Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets"— Presentation transcript:

1 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets
7 Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets Microeconomics P R I N C I P L E S O F N. Gregory Mankiw First, the tools introduced in this chapter (consumer & producer surplus, welfare economics) are used extensively in the real world to assess the costs and benefits of policies and market imperfections. When does a policy do more harm than good? Who does the policy make better off, and who is made worse off? How do the total gains to the winners compare to the total losses incurred by the losers? The following two chapters will use the tools of welfare economics to analyze taxes and international trade (including restrictions on trade). Students typically find these applications very interesting, and they are much easier to learn after students have a good working knowledge of the material covered in this chapter. Second, this chapter illuminates one of the most important ideas in economics: Adam Smith’s invisible hand, a.k.a. the principle that markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity. Note that this analysis assumes perfect competition. When this assumption fails, the market on its own may not maximize society’s well-being. We will study such market failures in later chapters, and we’ll use the tools of welfare economics to see how public policy can improve on the market outcome in such cases. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich

2 In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
What is consumer surplus? How is it related to the demand curve? What is producer surplus? How is it related to the supply curve? Do markets produce a desirable allocation of resources? Or could the market outcome be improved upon? 2

3 Welfare Economics Recall, the allocation of resources refers to:
how much of each good is produced which producers produce it which consumers consume it Welfare economics studies how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. First, we look at the well-being of consumers. CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 3

4 Willingness to Pay (WTP)
A buyer’s willingness to pay for a good is the maximum amount the buyer will pay for that good. WTP measures how much the buyer values the good. name WTP Anthony $250 Chad 175 Flea 300 John 125 Example: 4 buyers’ WTP for an iPod CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 4

5 WTP and the Demand Curve
Q: If price of iPod is $200, who will buy an iPod, and what is quantity demanded? A: Anthony & Flea will buy an iPod, Chad & John will not. Hence, Qd = 2 when P = $200. name WTP Anthony $250 Chad 175 Flea 300 John 125 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 5

6 WTP and the Demand Curve
Derive the demand schedule: P (price of iPod) who buys Qd $301 & up nobody 251 – 300 Flea 1 name WTP Anthony $250 Chad 175 Flea 300 John 125 176 – 250 Anthony, Flea 2 126 – 175 Chad, Anthony, Flea 3 0 – 125 John, Chad, Anthony, Flea 4 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 6

7 WTP and the Demand Curve
Qd $301 & up 251 – 300 1 176 – 250 2 126 – 175 3 0 – 125 4 Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 7

8 About the Staircase Shape…
This D curve looks like a staircase with 4 steps – one per buyer. If there were a huge # of buyers, as in a competitive market, there would be a huge # of very tiny steps, and it would look more like a smooth curve. A perfectly competitive market has a huge number of buyers. Suppose there were 10,000 buyers in the market for iPods (a tiny fraction of the actual number of buyers!). Then, the number of steps would be 10,000. In relation to the graph, each step would be insignificantly small, and the D curve would look like a smooth curve rather than a staircase – even though it really is a staircase – one with 10,000 infinitesimally small steps. Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 8

9 WTP and the Demand Curve
At any Q, the height of the D curve is the WTP of the marginal buyer, the buyer who would leave the market if P were any higher. Flea’s WTP Anthony’s WTP Chad’s WTP John’s WTP Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 9

10 Consumer Surplus (CS) CS = WTP – P
Consumer surplus is the amount a buyer is willing to pay minus the amount the buyer actually pays: CS = WTP – P Suppose P = $260. Flea’s CS = $300 – 260 = $40. The others get no CS because they do not buy an iPod at this price. Total CS = $40. name WTP Anthony $250 Chad 175 Flea 300 John 125 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 10

11 CS and the Demand Curve P Q P = $260 Flea’s CS = $300 – 260 = $40
Total CS = $40 Flea’s WTP The area of any rectangle equals base times height. For the green rectangle on this slide, base = 1 height = $300 – 260 = $40 area = 1 x $40 = $40 Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 11

12 CS and the Demand Curve P Q Instead, suppose P = $220
Flea’s CS = $300 – 220 = $80 Anthony’s CS = $250 – 220 = $30 Total CS = $110 Flea’s WTP Anthony’s WTP The entire green area (total CS) can be divided into two rectangles: The first (and leftmost) represents Flea’s CS. It has a height of $80 and a width of 1. The second represents Anthony’s CS. It has a height of $30 and a width of 1. The sum of these two rectangular areas equals total CS. Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 12

13 CS and the Demand Curve P Q The lesson:
Total CS equals the area under the demand curve above the price, from 0 to Q. Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 13

14 CS with Lots of Buyers & a Smooth D Curve
At Q = 5(thousand), the marginal buyer is willing to pay $50 for pair of shoes. Suppose P = $30. Then his consumer surplus = $20. P Q $ Price per pair The demand for shoes D 1000s of pairs of shoes CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 14

15 CS with Lots of Buyers & a Smooth D Curve
CS is the area b/w P and the D curve, from 0 to Q. Recall: area of a triangle equals ½ x base x height Height = $60 – 30 = $30. So, CS = ½ x 15 x $ = $225. P Q The demand for shoes $ h D CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 15

