Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL"— Presentation transcript:

1 TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL
2 TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL 1 Reasons for Trade 2 Ricardian Model 3 Determining the Pattern of International Trade 4 Solving for International Prices 5 Conclusions

2 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Chapter Outline Introduction Reasons for Trade Proximity Resources Absolute Advantage Comparative Advantage Ricardian Model The Home Country The Foreign Country © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

3 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Chapter Outline Determining the Pattern of International Trade International Trade Equilibrium Solving for Wages Across Countries Solving for International Prices Home Export Supply Curve Foreign Import Demand Curve Conclusions © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

4 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Learning Objectives Understand the reasons why countries trade Distinguish between absolute and comparative advantage Understand the Ricardian model Understand the no-trade equilibrium using each country’s PPF and Indifference Curve © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

5 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Learning Objectives Understand how the pattern of international trade is determined Understand how to solve for prices and wages across countries Understand how to derive the export supply curve and the import demand curve Understand the international trade equilibrium Understand how to determine a country’s terms of trade and how they affect that country © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

6 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Introduction Why does the U.S. import goods which they are capable of producing? The U.S. imports many manufactured goods but has great manufacturing capability? The first part of this book looks at the various reasons for trade: Technological differences Amounts of resources Differences in costs of outsourcing The proximity of countries to each other © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

7 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Introduction This chapter focuses on how technology differences across countries affect trade This is referred to as the Ricardian model because it was proposed by the 19th century economist David Ricardo It explains how the level of a country’s technology affects wages paid to labor in a way that countries with better technology have higher wages. We use this to explain a country’s trade pattern—the products it exports and imports © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

8 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Reasons for Trade In beginning to talk about the Ricardian model, we will cover an introduction to the other reasons for trade Proximity The closer countries are the lower the costs of transportation For example, the largest trading partner of most European countries is another European country Close proximity often leads to countries joining into a free trade area © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

9 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Reasons for Trade Resources A country can have resources that give it an edge in the production of certain goods A country with a lot of snow may be very good at producing snowboards Geography includes natural resources (including land and minerals), labor resources, and capital Resources are also called factors of production—the land, labor, and capital used to produce goods and services © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

10 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Reasons for Trade Resources Some countries that have a large resource of cheap labor produce unfinished products that are then processed in another country Trade in unfinished goods is an example of outsourcing—when production activities are spread across several countries and trade semi-finished products between them © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

11 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Reasons for Trade Absolute Advantage When a country has the best technology for producing a good, it has an absolute advantage in the production of that good Germany has an absolute advantage in the production of snowboards Why is it that so many are imported from China then? Or why doesn’t the U.S. just make all their own snowboards? © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

12 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Reasons for Trade Comparative Advantage Absolute advantage is actually not a good explanation of trade patterns Comparative advantage is primary explanation for trade among countries A country has a comparative advantage in producing these goods that it produces best compared to how well it produces other goods China does not have an absolute advantage compared to the U.S. but is better at producing snowboards than some other goods © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

13 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model We will use two goods to develop a Ricardian model of trade: wheat and cloth Wheat and other grains are major exports of the U.S. and Europe Many types of cloth are imported into these countries “Home” will be the country exporting wheat and importing cloth © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

14 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The Home Country We will assume that labor is the only resource used to produce both goods One worker can produce 4 bushels of wheat or 2 yards of cloth The Marginal Product of Labor is the extra output obtained by using one more unit of labor MPLW = 4 and MPLC = 2 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

15 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Home Production Possibilities Frontier We can use the marginal products of labor to construct Home’s PPF Assume there are 25 workers in Home If all the workers were employed in wheat, the country could produce 100 bushels If they were all employed in cloth they could produce 50 yards The PPF connects these two points © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

16 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Showing these calculations we can see: Labor = 25, MPLW = 4, MPLC = 2 QW = MPLW(L) = 25(4) = 100 QC = MPLC(L) = 25(2) = 50 This gives us a straight line PPF which is a unique feature of the Ricardian model Assumes marginal production of labor is constant No diminishing returns because it ignores the use of other resources © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

17 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The slope of the PPF can be calculated as the ratio of marginal products of the two goods The slope also equals the opportunity cost of wheat—the amount of cloth that must be given up to obtain one more unit of wheat. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

