleman Adds Value How does better information affect economic surplus? Ellis wants to sell a Babe Ruth baseball card. His reservation price is $300. An ad in the local newspaper cost $5. The maximum price in the local market is $400. eBay cost is 5% of the Internet auction price. The maximum prices in the eBay market is $900 and $800.

5 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 5 How the Middleman Adds Value Example How does better information affect economic surplus?  Notice that winning bidder pay the second price on eBay.  Economic surplus: = Price paid - transaction costs - reservation price  Local market = $400 - $5 - $300 = $95  eBay = $800 - $40 - $300 = $460 + $100 = $560

6 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 6 How the Middleman Adds Value How does better information affect economic surplus? Economic surplus is increased when a product goes to the person who values it the most. Sales agents and other middlemen help add economic value.

7 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 7 The Optimal Amount of Information $/unit Units of information Marginal cost of information Marginal benefit of information I * The optimal amount of information (ignorance) occurs where MC = MB

8 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 8 The Free Rider Problem An incentive problem in which too little of a good or service is produced because nonpayers cannot be excluded from using it Economic Naturalist Why is finding a knowledgeable salesclerk often difficult? Why did Rivergate Books, the last bookstore in Lambertville, NJ, recently go out of business? Get advice/preview from salesclerk/bookstore Buy the stuff on line for a cheaper price. The Optimal Amount of Information

9 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 9 Two Guidelines for Rational Search Additional search time is more likely to be worthwhile for expensive items than cheap ones Prices paid may be higher when the cost of a search is higher When to search Expensive items Lower cost in searching The Optimal Amount of Information

10 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 10 Example Should a person living in Paris, TX, spend more or less time searching for an apartment than someone living in Paris, France? Example Tom and Tim are shopping for a used upright piano. Tom has a car & Tim does not. Which one should expect to examine fewer pianos before making a purchase? The Optimal Amount of Information

11 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 11 The Gamble Inherent in Search When engaging in further search there are additional costs and uncertain benefits and, therefore, there is a degree of risk or gamble from the search. The Optimal Amount of Information

12 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 12 Determining whether or not to take the gamble: Compute the expected value of the gamble  The sum of the possible outcomes multiplied by their respective probabilities Fair Gamble  Coin flip: Heads win $1, Tails lose $1  Probabilities: 50% for head and 50% for tail.  Expected value = (.5)($1) + (.5)(-$1) = 0 The Optimal Amount of Information

13 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 13 Determining whether or not to take the gamble: Better-than-fair-gamble  Coin flip: Heads win $2, Tails lose $1  Expected value = (.5)($2) + (.5)(-$1) =.5 Risk-neutral person  Will accept any gamble that is fair or better Risk-averse person  Will refuse any fair gamble The Optimal Amount of Information

14 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 14 Example Should you search further for an apartment?  Searching for an apartment in a neighborhood where identical apartments rent fo $400 & $360  Of the vacant apartments, 80% rent for $400 and 20% rent for $360  You must visit the apartment to get to rental rate  You are risk neutral. The Optimal Amount of Information

15 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 15 Example Should you search further for an apartment?  The first visit is a $400 apartment.  The opportunity cost of an additional visit is $6. The expected value of another visit:  Find one $360 apartment: save $40 and pay $6  Find another $400 apartment: pay $6  (.2)($34) + (.80)(-$6) = $2  What is your decision given that you are risk neutral? What if you are risk averse? The Optimal Amount of Information

16 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 16 The Commitment Problems When Search is Costly Since searching is costly, you may just take whatever is available for good. But… What happens when, by chance, a more attractive option comes along after the search has ceased? When information is costly and the search must be limited, a relationship may stay for a while then may dissolve. The Optimal Amount of Information

17 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 17 The Commitment Problems When Search is Costly Commitment agreements  Lease agreements  binding the landlords/tenants for a specified period  Employment contracts  Honor obligations under normal situations  Marriage contracts  Penalizes whose who abandon their spouses, big wedding etc. The Optimal Amount of Information

18 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 18 The Optimal Amount of Information Marriage contract and Prenup Searching for a perfect match is costly In an imperfect match, one side may have disadvantage when the match breaks up. To induce the disadvantaged party to enter the marriage contract, a break up cost upon the party with advantage is imposed. If the imposed break up cost is too high for the advantaged party, a prenup is used to lower that cost to induce the advantaged party enter into marriage.

19 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 19 Asymmetric Information Situations in which buyers and sellers are not equally well informed about the characteristics of goods and services for sale in the marketplace.

