Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

The Pricing Of Risk Understanding the Relation between Risk and Return.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "The Pricing Of Risk Understanding the Relation between Risk and Return."— Presentation transcript:

1 The Pricing Of Risk Understanding the Relation between Risk and Return

2 Discounting Risky Cash Flows  How should the discount rate change in the NPV calculation if the cash flows are not riskless?  The question is more easily answered from the “other side.” How must the expected return on an asset change so you will be happy to own it if it is a risky rather than a riskless asset?  Risk averse investors say that to hold a risky asset they require a higher expected return than they require for holding a riskless asset. E(r risky ) = r f + .  Note that we now have to start to talk about expected returns since risk has been explicitly introduced.  Note also that this captures the two basic “services” investors perform for the economy.

3 The Answer!! Expected Return Risk But, how should risk be measured? at what rate does the line slope up? is the relation linear? Lets look at some simple but important historical evidence. “E(r) = r f + θ”

4 Returns for Different Types of Securities

5 Risk, More Formally  Many people think intuitively about risk as the possibility of an outcome that is worse than was expected.  Must be incomplete.  Also: for those who hold more than one asset, is it the risk of each asset they care about, or the risk of their whole portfolio?  A useful construct for thinking rigorously about risk:  The “probability distribution.”  A list of all possible outcomes and their probabilities.  Very importantly we think about the moments of the distribution.

6 Example: Two Probability Distributions on Tomorrow's Share Price. n The expected price is the same. n Which implies more risk?

7 The Empirical Distribution of Annual Returns for U.S. Large Stocks (S&P 500), Small Stocks, Corporate Bonds, and Treasury Bills, 1926–2011.

8 Expected Return  Expected (Mean) Return  Calculated as a “weighted average of the possible returns,” (where the weights correspond to the associated probabilities).

9 Variance and Standard Deviation  Variance  The expected squared deviation from the mean  Standard Deviation  The square root of the variance: commonly called volatility in finance jargon  Both are measures of the risk or volatility associated with a probability distribution

10 Average Return and Variance  Where R t is the realized return of a security in year t, for the years 1 through T  The estimate of the volatility/standard deviation is the square root of the estimate of variance.

11 History for US Portfolios (1926 – 2011) Portfolio Average Annual Return Excess Return: Average Return in Excess of T-Bills Return Volatility (Standard Deviation) Small Stocks18.7%15.1%39.2% S&P 50011.7%8.1%20.3% Corporate Bonds6.6%3.0%7.0% Treasury Bonds3.6%0.0%3.1%

12 Using Past Returns to Predict the Future: Let’s Remind Ourselves of Estimation Error  Standard Error of the Estimate of Expected Return  A statistical measure of the degree of estimation error  95% Confidence Interval  For the S&P 500 (1926–2011)  Or a range from 7.3% to 16.1%. So not a great deal of accuracy, and this is a large portfolio that has been around for a long time.

13 The Historical Tradeoff Between Risk and Return in Large Portfolios, 1926–2011  Note: a positive linear relationship between volatility and average returns for large portfolios.

14 Historical Volatility and Return for 500 Individual Stocks, by Size, Updated Quarterly, 1926–2011

15 The Returns of Individual Stocks  Is there a positive linear relationship between volatility and average returns for individual stocks?  As shown on the last slide, there is no precise relationship between volatility and average return for individual stocks.  For a given level of average return, larger stocks tend to have lower volatility than smaller stocks.  All stocks tend to have higher risk for a given average return relative to large portfolios.  There must be something magical going on with portfolios.  Volatility doesn’t seem to be an adequate measure of risk to explain the expected return of individual stocks.  Can we deal with this and resurrect our simple idea?