18 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Figure 2.1 Home Production Possibilities Frontier The Home PPF is a straight line between 50 yards of cloth and 100 bushels of wheat. The slope of the PPF equals the negative of the opportunity cost of wheat, that is, the amount of cloth that must be given up (yard) to obtain 1 more bushel of wheat. Equivalently, the magnitude of the slope can be expressed as the ratio of the marginal products of labor for the two goods. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

19 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Home Indifference Curve Given Home’s PPF, we still don’t know how much Home will choose to produce We need information about the country’s preferences—we need an indifference curve The indifference curve shows the combinations of two goods that the country can consume and be equally satisfied © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

20 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Indifference curves increase in utility as the curves move northeast All points on an indifference curve have the same level of utility A country cannot produce outside their PPF so, without trade, they are constrained in their utility by the PPF We use these indifference curves to show the preferences of an entire country © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

21 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The country is indifferent between A and B The country is better off on U2 but cannot produce that much U0<U1<U2 Figure 2.2 Home Equilibrium with No Trade Points A and B lie on the same indifference curve and give the Home consumers the level of utility U1. The highest level of Home utility on the PPF is obtained at point A, which is the no-trade equilibrium. Point D is also on the PPF but would give lower utility. Point C represents a higher utility level but is off of the PPF, so it is not attainable in the absence of international trade. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

22 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Home Equilibrium Without trade, the PPF acts as a budget constraint for the country The country will produce at its highest level of utility within the limits of the PPF In the graph, the highest level of utility that can be reached and still stay within the PPF is U1 with production at point A © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

23 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Home Equilibrium Point A is the no-trade equilibrium The country can reach point A by its own production The assumption of perfect competition will assure the country ends up at the highest level of utility possible © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

24 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The country could produce at point D but would be at a higher level of utility at point A. At point A, on U1, is the best the country can do Figure 2.2 Home Equilibrium with No Trade © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

25 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Opportunity Cost and Prices The slope of the PPF reflects the opportunity of producing one more bushel of wheat Under perfect competition the opportunity cost of wheat should equal the price of wheat Price reflects the opportunity cost of a good © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

26 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Wages Determination of wages In competitive markets firms hire workers up to the point at which the hourly wage equals the value of one more hour of production The value of one more hour of labor equals the amount of goods produced in that hour (MPL) times the price of the good Labor hired up to the point where wage equals P*MPL for each industry © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

27 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Wages In competitive markets, labor can move freely between industries Labor will move to the higher paid industry This will continue until there is equalization of wages between industries © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

28 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The equalization of wages will give us the following: The right hand side is the slope of the PPF and the opportunity cost of obtaining one more bushel of wheat The left hand side is the relative price of wheat © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

29 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The price ratio, PW/PC, always denotes the relative price of the good in the numerator, measured in terms of how much of the good in the denominator must be given up The slope of the PPF equals the relative price of wheat, the good on the horizontal axis © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

30 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The Foreign Country Assume Foreign’s technology is inferior to Home’s Foreign has an absolute disadvantage in producing both wheat and cloth as compared to Home © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

31 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model The Foreign Country Foreign Production Possibilities Frontier Assume a Foreign worker can produce one bushel of wheat or one yard of cloth MPL*W = 1, MPL*C = 1 Assume there are 100 workers available in Foreign If all workers were employed in wheat they could produce 100 bushels. If all workers were employed in cloth they could produce 100 yards. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

32 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Figure 2.3 Foreign Production Possibilities Frontier The Foreign PPF is a straight line between 100 yards of cloth and 100 bushels of wheat. The slope of the PPF equals the negative of the opportunity cost of wheat, that is, the amount of cloth that must be given up (1 yard) to obtain 1 more bushel of wheat. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

33 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Comparative Advantage Given the information we have gathered, we can begin to talk about the opportunity cost of production of each good in each country Given the opportunity cost information, we can determine comparative advantages in each country for each good © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

34 Ricardian Model Opportunity Costs for Goods in Home and Foreign Cloth
(1 Yard) Wheat (1 Bushel) Home 2 Bushels Of Wheat ½ Yard Of Cloth Foreign 1 Bushel 1 Yard © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

