Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byRandolph Spencer Modified over 9 years ago
1
1 1 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Slides by JOHN LOUCKS St. Edward’s University
2
2 2 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Chapter 3 Linear Programming: Sensitivity Analysis and Interpretation of Solution n Introduction to Sensitivity Analysis n Graphical Sensitivity Analysis n Sensitivity Analysis: Computer Solution n Simultaneous Changes
3
3 3 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved n In the previous chapter we discussed: objective function value objective function value values of the decision variables values of the decision variables reduced costs reduced costs slack/surplus slack/surplus n In this chapter we will discuss: changes in the coefficients of the objective function changes in the coefficients of the objective function changes in the right-hand side value of a constraint changes in the right-hand side value of a constraint Introduction to Sensitivity Analysis
4
4 4 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Introduction to Sensitivity Analysis n Sensitivity analysis (or post-optimality analysis) is used to determine how the optimal solution is affected by changes, within specified ranges, in: the objective function coefficients the objective function coefficients the right-hand side (RHS) values the right-hand side (RHS) values n Sensitivity analysis is important to a manager who must operate in a dynamic environment with imprecise estimates of the coefficients. n Sensitivity analysis allows a manager to ask certain what-if questions about the problem.
5
5 5 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n LP Formulation Max 5 x 1 + 7 x 2 s.t. x 1 < 6 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 < 19 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 < 19 x 1 + x 2 < 8 x 1 + x 2 < 8 x 1, x 2 > 0 x 1, x 2 > 0
6
6 6 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Graphical Solution 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 < 19 x 2 x 2 x1x1x1x1 x 1 + x 2 < 8 Max 5 x 1 + 7x 2 x 1 < 6 Optimal Solution: x 1 = 5, x 2 = 3 x 1 = 5, x 2 = 3 87654321 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
7
7 7 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Objective Function Coefficients n Let us consider how changes in the objective function coefficients might affect the optimal solution. n The range of optimality for each coefficient provides the range of values over which the current solution will remain optimal. n Managers should focus on those objective coefficients that have a narrow range of optimality and coefficients near the endpoints of the range.
8
8 8 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Changing Slope of Objective Function x1x1x1x1 FeasibleRegion 11 22 33 44 55 x 2 x 2 Coincides with x 1 + x 2 < 8 constraint line 87654321 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Coincides with 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 < 19 constraint line Objective function line for 5 x 1 + 7 x 2
9
9 9 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Range of Optimality n Graphically, the limits of a range of optimality are found by changing the slope of the objective function line within the limits of the slopes of the binding constraint lines. n Slope of an objective function line, Max c 1 x 1 + c 2 x 2, is - c 1 / c 2, and the slope of a constraint, a 1 x 1 + a 2 x 2 = b, is - a 1 / a 2.
10
10 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Range of Optimality for c 1 The slope of the objective function line is - c 1 / c 2. The slope of the first binding constraint, x 1 + x 2 = 8, is -1 and the slope of the second binding constraint, x 1 + 3 x 2 = 19, is -2/3. Find the range of values for c 1 (with c 2 staying 7) such that the objective function line slope lies between that of the two binding constraints: -1 < - c 1 /7 < -2/3 -1 < - c 1 /7 < -2/3 Multiplying through by -7 (and reversing the inequalities): Multiplying through by -7 (and reversing the inequalities): 14/3 < c 1 < 7 14/3 < c 1 < 7
11
11 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Range of Optimality for c 2 Find the range of values for c 2 ( with c 1 staying 5) such that the objective function line slope lies between that of the two binding constraints: Find the range of values for c 2 ( with c 1 staying 5) such that the objective function line slope lies between that of the two binding constraints: -1 < -5/ c 2 < -2/3 -1 < -5/ c 2 < -2/3 Multiplying by -1: 1 > 5/ c 2 > 2/3 Inverting, 1 < c 2 /5 < 3/2 Multiplying by 5: 5 < c 2 < 15/2 Multiplying by 5: 5 < c 2 < 15/2
12
12 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Software packages such as The Management Scientist and Microsoft Excel provide the following LP information: n Information about the objective function: its optimal value its optimal value coefficient ranges (ranges of optimality) coefficient ranges (ranges of optimality) n Information about the decision variables: their optimal values their optimal values their reduced costs their reduced costs n Information about the constraints: the amount of slack or surplus the amount of slack or surplus the dual prices the dual prices right-hand side ranges (ranges of feasibility) right-hand side ranges (ranges of feasibility) Sensitivity Analysis: Computer Solution
13
13 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Range of Optimality for c 1 and c 2 Adjustable Cells FinalReducedObjectiveAllowableAllowable CellNameValueCostCoefficientIncreaseDecrease $B$8 X1 X15.00.0520.33333333 $C$8 X2 X23.00.070.52 Constraints FinalShadowConstraintAllowableAllowable CellNameValuePrice R.H. Side IncreaseDecrease $B$13 #1 #15061E+301 $B$14 #2 #21921951 $B$15 #3 #38180.333333331.66666667
14
14 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Right-Hand Sides n Let us consider how a change in the right-hand side for a constraint might affect the feasible region and perhaps cause a change in the optimal solution. n The improvement in the value of the optimal solution per unit increase in the right-hand side is called the dual price or shadow price (for max problems). n The range of feasibility is the range over which the dual price is applicable. n As the RHS increases, other constraints will become binding and limit the change in the value of the objective function.