16 Going Forward  As we discussed, the “market” pays investors for two services they provide: (1) surrendering their capital and forgoing current consumption and (2) sharing in the aggregate risk of the economy.  The first gets you the time value of money.  The second gets you a risk premium.  From this we wrote E(r) = r f + θ  The size of the risk premium should depend on the amount of aggregate risk you take on.  So we refine this relation to E(r) = r f + Units × Price  In other words the premium cannot be the same for all assets. If you take more risk (more units of risk) you require more of a premium.

17 Going Forward  We need a reference for measuring risk and choose the risk the market must distribute across investors, the aggregate total risk or the risk of the “market portfolio” as that reference.  The market portfolio is defined to have one unit of risk (Var(r m ) = 1 unit of risk). Other assets will be evaluated relative to this definition of one unit of risk.  From E(r) = r f + Units × Price we can see that “Price” = {E(r m ) – r f }. (Note: 1 unit of risk for the market.)  Therefore, we also defined the price per unit risk (the market risk premium) once we select this reference for measuring risk.

18 Going Forward  The hard part is to show that any asset’s contribution to the aggregate risk of the economy or Var(r m ) is determined not by Var(r i ) but rather by Cov(r i, r m ).  Standardize Cov(r i, r m ) so that we measure the risk of each asset relative to our definition of one unit and we get beta: “Units” = β i = Cov(r i, r m )/Var(r m )  The number of “units of risk” for asset i is β i.  So E(r i )=r f + β i (E(r m ) – r f ) = r f + Units × Price.

19 Going Forward  When we are concerned with only one asset (or only a large portfolio) risk and return can be measured/related using expected return and variance/standard deviation of return.  If there is more that one asset (so various portfolios can be formed) risk becomes more complex.  We will show there are two types of risk for individual assets:  Diversifiable/nonsystematic/idiosyncratic risk  Nondiversifiable/systematic/market risk  Diversifiable risk can be eliminated without cost by combining assets into portfolios. (Big Wow.)  Individual stocks are exposed to this type of risk.  Large portfolios (created appropriately) are not.

20 Diversification  One of the most important lessons in all of finance concerns the power of diversification.  Part of the total risk of any asset can be “diversified away” without any loss in expected return (i.e. without cost).  No compensation needs to be provided to investors for exposing their portfolios to this type of risk.  Why should the economy pay you to hold risk that you can get rid of for free (which is not part of the aggregate risk that all agents must share).  The risk that remains is called systematic risk.  This in turn implies that the risk/return relation is actually a systematic risk/expected return relation.  An asset/portfolio with a lot of systematic risk will have a high expected return.  An asset/portfolio with very little systematic risk will have a low expected return.

21 Diversification Example  Suppose a large green ogre has approached you and demanded that you enter into a bet with him.  The terms are that you must wager $10,000 and it must be decided by the flip of a coin, where heads he wins and tails you win.  What is your expected payoff and what is your risk?

22 Example…  The expected payoff from such a bet is of course $0 if the coin is fair.  The standard deviation of this “position” is $10,000, reflecting the wide swings in value across the two outcomes (winning and losing).  Can you suggest another approach that stays within the rules?

23 Example…  If instead of wagering the whole $10,000 on one coin flip think about wagering $1 on each of 10,000 coin flips.  The expected payoff on this version is still $0 so you haven’t changed the expectation.  The standard deviation of the payoff in this version, however, is $100.  Why the change?  If we bet a penny on each of 1,000,000 coin flips, the risk, measured by the standard deviation of the payoff, is $10. The expected payoff is of course still $0.

24 Example…  The example works so well at reducing risk because the coin flips are uncorrelated.  If the coins were somehow perfectly correlated we would be right back in the first situation.  Suppose all flips after the first always landed the same way as the first did, what good is bothering with 10,000 flips?  With one dollar bets on 10,000 flips, for “flip correlations” between zero (no correlation) and one (perfect correlation) the measure of risk lies between $100 and $10,000.  This is one way to see that the way an “asset” contributes to the risk of a large “portfolio” is determined by its correlation or covariance with the other assets in the portfolio.