35 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Comparative Advantage Remember a country has a comparative advantage in a good when it has a lower opportunity cost of producing than another country By looking at the chart we can see that Foreign has a comparative advantage in producing cloth Foreign’s Opportunity cost of cloth is lower Home has a comparative advantage in producing wheat Home’s opportunity cost of wheat is lower © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

36 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Ricardian Model Equilibrium in Foreign Foreign’s preferences can also be represented by an indifference curve Economy produces at the point of highest utility for the country within the PPF constraint The slope of the PPF is the opportunity cost of wheat The no-trade relative price of wheat is P*W/P*C = 1 The relative price exceeds Home’s no-trade relative price of wheat: P*W/P*C = ½ The difference in relative prices comes from the comparative advantage that Home has in wheat © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

37 Ricardian Model—Foreign
Figure 2.4 Foreign Equilibrium with No Trade The highest level of Foreign utility on the PPF is obtained at point A*, which is the no-trade equilibrium. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

38 Comparative Advantage in Apparel, Textiles, and Wheat
U.S. Textile and apparel industries face intense import competition Burlington Industries announced in January 1999 it would reduce production capacity by 25% due to increased imports from Asia After layoffs they employed 17,400 persons in the U.S. with a 1999 sales of $1.6 billion Sales per employee were therefore $92,000 This is the average for all U.S. apparel producers Textiles are even more productive with annual sales per employee of $140,000 in the U.S. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

39 Can Comparative Advantage be Created? The Case of “Icewine”
In general we think of a country having a comparative advantage in a good Certain countries have a comparative advantage in the production of wine Can a country create a comparative advantage? Areas that get very cold are not good wine producers because the vines get too cold © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

40 Can Comparative Advantage be Created? The Case of “Icewine”
Countries that are not able to produce traditional wine have done this The Niagara Falls region of Canada sells a product called “icewine” The production of this good requires that grapes freeze on the vine and then picked Unique flavor of the wine has lead to a relatively high demand This has created a comparative advantage in a certain type of wine, even though they did not have the advantage in traditional wine production © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

41 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
What happens now when goods are traded between these countries? We will see the country’s no-trade relative price determines which product it will export and which it will import The no-trade relative price equals its opportunity cost of production Therefore the pattern of exports and imports, will be determined by the opportunity costs of production in each country—their comparative advantage © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

42 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
International Trade Equilibrium Relative price of cloth in Foreign is PC/PW = 1 Relative price of cloth in Home is PC/PW = 2 Therefore Foreign would want to export their cloth to Home—they can make it for $1 and export it for more than $1 The opposite is true for wheat Home will export wheat and Foreign will export cloth Both countries export the good for which they have the comparative advantage © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

43 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
How Trade Occurs As Home exports wheat, quantity of wheat sold at Home falls The price of wheat at Home is bid up More wheat goes into Foreign’s market The price of wheat in Foreign falls As Foreign exports cloth, the quantity sold in Foreign falls, and the price in Foreign for cloth rises. The price of cloth at Home falls © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

44 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
International Trade Equilibrium Two countries are in a trade equilibrium when the relative price of wheat is the same in the two countries—this means the relative price of cloth is also the same in both countries. In understanding the trade equilibrium we need to do two things Determine the relative price of wheat or cloth in the trade equilibrium See how the shift from the no-trade equilibrium to the trade equilibrium affects production and consumption in both Home and Foreign © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

45 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
International Trade Equilibrium The relative price of wheat in the trade equilibrium will be between the no-trade price in the two countries For now lets assume the free-trade price, PW/PC = 2/3. This is between the price of ½ in Home and 1 in Foreign. We can now take this price and see how trade changes production and consumption in each country © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

46 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Change in Production and Consumption Home producers of wheat can earn more than the opportunity cost of wheat by selling it to Foreign Home will therefore shift labor resources toward the production of wheat and increase its production Remember wages are calculated by the price of the good times its marginal product Given the information from before, we can calculate the ratio of wages in the two industries © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

47 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Home’s workers will want to work in wheat and no cloth will be produced With trade, Home will be fully specialized in wheat production © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

48 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Home can export wheat at the international relative price of 2/3 For each bushel of wheat it exports, it gets 2/3 yards of cloth in return In Figure 2.5 we trace this out to get a new price line showing the world price The world price line shows the range of consumption possibilities that a country can achieve by specializing in one good and trading Remember: this only represents consumption possibilities since production is still constrained by the PPF © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