15
15 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Dual Price n Graphically, a dual price is determined by adding +1 to the right hand side value in question and then resolving for the optimal solution in terms of the same two binding constraints. n The dual price is equal to the difference in the values of the objective functions between the new and original problems. n The dual price for a nonbinding constraint is 0. n A negative dual price indicates that the objective function will not improve if the RHS is increased.
16
16 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Relevant Cost and Sunk Cost n A resource cost is a relevant cost if the amount paid for it is dependent upon the amount of the resource used by the decision variables. n Relevant costs are reflected in the objective function coefficients. n A resource cost is a sunk cost if it must be paid regardless of the amount of the resource actually used by the decision variables. n Sunk resource costs are not reflected in the objective function coefficients.
17
17 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Cautionary Note on the Interpretation of Dual Prices n Resource cost is sunk The dual price is the maximum amount you should be willing to pay for one additional unit of the resource. n Resource cost is relevant The dual price is the maximum premium over the normal cost that you should be willing to pay for one unit of the resource.
18
18 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Dual Prices Constraint 1: Since x 1 < 6 is not a binding constraint, its dual price is 0. Constraint 1: Since x 1 < 6 is not a binding constraint, its dual price is 0. Constraint 2: Change the RHS value of the second constraint to 20 and resolve for the optimal point determined by the last two constraints: 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 = 20 and x 1 + x 2 = 8. Constraint 2: Change the RHS value of the second constraint to 20 and resolve for the optimal point determined by the last two constraints: 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 = 20 and x 1 + x 2 = 8. The solution is x 1 = 4, x 2 = 4, z = 48. Hence, The solution is x 1 = 4, x 2 = 4, z = 48. Hence, the dual price = z new - z old = 48 - 46 = 2. the dual price = z new - z old = 48 - 46 = 2.
19
19 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Dual Prices Constraint 3: Change the RHS value of the third constraint to 9 and resolve for the optimal point determined by the last two constraints: 2 x 1 + 3 x 2 = 19 and x 1 + x 2 = 9. The solution is: x 1 = 8, x 2 = 1, z = 47. The dual price is z new - z old = 47 - 46 = 1.
20
20 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Dual Prices Adjustable Cells FinalReducedObjectiveAllowableAllowable CellNameValueCostCoefficientIncreaseDecrease $B$8 X1 X15.00.0520.33333333 $C$8 X2 X23.00.070.52 Constraints FinalShadowConstraintAllowableAllowable CellNameValuePrice R.H. Side IncreaseDecrease $B$13 #1 #15061E+301 $B$14 #2 #21921951 $B$15 #3 #38180.333333331.66666667
21
21 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Range of Feasibility n The range of feasibility for a change in the right hand side value is the range of values for this coefficient in which the original dual price remains constant. n Graphically, the range of feasibility is determined by finding the values of a right hand side coefficient such that the same two lines that determined the original optimal solution continue to determine the optimal solution for the problem.
22
22 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 1 n Range of Feasibility Adjustable Cells FinalReducedObjectiveAllowableAllowable CellNameValueCostCoefficientIncreaseDecrease $B$8 X1 X15.00.0520.33333333 $C$8 X2 X23.00.070.52 Constraints FinalShadowConstraintAllowableAllowable CellNameValuePrice R.H. Side IncreaseDecrease $B$13 #1 #15061E+301 $B$14 #2 #21921951 $B$15 #3 #38180.333333331.66666667
23
23 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Olympic Bike is introducing two new lightweight bicycle frames, the Deluxe and the Professional, to be made from special aluminum and steel alloys. The anticipated unit profits are $10 for the Deluxe and $15 for the Professional. The number of pounds of each alloy needed per frame is summarized on the next slide. Example 2: Olympic Bike Co.
24
24 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved A supplier delivers 100 pounds of the aluminum alloy and 80 pounds of the steel alloy weekly. Aluminum Alloy Steel Alloy Aluminum Alloy Steel Alloy Deluxe 2 3 Deluxe 2 3 Professional 4 2 Professional 4 2 How many Deluxe and Professional frames should Olympic produce each week? Olympic produce each week? Example 2: Olympic Bike Co.