25 Covariances and Correlations: The Keys to Understanding Diversification  When thinking in terms of probability distributions, the covariance between the returns of two assets (A & B) equals Cov(R A,R B ) =  AB =  When estimating covariances from historical data, the estimate is given by:  Note: An asset’s variance is its covariance with itself.

26 Correlation Coefficients Covariances are difficult to interpret. Only the sign is really informative. Is a covariance of 20 big or small? The correlation coefficient, , is a normalized version of the covariance given by: Correlation = CORR(R A,R B ) = The correlation will always lie between 1 and -1.  A correlation of 1.0 implies...  A correlation of -1.0 implies...  A correlation of 0.0 implies...  We normalize differently.

27 Risk and Return in Portfolios: Example Two Assets, A and B A portfolio, P, comprised of 50% of your total investment invested in asset A and 50% in B. There are five equally probable future outcomes, see below. In this case: VAR(R A ) = 191.6, STD(R A ) = 13.84, and E(R A ) = 16%. VAR(R B ) = 106.0, STD(R B ) = 10.29, and E(R B ) = 12%. COV(R A,R B ) = 21, CORR(R A,R B ) = 21/(13.84*10.29) =.1475. E(R p )=14%=½ E(R A ) + ½ E(R B ), VAR(R P )=84.9, STD(R p )=9.21, Var(R p ) or STD(R P ) is less than that of either component!

28 Risk/return pairs with different weights Asset A Asset B ½ and ½ portfolio

29 Asset A Asset B Risk return pairs with different correlations

30 How Diversification Works: The Variance of a Two-Asset Portfolio For a portfolio of two assets, A and B, the portfolio variance is: For the two-asset example considered above: Portfolio Variance =.5 2 (191.6) +.5 2 (106.0) + 2(.5)(.5)21 = 84.9 (check for yourself) or,

31 For General Portfolios The expected return on a portfolio is the weighted average of the expected returns on each asset. If w i is the proportion of the investment invested in asset i, then Note that this is a simple linear relation.

32 For General Portfolios  The variance of the portfolio’s return is given by:  Not simple and not linear but very powerful.

33 In A Picture (N = 2) Var(R A )= Cov(R A, R A ) Cov(R A, R B ) Cov(R B, R A )Var(R B )= Cov(R B, R B ) Portfolio variance is a weighted sum of these terms.

34 In A Picture (N = 3) Portfolio variance is a weighted sum of these terms. Var(R A )Cov(R A,R B )Cov(R A,R C ) Cov(R B,R A )Var(R B )Cov(R B,R C ) Cov(R C,R A )Cov(R C,R B )Var(R C )

35 In A Picture (N = 10) Portfolio variance is a simple weighted sum of the terms in the squares. The blue are covariances and the white the variance terms.

36 In A Picture (N = 20) Which squares are becoming more important?

37 Volatility of an Equally Weighted Portfolio Versus the Number of Stocks

38 Implications of Diversification  Diversification reduces risk. If asset returns were uncorrelated on average, diversification could eliminate all risk. They are positively correlated on average.  Diversification will reduce risk but will not remove all of the risk.  Individual stocks are exposed to two kinds of risk  Diversifiable/nonsystematic/idiosyncratic risk.  Disappears in well diversified portfolios.  It disappears without cost, i.e. you need not sacrifice expected return to reduce/eliminate this type of risk.  The law of one price implies that there will be no premium for diversifiable risk.  Nondiversifiable/systematic/market risk.  Does not disappear in well diversified portfolios.  A large (well diversified) portfolio has only systematic risk.  There is a tradeoff between expected return and systematic risk.  The level of systematic risk in a portfolio is an important choice for an individual.

39 Historical Volatility and Return for 500 Individual Stocks, by Size, Updated Quarterly, 1926–2011


Download ppt "The Pricing Of Risk Understanding the Relation between Risk and Return."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google