49 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
The new world price, PW/PC = 2/3, shows us the new range of consumption possibilities U1 A Wheat, QW (bushels) Cloth, QC (yards) B Home production 50 25 The country can now achieve a higher utility with the new consumption possibilities World price line, Slope = –2/3 U2 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

50 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Trade allows a country to engage in consumption possibilities it did not have before trade We can see this as Home can now be on a higher indifference curve with trade than they were without it This is the first demonstration of gains from trade © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

51 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Pattern of Trade and Gains from Trade Under the new production, each country specializes fully in the good for which they have the comparative advantage They then export some of their production and import some of the other good from the other country Home specializes in wheat and Foreign specializes in cloth The new indifference curve shows the new consumption point The difference between production and consumption give us trade patterns © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

52 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Home produces 100 bushels but consumes only 40, so exports equal 60 U1 Wheat, QW (bushels) Cloth, QC (yards) C B U2 World price line, Slope = –2/3 50 40 Home produces 0 yards of cloth but consumes 40, so imports equal 40. Home consumption Home imports 40 yards of cloth Figure 2.5 Home Equilibrium with Trade With a world relative price of wheat of 2/3, Home production will occur at point B. Through international trade, Home is able to export each bushel of wheat it produces in exchange for 2/3 yard of cloth. As wheat is exported, Home moves up the world price line BC. Home consumption occurs at point C, at the tangent intersection with indifference curve U2, since this is the highest possible utility curve on the world price line. Given these levels of production and consumption, we can see that total exports are 60 bushels of wheat in exchange for imports of 40 yards of cloth and also that Home consumes 10 fewer bushels of wheat and 15 more yards of cloth relative to its pretrade levels. Home production Home exports 60 bushels of wheat © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

53 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Pattern of Trade and Gains from Trade Foreign specializes in cloth and Home specializes in wheat The new indifference curve shows the new consumption point for Foreign The difference between production and consumption give us trade patterns We see a similar graph for Foreign as we did for Home and can see the imports and exports © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

54 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Home produces 0 bushels of wheat but consumes 60, so imports equal 60. Foreign production Wheat, (bushels) Cloth, (yards) 100 60 B* World price line, Slope = –2/3 U0 U1 Foreign produces 100 Yards but consumes only 60, so exports equal 40 C* Foreign consumption Foreign exports 40 yards of cloth Figure 2.6 Foreign Equilibrium with Trade With a world relative price of wheat of 2/3, Foreign production will occur at point B*. Through international trade, Foreign is able to export 2/3 yard of cloth in exchange for 1 bushel of wheat, moving down the world price line B*C*. Foreign consumption occurs at point C*, and total exports are 40 yards of cloth in exchange for imports of 60 bushels of wheat. Relative to its pretrade wheat and cloth consumption (point A*), Foreign consumes 10 more bushels of wheat and 10 more yards of cloth. Foreign imports 60 bushels of wheat © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

55 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Each country is exporting the good for which it has the comparative advantage The confirms that the pattern of trade is determined by comparative advantage The first lesson of the Ricardian model There are gains from trade for both countries The second lesson of the Ricardian model However, we have not yet determined the level of wages across countries Relative prices converge. Do wages? Wages actually differ—they are determined by absolute advantage—not comparative advantage © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

56 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Solving for Wages Across Countries As stated before, in competitive labor markets, firms will pay workers the value of their marginal product Since Home produces and exports wheat, they will be paid in terms of that good—the real wage is MPLW = 4 bushels of wheat The workers sell the wheat on the world market at a relative price of PW/PC = 2/3 We can use this to calculate the real wage in terms of cloth (PW/PC)MPLW = (2/3)4 = 8/3 yards © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

57 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Solving for Wages Across Countries We can do this for Foreign as well and summarize Home real wage is 4 bushels of wheat 8/3 yards of cloth Foreign real wage is 3/2 bushels of wheat 1 yard of cloth Foreign workers earn less than Home workers as measured by their ability to purchase either good This fact reflects Home’s absolute advantage in the production of both goods © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

58 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
Wages are determined by absolute advantage and trade is determined by comparative advantage This should make sense The only way a country with poor technology can export at a price others are willing to pay is by having low wages As a country develops better technology, its wages will rise Workers become better off through receiving higher wages As countries engage in trade, the Ricardian model predicts that their real wages will rise © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