20 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 20 Asymmetric Information Example Will Jane sell her car to Tom? Assume Jane wants to sell a 2000 Miata  70,000 highway miles  Complete maintenance  Excellent condition  Average price is $8,000  Jane’s reservation price is $10,000

21 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 21 Asymmetric Information Tom Reservation price  $13,000 if in excellent condition  $9,000 if not in excellent condition Will not pay $10,000 because he cannot tell if Jane’s car is an excellent buy  cannot tell the quality of the car even by a mechanic, so treat Jane’s as average.  Tom buys an average car at $8,000

22 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 22 Asymmetric Information Example There is a loss in economic surplus  Assuming Tom had paid Jane $11,000 Tom  Pays $8,000 and has a gain of $1,000 ($9,000 - $8,000) if he buys the average car

23 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 23 Asymmetric Information Tom’s Gain if he buys at $11,000  $13,000 - $11,000 = $2,000 (bought from Jane)  Tom’s Loss=$2,000 - $1,000 = $1,000 (compared to paying $8,000) Jane’s loss is $1,000 (=11,000-10,000) Total loss is $2,000 ($1,000 for Jane & $1,000 for Tom) Asymmetric information costs economic surplus

24 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 24 Asymmetric Information The Lemons Model Asymmetric information tends to reduce the average quality of goods offered for sale. People who have below average (lemons) cars, are more likely to want to sell them. Buyers know that below average cars are likely to be on the market and lower their reservation prices.

25 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 25 Asymmetric Information The Lemons Model Because used car prices are low, people with good cars keep them longer. The average quality of used cars falls even further. As the average quality of used cars falls, buyers’ reservation price will fall as well. And so on and so forth.

26 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 26 Asymmetric Information Example Should you buy your aunt’s car?  4-year old Accord  The asking price of $10,000 is the blue book value.  You believe the car is in good condition.  It is a good deal because the blue book value is the equilibrium price for below average cars.

27 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 27 Asymmetric Information Example How much will a naïve buyer pay for a used car?

28 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 28 Asymmetric Information Assume There are only good cars and lemons. 10% of all new cars are lemons. Good used cars are worth $10,000 and lemons are worth $6,000. The used car market is 90% good cars and 10% lemons.

29 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 29 Asymmetric Information Example Calculating the expected value:  (.90)($10,000) + (.10)($6,000) = $9,600  Reservation price for a risk-neutral buyer A naïve buyer will pay $9,600 for a used car.

30 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 30 Asymmetric Information Example Who will sell a used car for what the naïve buyer is willing to pay?  Would not sell a good car that is worth $10,000  Would sell a lemon that is worth $6,000  Only lemons will be on the market  Price will fall to $6,000

31 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 31 Asymmetric Information If you have a good used car for sale, how can you get a higher price?

32 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 32 Asymmetric Information The Credibility Problem In Trading People tend to interpret ambiguous information in ways that promote their own interests. Sellers: overstate the quality of their products for higher price. Buyers: understate the amount they’re willing to pay to bargain a low price.

33 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 33 Asymmetric Information The Costly-to-Fake Principle To communicate information credibly, a signal must be costly or difficult to fake. Called “signaling” in game theory Who wants to fake? Who can signal?

34 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 34 Asymmetric Information Economic Naturalist: common signals Firms insert the phrase “As advertised on TV” when they advertise their products in magazines and newspapers for million dollars TV ads.  Signal the ability to earn money back from the profit on the product. Many companies care a lot about elite educational credentials.  High grade: signal for high capability

35 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 35 Asymmetric Information Economic Naturalist Many clients seem to prefer lawyers who wear expensive suits. Expensive personal items signal the ability to earn money from winning cases.

36 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 36 Asymmetric Information Statistical Discrimination The practice of making judgments about the quality of people, goods, or services based on the characteristics of the groups to which they belong. Use information on groups (statistics) instead of on individual customer to make pricing decisions.

37 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 37 Asymmetric Information Economic Naturalist Why do males under 25 years of age pay more than other drivers for auto insurance? The group of males under 25 years old tends to have more accidents than other group. If you belong to that group, you pay higher premium. High grades/expensive suits signals which group an individual belongs to.

38 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 38 Asymmetric Information Adverse Selection The pattern in which insurance tends to be purchased disproportionately by those who are most costly for companies to insure Raises premiums Reduces the number of low-risk policy holders Increases the risk level of the insured

39 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 39 Asymmetric Information Adverse Selection Happens when the insurance contract is sold/signed. High risk individuals would like to pay higher prices. Same price looks more attractive to high risk individuals than people with average/low risk Government enforced insurance policy may lower the premium in the market.

40 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 40 Asymmetric Information Moral Hazard The tendency of people to expend less effort protecting those goods that are insured against theft or damage Happens after the insurance contract is signed. Because of insurance, people tend to choose riskier behavior for lower potential loss.

41 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 41 Asymmetric Information Moral Hazard Deductibles are used to reduce moral hazard and adverse selection. Benefits from deductibles in the insurance policy  Lower rates  Increase the incentive to drive safely  Reduce the number of claims, which lowers cost and premiums

42 MBMC Copyright c 2006 by McGraw-Hill Chapter 13: The Economics of Information Slide 42 Disappearing Political Discourse Economic Naturalist Why do opponents of the death penalty often remain silent? (bad signal) Why do proponents of legalized drugs remain silent? (bad signal) Why did it take Richard Nixon – a diehard anti-communist – to reestablish normal diplomatic relations to China – a communist country at then? (no bad signal)

43 MBMC End of Chapter End of Chapter


Download ppt "MBMC The Economics of Information The Economics of Information."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google