25
25 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Model Formulation Verbal Statement of the Objective Function Verbal Statement of the Objective Function Maximize total weekly profit. Maximize total weekly profit. Verbal Statement of the Constraints Verbal Statement of the Constraints Total weekly usage of aluminum alloy < 100 pounds. Total weekly usage of aluminum alloy < 100 pounds. Total weekly usage of steel alloy < 80 pounds. Total weekly usage of steel alloy < 80 pounds. Definition of the Decision Variables Definition of the Decision Variables x 1 = number of Deluxe frames produced weekly. x 1 = number of Deluxe frames produced weekly. x 2 = number of Professional frames produced weekly. x 2 = number of Professional frames produced weekly.
26
26 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Model Formulation (continued) Max 10 x 1 + 15 x 2 (Total Weekly Profit) s.t. 2 x 1 + 4 x 2 < 100 (Aluminum Available) 3 x 1 + 2 x 2 < 80 (Steel Available) 3 x 1 + 2 x 2 < 80 (Steel Available) x 1, x 2 > 0 x 1, x 2 > 0
27
27 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Partial Spreadsheet: Problem Data
28
28 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Partial Spreadsheet Showing Solution
29
29 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Optimal Solution According to the output: x 1 (Deluxe frames) = 15 x 1 (Deluxe frames) = 15 x 2 (Professional frames) = 17.5 x 2 (Professional frames) = 17.5 Objective function value = $412.50 Objective function value = $412.50
30
30 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality Question: Suppose the profit on deluxe frames is increased to $20. Is the above solution still optimal? What is the value of the objective function when this unit profit is increased to $20?
31
31 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Sensitivity Report
32
32 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality Answer: The output states that the solution remains optimal as long as the objective function coefficient of x 1 is between 7.5 and 22.5. Because 20 is within this range, the optimal solution will not change. The optimal profit will change: 20 x 1 + 15 x 2 = 20(15) + 15(17.5) = $562.50.
33
33 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality Question: If the unit profit on deluxe frames were $6 instead of $10, would the optimal solution change?
34
34 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality
35
35 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved n Range of Optimality Answer: The output states that the solution remains optimal as long as the objective function coefficient of x 1 is between 7.5 and 22.5. Because 6 is outside this range, the optimal solution would change. Example 2: Olympic Bike Co.
36
36 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Simultaneous Changes n Range of Optimality and 100% Rule The 100% rule states that simultaneous changes in objective function coefficients will not change the optimal solution as long as the sum of the percentages of the change divided by the corresponding maximum allowable change in the range of optimality for each coefficient does not exceed 100%.
37
37 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality and 100% Rule Question: If simultaneously the profit on Deluxe frames was raised to $16 and the profit on Professional frames was raised to $17, would the current solution be optimal?
38
38 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Optimality and 100% Rule Answer: If c 1 = 16, the amount c 1 changed is 16 - 10 = 6. The maximum allowable increase is 22.5 - 10 = 12.5, so this is a 6/12.5 = 48% change. If c 2 = 17, the amount that c 2 changed is 17 - 15 = 2. The maximum allowable increase is 20 - 15 = 5 so this is a 2/5 = 40% change. The sum of the change percentages is 88%. Since this does not exceed 100%, the optimal solution would not change.
39
39 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Simultaneous Changes n Range of Feasibility and 100% Rule The 100% rule states that simultaneous changes in right-hand sides will not change the dual prices as long as the sum of the percentages of the changes divided by the corresponding maximum allowable change in the range of feasibility for each right-hand side does not exceed 100%.
40
40 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Feasibility and Sunk Costs Question: Given that aluminum is a sunk cost, what is the maximum amount the company should pay for 50 extra pounds of aluminum?
41
41 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Feasibility and Sunk Costs
42
42 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Feasibility and Sunk Costs Answer: Because the cost for aluminum is a sunk cost, the shadow price provides the value of extra aluminum. The shadow price for aluminum is the same as its dual price (for a maximization problem). The shadow price for aluminum is $3.125 per pound and the maximum allowable increase is 60 pounds. Because 50 is in this range, the $3.125 is valid. Thus, the value of 50 additional pounds is = 50($3.125) = $156.25.
43
43 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Feasibility and Relevant Costs Question: If aluminum were a relevant cost, what is the maximum amount the company should pay for 50 extra pounds of aluminum?
44
44 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved Example 2: Olympic Bike Co. n Range of Feasibility and Relevant Costs Answer: If aluminum were a relevant cost, the shadow price would be the amount above the normal price of aluminum the company would be willing to pay. Thus if initially aluminum cost $4 per pound, then additional units in the range of feasibility would be worth $4 + $3.125 = $7.125 per pound.
45
45 Slide © 2008 Thomson South-Western. All Rights Reserved End of Chapter 3
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com Inc.
All rights reserved.