59 Determining the Pattern of International Trade
We can see this in the real world Per capita income in China in 1978 is estimated at $925 In 2000, per capita income in China had risen to $3750 Per capita income in India more than doubled from $1180 in 1978 to $2480 in 2000 It is strongly believed that the opportunity for these countries to engage in international trade has been crucial in raising their standard of living © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

60 Labor Productivity and Wages
Labor productivity can be measured by the value-added per hour in manufacturing Value-added is the difference between sales revenue in an industry and the costs of intermediate inputs Equals the payments to labor and capital in an industry The Ricardian model ignores capital so we can measure labor productivity as value-added divided by the number of hours worked, or value-added per hour Figure 2.7 shows value-added per hour in manufacturing for several countries Countries with higher labor productivity pay higher wages, just as the Ricardian model predicts © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

61 Labor Productivity and Wages
Figure 2.7 Labor Productivity and Wages, 2001 Labor productivity is measured by value-added per hour of work and can be compared with the wages paid in manufacturing in various countries. The general ranking of countries—from highest to lowest—in terms of labor productivity is the same as the ranking in terms of wages: countries with higher labor productivity pay higher wages, just as the Ricardian model predicts. Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

62 Labor Productivity and Wages
We can also see the connection between productivity and wages over time Figure 2.8 shows the general upward movement in labor productivity is matched by upward movement in wages This is also predicted by the Ricardian Model An excerpt of Figure 2.8 is shown in the next slide © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

63 Labor Productivity and Wages
Figure 2.8 Labor Productivity and Wages over Time The trends in labor productivity and wages can also be graphed over time. The general upward movement in labor productivity is matched by upward movements in wages, as predicted by the Ricardian model. Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

64 Solving for International Prices
In the previous analysis we assumed the world price of wheat was 2/3 In reality world price is determined by a market for exports and imports We will derive a Home export supply curve Shows the amount it wants to export at various relative prices Similarly we will derive a Foreign import demand curve Shows the amount of wheat that it will import at various relative prices © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

65 Solving for International Prices
Home Export Supply Curve We can use the information we gathered from before to derive an export supply curve The export supply curve will have the relative price of wheat on the Y-axis and the amount of wheat on the X-axis We saw before at a relative price of 2/3 related to exports of 60 bushels The first point on the export supply curve: A and A′ © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

66 Solving for International Prices
To derive other points on the export supply curve we look at the no-trade equilibrium When the relative price of wheat is ½, Home exports of wheat are zero (no-trade equilibrium) Point A and A′ For the 3rd point, we keep the relative price of wheat at ½ At this price, Home could export some wheat in exchange for cloth Production could shift from A to any other place on the PPF Workers are willing to shift between industries as the wages are the same © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

67 Solving for International Prices
If we assume that all workers have moved into wheat production With the relative price of ½, consumption is still at point A and the difference between A and B is the amount of wheat that Home is exporting At the relative price of ½, with wheat exports of 50, gives another point on the Home export supply curve: B′ © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

68 Solving for International Prices
Figure 2.9 Home Export Supply Panel (a) repeats Figure 2-5 showing the trade equilibrium for Home with production at point B and consumption at point C. Panel (b) shows the Home export supply of wheat. When the relative price of wheat is ½, Home will export any amount of wheat between 0 and 50 bushels, along the segment A′B′ of the Home export supply curve. For relative prices above ½ Home exports more than 50 bushels, along the segment B′C′. For example, at the relative price of 2/3, Home exports 60 bushels of wheat. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

69 Solving for International Prices
The flat portion of the export supply curve is a special feature of the Ricardian model The PPF is a straight line Production can occur anywhere along the PPF as workers shift between industries This leads to all the export levels between A′ and B′ At prices above ½ production is the same but consumption changes, rising above point A © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

70 Solving for International Prices
Foreign Import Demand We can use a similar analysis to construct the import demand for wheat At the world relative price of 2/3, Foreign imports 50 bushels of wheat, C′ and C′ The no-trade equilibrium in Foreign, with a relative price of 1, is zero imports, A′ and A′ Production can shift from point A, at a price of 1, as workers move between industries If workers all shift to cloth Foreign imports 50 bushels of wheat, B′ and B′ This gives us the import demand curve © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

