Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

WIOD Consortium Meeting Sevilla, 25 – 26, May, 2011 Embodied and induced technical change and the price of carbon Kurt Kratena Michael Wueger.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "WIOD Consortium Meeting Sevilla, 25 – 26, May, 2011 Embodied and induced technical change and the price of carbon Kurt Kratena Michael Wueger."— Presentation transcript:

1 WIOD Consortium Meeting Sevilla, 25 – 26, May, 2011 Embodied and induced technical change and the price of carbon Kurt Kratena Michael Wueger

2 Literature: embodied and induced technical change Models increasingly integrate features of endogenous technical change: WITCH (Bosetti et al., 2006), CGE (Otto, Loeschel and Reilly, 2008) Endogenous innovation: (i) energy saving R&D, (ii) learning by doing for carbon-free technologies Popp (2002): energy saving innovation, Sue Wing (2006): technical change induced by climate policy climate policy creates the cost savings of its own measures Critical issues and questions Induced innovation or diffusion of (existing) technologies? Difference between substitution of factors (for example K and E) and technical change (Binswanger and Ruttan, 1978 and Sue Wing, 2006) Are K and E substitutes or complements ? Does embodied and induced technical change only work with K and E substitutability ? Technical change in E3 modelling

3 K,L,E,M (Translog) model of production with embodied and induced technical change Factor bias & TFP (Binswanger and Ruttan, 1978; Jorgenson and Fraumeni, 1981, Jorgenson, 1984) Embodied technical change (Berndt, Kolstad and Lee,1993; Sue Wing and Eckaus, 2007) From embodied to induced technical change: K as short-run fixed factor plus investment function (first results with EUKLEMS data in Kratena, 2007) Model of dynamic factor demand (Pindyck and Rotemberg, 1983): forward looking, but no explicit adjustment costs Application to WIOD data (YL files, environmental satellites accounts) combining with EUKLEMS (release March 2008, including energy inputs) and IEA Energy Prices and Taxes Technical change in E3 modelling

4 Dynamic factor demand model: general Dynamic cost functions with short-run variable costs VC (prices p v of variable factors L, E, M), investment costs (K = capital stock, p I = investment price), gross output Q, labour L (second nest: different skills), energy E, TFP, returns to scale and technical change bias Shephards Lemma and Euler condition: Euler condition without explicit adjustment costs just states that the shadow price of K equals the user costs of K. Technical change in production

5 Translog model with non-constant returns to scale Dynamic factor demand model

6 Translog model with constant returns to scale Dynamic factor demand model

7 Embodied and induced technical change Derivation of the shadow price of capital derivation of the optimal stock K*: Impact of energy price on K* (long-run) Returns to scale ( measures the cost effect of Q): Increasing returns to scale: < 1.

8 Dynamic factor demand model Capital stock adjustment and energy Forward looking adjustment of K to K*: Investment function (non-constant returns to scale) Input-output spill-overs of technical change through production of capital goods: p = VC/Q + p K K/Q With B ij as the investment matrix (industries * commodities) for imports (M B ) and domestic deliveries

9 Dynamic factor demand model Embodied and induced technical change:energy Elasticity of E to K: Long-run elasticity of E:

10 Estimation methodology Balanced panel for: AUT, DNK, FIN, NLD, GB, from 1980-2006 GMM estimation with lagged exogenous (factor prices, output, capital stock, depreciation rate, rate of return) as instruments the expectation of K* t+1 is determined by all information in t capital stock adjustment can be due to expectation errors or shocks Estimating the full system with VC-function, factor demand for L and E and investment function ( log K t+1 ) for non-constant and constant returns to scale Deriving returns to scale, own price elasticities, capital/energy and capital/labour elasticities (calculating shadow price of K), as well as long-run elasticities of E Restrictions: homogeneity, symmetry and concavity of the cost function (individual, for problem cases) Dynamic factor demand model

