Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Economic Exchange on Networks Networked Life CSE 112 Spring 2007 Prof. Michael Kearns.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Economic Exchange on Networks Networked Life CSE 112 Spring 2007 Prof. Michael Kearns."— Presentation transcript:

1 Economic Exchange on Networks Networked Life CSE 112 Spring 2007 Prof. Michael Kearns

2 Exchange Economies Suppose there are a bunch of different goods orcommodities –wheat, milk, rice, paper, raccoon pelts, matches, grain alcohol,… –no differences or distinctions within a good: rice is rice We may all have different initial amounts or endowments –I might have 10 sacks of rice and two raccoon pelts –you might have 6 bushels of wheat, 2 boxes of matches –etc. etc. etc. Of course, we may want to exchange some of our goods –I can’t eat 10 sacks of rice, and I need matches to light a fire –it’s getting cold and you need raccoon mittens –etc. etc. etc. How should we engage in exchange? What should be the rates of exchange? –how many sacks of rice per box of matches? These are among the oldest questions in markets and economics

3 Cash and Prices Suppose we introduce an abstract resource called cash –no inherent value –simply meant to facilitate trade, “encode” pairwise exchange rates And now suppose we introduce prices in cash –i.e. rates of exchange between each “real” good and cash –e.g. a racoon pelt is worth $5.25, a box of matches $1.10 Then if we all believed in cash and the prices… –we might try to sell our initial endowments for cash –then use the cash to buy exactly what we most want But will there really be: –others who want to buy all of our endowments? (demand) –others who will be selling what we want? (supply)

4 Mathematical Microeconomics Have k abstract goods or commodities g1, g2, …, gk Have n consumers or “players” Each player has an initial endowment e = (e1,e2,…,ek) > 0 Each consumer has their own utility function: –assigns a subjective “valuation” or utility to any amounts of the k goods –e.g. if k = 4, U(x1,x2,x3,x4) = 0.2*x1 + 0.7*x2 + 0.3*x3 + 0.5*x4 –here g2 is my “favorite” good --- but it might be expensive –generally assume utility functions are insatiable always some bundle of goods you’d prefer more –utility functions not necessarily linear, though

5 Market Equilibrium Suppose we announce prices p = (p1,p2,…,pk) for the k goods Assume consumers are rational: –they will attempt to sell their endowment e at the prices p (supply) –if successful, they will get cash e*p = e1 *p1 + e2*p2 + … + ek*pk (* = times) –with this cash, they will then attempt to purchase x = (x1,x2,…,xk) that maximizes their utility U(x) subject to their budget (demand) –example: U(x1,x2,x3,x4) = 0.2*x1 + 0.7*x2 + 0.3*x3 + 0.5*x4 p = (1.0,0.35,0.15,2.0) look at “bang for the buck” for each good i, wi/pi: –g1: 0.2/1.0 = 0.2; g2: 0.7/0.35 = 2.0; g3: 0.3/0.15 = 2.0; g4: 0.5/2.0 = 0.25 –so we will purchase as much of g2 and/or g3 as we can subject to budget A specific mechanism: bringing your endowments to the stage –what could go wrong? 1) stuff left on stage 2) not enough stuff on stage Say that the prices p are an equilibrium if there are exactly enough goods to accomplish all supply and demand constraints That is, supply exactly balances demand --- market clears

6 Another Phone Call from Stockholm Arrow and Debreu, 1954: –There is always a set of equilibrium prices! –Both won Nobel prizes in Economics Intuition: suppose p is not an equilibrium –if there is excess demand for some good at p, raise its price –if there is excess supply for some good at p, lower its price –the famed “invisible hand” of the market The trickiness: –changing prices can radically alter consumer preferences not necessarily a gradual process; see “bang for the buck” argument –everyone reacting/adjusting simultaneously –utility functions may be extremely complex May also have to specify “consumption plans”: –who buys exactly what, and from whom from whom –in previous example, may have to specify how much of g2 and g3 to buy –example: A has Fruit Loops and Lucky Charms, but wants granola B and C have only granola, both want either FL or LC (indifferent) need to “coordinate” B and C to buy A’s FL and LC

7 Remarks A&D 1954 a mathematical tour-de-force –resolved and clarified a hundred of years of confusion –proof related to Nash’s; (n+1)-player game with “price player” Actual markets have been around for millennia –highly structured social systems –it’s the mathematical formalism and understanding that’s new Model abstracts away details of price adjustment/formation process –modern financial markets –pre-currency bartering and trade –auctions –etc. etc. etc. Model can be augmented in various way: –labor as a commodity –firms producing goods from raw materials and labor –etc. etc. etc. “Efficient markets” ~ in equilibrium (at least at any given moment)

8 Network Economics All of what we’ve said so far assumes: –that anyone can trade (buy or sell) with anyone else –equivalently, exchange takes place on a complete network –at equilibrium, global prices must emerge due to competition But there are many economic settings in which everyone is not free to trade with everyone else –geography: perishability: you buy groceries from local markets so it won’t spoil labor: you purchases services from local residents –legality: if one were to purchase drugs, it is likely to be from an acquaintance (no centralized market possible) peer-to-peer music exchange –politics: there may be trade embargoes between nations –regulations: on Wall Street, certain transactions (within a firm) may be prohibited