71 Solving for International Prices
Figure 2.10 Foreign Import Demand Panel (a) repeats Figure 2-6, showing the Foreign trade equilibrium with production at point B* and consumption at point C*. Panel (b) shows Foreign import demand for wheat. When the relative price of wheat is 1, Foreign will import any amount of wheat between 0 and 50 bushels, along the segment A*’B*’ of the Foreign import demand curve. For relative prices below 1, Foreign imports more than 50 bushels, along the segment B*’C*’. For example, at the relative price of 2/3, Foreign imports 60 bushels of wheat. © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

72 Solving for International Prices
International Trade Equilibrium We need to put the Home export supply together with the Foreign import demand The exports from Home come from the excess domestic supply The imports to Foreign come from the excess domestic demand The is the World market for wheat: Equilibrium price of 2/3 and trade of 60 bushels of wheat This is the amount that clears the world market Desired sales of Home equal the desired purchases by Foreign © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

73 Solving for International Prices
The Terms of Trade The price of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports For Home, PW/PC is their terms of trade An increase in PW or a fall in PC will raise Home’s terms of trade An increase in the terms of trade is good for a country: it makes it better off They earn more for their exports They pay less for their imports The opposite is true for Foreign © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

74 The Terms of Trade for Primary Commodities
Latin American economist Raúl Prebisch and British economist Hans Singer each put forward the hypothesis that the price of primary commodities would decline over time relative to the price of manufactured goods Primary commodities are often exported by developing countries, so their terms of trade would decline over time © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

75 The Terms of Trade for Primary Commodities
This theory might be true for a couple of reasons First, As countries become richer, they spend a smaller share of their income on food As world income grows, demand for food falls relative to the demand for manufactured goods The price of agricultural products can also be expected to fall relative to manufactured goods © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

76 The Terms of Trade for Primary Commodities
Second, For mineral products, industrialized countries continually find substitutes in the production of manufactured products The substitution away from mineral products is a form of technological progress, and as it proceeds, can lead to a fall in the price of raw materials © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

77 The Terms of Trade for Primary Commodities
There are also reasons why the theory might not be true: First, Technological progress in manufactured goods can certainly lead to a fall in the price of these goods as they become easier to produce This is a fall in terms of trade for industrialized countries rather than developing countries Second, At least for oil, the cartel restricting prices has caused an increase in the terms of trade for oil-exporting countries © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

78 The Terms of Trade for Primary Commodities
Figure 2.12 shows 24 primary commodities from 1900–1998, with their world price relative to the overall price of manufactured goods From these results for different commodities, we can conclude that there are some that follow the pattern predicted by Prebisch and Singer, with falling prices relative to manufacturing However, this is not the general rule—other primary commodities have had increasing or non-consistent change in their prices © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

79 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Conclusions The Ricardian model was to prove the mercantilist idea that exports are good and imports are bad David Ricardo found this was not true and considered an example where trade between two countries was balanced The pattern of trade is actually determined by comparative advantage, and both countries gain from trade The Ricardian model is presented with only one factor of production—labor © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

80 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Conclusions Because wages depend on the marginal products of labor in each country, we conclude that wages are determined by absolute advantage Country with better technology will be able to pay higher wages In addition, wages depend on the prices prevailing on world markets for the goods exported by each country The terms of trade is the price of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

81 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Conclusions Because we assume that labor is the only resource, the PPF in the Ricardian model is a straight line This leads to the export supply and import demand curves each have a flat segment Allowing for more realistic assumptions using several factors of production, the gains from trade become much more complicated We will discuss this in future chapters © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

82 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Key Points A country has comparative advantage in producing a good when the opportunity cost of producing the goods is lower than the opportunity cost of producing the good in another country The pattern of trade between countries is determined by comparative advantage All countries experience gains from trade © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor

83 © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor
Key Points The level of wages in each country is determined by its absolute advantage, that is, by the amount the country can produce with its labor The equilibrium price of a good on the world market is determined where the export supply of one country equals the import demand of the other country A country’s terms of trade, the price of its export good divided by the price of its import good, affects how well off a country is from trade © 2007 Worth Publishers ▪ International Trade ▪ Feenstra/Taylor


Download ppt "TRADE AND TECHNOLOGY: THE RICARDIAN MODEL"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google