11 Data from WIOD, EUKLEMS and IEA (energy prices) Energy inputs in physical units (TJ) by about 20 energy carriers from WIOD environmental accounts IEA Energy Prices and Taxes for most of the energy carriers/countries (estimating missing data to fill gaps) Constructing an aggregate energy input in current prices (p E *E), volumes (E), and price of energy p E. The volume measure is based on aggregation of energy contents effective input (energy services like labour servives and capital srvices in EUKLEMS) Capital stock, GFCF deflators, depreciation rate (capital input files from EUKLEMS), benchmark interest rate (EUROSTAT), deflated with VA deflator (YL files, WIOD) user costs p I (r + ) Labour services (L), compensation of employees from (p L *L) price of labour (p L ), data from YL files, WIOD Dynamic factor demand model

12 Estimation results: non-constant returns to scale 25 parameters out of 91 are insignificant Embodied energy saving technical change: wood and cork, pulp and paper/printing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metals and fabricated metal, electrical and optical equipment Dynamic factor demand model

13 Estimation results: constant returns to scale 8 parameters out of 91 are insignificant Embodied energy saving technical change: Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel, chemicals, basic metals and fabricated metal Dynamic factor demand model

14 Estimation results: non-constant returns to scale Factor bias: (i) labour saving in all industries, (ii) energy saving in: chemicals, other non-metallic minerals, basic metals and fabricated metal, machinery, electrical and optical equipment, and transport equipment Dynamic factor demand model

15 Estimation results: constant returns to scale Factor bias: (i) labour saving in all industries except pulp and paper, (ii) energy saving in a majority of industries Dynamic factor demand model

16 Estimation results: elasticities, non-constant returns to scale price elasticity of E : - 0.2, of L : - 0.5. Negative energy/capital elasticities (K and E are substitutes): pulp and paper/printing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metals and fabricated metal, machinery, electrical and optical equipment Energy saving embodied technical change Dynamic factor demand model

17 Estimation results: elasticities, constant returns to scale Negative energy/capital elasticities (K and E are substitutes): coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel, chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metals and fabricated metal Three industries show energy saving embodied technical change in both specifications: chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metal/fabricated metal Dynamic factor demand model

18 Estimation results: embodied and induced technical change Two industries with embodied energy saving technical change in the case of non-constant returns to scale, but not with constant returns: pulp and paper/printing, electrical and optical equipment Are non-constant returns to scale an additional source of technical change? (some industres with decreasing returns !) Main disadvantage of this approach: (Price) induced technical change is only possible, when K and E are substitutes and investment reacts positive to energy price shocks further reduction of number of industries with embodied plus induced energy saving technical change Dynamic factor demand model

19 Estimation results: long-run price elasticities of E Starting point: industries with embodied energy saving technical change Is there also induced energy saving technical change ? = Is the long-run price elasticity of E higher than the short-run ? Dynamic factor demand model

20 Embodied & induced technical change Non-constant returns to scale Starting point: industries with embodied energy saving technical change: pulp and paper/printing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metals and fabricated metal, machinery, electrical and optical equipment Long-run elasticity of E ( EE ) > short-run elasticity ( EE ) = induced technical change: pulp and paper/printing, chemicals, rubber and plastics, machinery Dynamic factor demand model

21 Embodied & induced technical change Constant returns to scale Starting point: industries with embodied energy saving technical change: coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel, chemicals, rubber and plastics, basic metals and fabricated metal Long-run elasticity of E ( EE ) > short-run elasticity ( EE ) = induced technical change: chemicals Dynamic factor demand model

22 Conclusions and Future Research Conclusions Dynamic Translog factor demand model allows for diverse sources/types of technical change: returns to scale, TFP, factor bias, embodied and induced technical change. Technical change/progress is only partly energy saving, also for embodied technical change Disadvantage: embodied technical change is only energy saving, if E and K are substitutes induced technical change is only energy saving, if E and K are substitutes plus if investment reacts positively to energy prices. Future research Allowing for embodied technical change in the case that E and K are complements vintage model for aggregate K.


Download ppt "WIOD Consortium Meeting Sevilla, 25 – 26, May, 2011 Embodied and induced technical change and the price of carbon Kurt Kratena Michael Wueger."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google