9 A Network Model of Market Economies Still begin with the same framework: –k goods or commodities –n consumers, each with their own endowments and utility functions But now assume an undirected network dictating exchange –each vertex is a consumer –edge between i and j means they are free to engage in trade –no edge between i and j: direct exchange is forbidden Note: can “encode” network in goods and utilities –for each raw good g and consumer i, introduce virtual good (g,i) –think of (g,i) as “good g when sold by consumer i” –consumer j will have zero utility for (g,i) if no edge between i and j j’s original utility for g if there is an edge between i and j

10 Network Equilibrium Now prices are for each (g,i), not for just raw goods –permits the possibility of variation in price for raw goods –prices of (g,i) and (g,j) may differ –what would cause such variation at equilibrium? Each consumer must still behave rationally –attempt to sell all of initial endowment, but only to NW neighbors –attempt to purchase goods maximizing utility within budget –will only purchase g from those neighbors with minimum price for g Market equilibrium still always exists! –set of prices (and consumptions plans) such that: all initial endowments sold (no excess supply) no consumer has money left over (no excess demand)

11 Network Structure and Outcome Q: How does the structure of a network influence the prices/wealths at equilibrium? Need to separate asymmetries of endowments & utilities from those of NW structure We will thus consider bipartite economies Only two kinds of players/consumers: –“Milks”: start with 1 unit of milk, but have utility only for wheat –“Wheats” start with 1 unit of wheat, but have utility only for milk –exact form of utility functions irrelevant Equal numbers of Milks and Wheats Network is bipartite --- only have edges between Milks and Wheats When will such a network have variation in prices?

12 22/3 1/2 3/2 Price = amount of the other good received = wealth Prices at opposite ends of an edge always reciprocal: p and 1/p Checking equilibrium conditions: –only “cheapest” edges used –supply and demand balance: a sends 1/2 each to w and y b sends 1 to x c sends 1/2 each to x and z d sends 1 to z w sends 1 to a x sends 2/3 to b, 1/3 to c y sends 1 to a z sends 1/3 to c, 2/3 to b Some edges unused at equilibrium –exchange subgraph adcb wxyz An Example

13 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Suppose we add the single green edge Now equilibrium has no wealth variation! adcb wxyz

14 A More Complex Example Solid edges: –exchange at equilibrium Dashed edges: –competitive but unused Dotted edges: –non-competitive prices Note price variation –0.33 to 2.00 Degree alone does not determine price! –e.g. B2 vs. B11 –e.g. S5 vs. S14

15 Characterizing Price Variation Consider any bipartite “Milk-Wheat” network economy –again, all endowments equal to 1.0, equal numbers of Milks and Wheats Necessary and sufficient condition for all equilibrium prices and wealths to be equal: –network has a perfect matching as a subgraph –a pairing of Milks and Wheats such that everyone has exactly one trading partner on the other side What if there is no perfect matching subgraph? How large can the price variation be? For any set of vertices S on one side (e.g. Milks), let N(S) be its set of neighbors on the other side Find the S such that |S|/|N(S)| = p is maximized (here |S| is the number of vertices in S) Then the largest price/wealth in the network will be p, and the smallest 1/p Intuition: When S is very large but N(S) is small, consumers in S are “captives” of their neighbors N(S) –Can actually iterate: remove S and N(S) from the network, find S’ maximizing |S’|/|N(S’)|,… Note: When network has a perfect matching, N(S) is always at least as large as S Note: Finding the maximizing set S may involve some computation… Now let’s examine price variation in a statistical network formation model…

16 A Bipartite Economy Network Formation Model Consider economies with only two goods: milk and wheat… …and only two kinds of players/consumers: –Milks: start with 1 unit of milk, have utility only for wheat –Wheats: start with 1 unit of wheat, have utility only for milk –exact form of utility functions irrelevant Wheats and Milks added incrementally in pairs at each time step Goal: bipartite network formation model interpolating between P.A. and E-R Probabilistically generates a bipartite graph All edges between buyers and sellers Each new party will have  links back to extant graph –note:  generates bipartite trees –larger generates cyclical graphs Distribution of new buyer’s links: –with prob. 1 –  : extant seller chosen w.r.t. preferential attachment –with prob.  : extant seller chosen uniformly at random –  is pure pref. att.;  is “like” Erdos-Renyi model So (  ) characterizes distribution of generative model

17 Price Variation vs.  and   n = 250, scatter plot Exponential decrease with  rapid decrease with

18 (Statistical) Structure and Outcome Wealth distribution at equilibrium: –Power law (heavy-tailed) in networks generated by preferential attachment –Sharply peaked (Poisson) in random graphs Price variation (max/min) at equilibrium: –Grows as a root of n in preferential attachment –None in random graphs Random graphs result in “socialist” outcomes –Despite lack of centralized formation process Price variation in arbitrary networks: –Characterized by presence/absence of a perfect matching –Alternately: an expansion property –Theory of random walks –Economic vs. geographic isolation

19 An Amusing Case Study

20 U.N. Comtrade Data Network

21 USA: 4.42 Germany: 4.01 Italy: 3.67 France: 3.16 Japan: 2.27 Full Network sorted equilibrium prices vertex degree price

22 European Union Network

23 USA: 4.42 Germany: 4.01 Italy: 3.67 France: 3.16 Japan: 2.27 Full NetworkEU network sorted equilibrium prices vertex degree price EU: 7.18 USA: 4.50 Japan: 2.96


Download ppt "Economic Exchange on Networks Networked Life CSE 112 Spring 2007 Prof. Michael Kearns."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google