16 How a Higher Price Reduces CS
If P rises to $40, CS = ½ x 10 x $ = $100. Two reasons for the fall in CS. P Q 1. Fall in CS due to buyers leaving market D 2. Fall in CS due to remaining buyers paying higher P CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 16

17 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Consumer surplus
demand curve P A. Find marginal buyer’s WTP at Q = 10. B. Find CS for P = $30. $ Suppose P falls to $20. How much will CS increase due to… C. buyers entering the market D. existing buyers paying lower price Q 17

18 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 1 Answers
demand curve P A. At Q = 10, marginal buyer’s WTP is $30. B. CS = ½ x 10 x $10 = $50 $ P falls to $20. C. CS for the additional buyers = ½ x 10 x $10 = $50 D. Increase in CS on initial 10 units = 10 x $10 = $100 Q 18

19 Cost and the Supply Curve
Cost is the value of everything a seller must give up to produce a good (i.e., opportunity cost). Includes cost of all resources used to produce good, including value of the seller’s time. Example: Costs of 3 sellers in the lawn-cutting business. A seller will produce and sell the good/service only if the price exceeds his or her cost. Hence, cost is a measure of willingness to sell. name cost Jack $10 Janet 20 Chrissy 35 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 19

20 Cost and the Supply Curve
Qs Derive the supply schedule from the cost data: $0 – 9 10 – 19 1 20 – 34 2 name cost Jack $10 Janet 20 Chrissy 35 35 & up 3 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 20

21 Cost and the Supply Curve
Q P Qs $0 – 9 10 – 19 1 20 – 34 2 35 & up 3 CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 21

22 Cost and the Supply Curve
At each Q, the height of the S curve is the cost of the marginal seller, the seller who would leave the market if the price were any lower. Chrissy’s cost Janet’s cost Jack’s cost Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 22

23 Producer Surplus P Q PS = P – cost
Producer surplus (PS): the amount a seller is paid for a good minus the seller’s cost Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 23

24 Producer Surplus and the S Curve
PS = P – cost Suppose P = $25. Jack’s PS = $15 Janet’s PS = $5 Chrissy’s PS = $0 Total PS = $20 Chrissy’s cost Janet’s cost Jack’s cost Total PS equals the area above the supply curve under the price, from 0 to Q. Q CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 24

25 PS with Lots of Sellers & a Smooth S Curve
Suppose P = $40. At Q = 15(thousand), the marginal seller’s cost is $30, and her producer surplus is $10. P Q Price per pair The supply of shoes S 1000s of pairs of shoes CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 25

26 PS with Lots of Sellers & a Smooth S Curve
PS is the area b/w P and the S curve, from 0 to Q. The height of this triangle is $40 – 15 = $25. So, PS = ½ x b x h = ½ x 25 x $ = $312.50 P Q The supply of shoes S h CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 26

27 How a Lower Price Reduces PS
If P falls to $30, PS = ½ x 15 x $ = $112.50 Two reasons for the fall in PS. P Q 1. Fall in PS due to sellers leaving market S 2. Fall in PS due to remaining sellers getting lower P CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 27

28 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 2 Producer surplus
supply curve P A. Find marginal seller’s cost at Q = 10. B. Find total PS for P = $20. Suppose P rises to $30. Find the increase in PS due to… C. selling 5 additional units D. getting a higher price on the initial 10 units Q 28

29 A C T I V E L E A R N I N G 2 Answers
supply curve P A. At Q = 10, marginal cost = $20 B. PS = ½ x 10 x $20 = $100 P rises to $30. C. PS on additional units = ½ x 5 x $10 = $25 D. Increase in PS on initial 10 units = 10 x $10 = $100 Q 29

30 CS, PS, and Total Surplus CS = (value to buyers) – (amount paid by buyers) = buyers’ gains from participating in the market PS = (amount received by sellers) – (cost to sellers) = sellers’ gains from participating in the market Total surplus = CS + PS = total gains from trade in a market = (value to buyers) – (cost to sellers) CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 30

31 The Market’s Allocation of Resources
In a market economy, the allocation of resources is decentralized, determined by the interactions of many self-interested buyers and sellers. Is the market’s allocation of resources desirable? Or would a different allocation of resources make society better off? To answer this, we use total surplus as a measure of society’s well-being, and we consider whether the market’s allocation is efficient. (Policymakers also care about equality, though are focus here is on efficiency.) CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 31

32 Efficiency = (value to buyers) – (cost to sellers) Total surplus An allocation of resources is efficient if it maximizes total surplus. Efficiency means: The goods are consumed by the buyers who value them most highly. The goods are produced by the producers with the lowest costs. Raising or lowering the quantity of a good would not increase total surplus. CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 32

33 Evaluating the Market Equilibrium
Market eq’m: P = $30 Q = 15,000 Total surplus = CS + PS Is the market eq’m efficient? P Q D CS S PS CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 33

34 Which Buyers Consume the Good?
Every buyer whose WTP is ≥ $30 will buy. Every buyer whose WTP is < $30 will not. So, the buyers who value the good most highly are the ones who consume it. P Q D S CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 34

35 Which Sellers Produce the Good?
Every seller whose cost is ≤ $30 will produce the good. Every seller whose cost is > $30 will not. So, the sellers with the lowest cost produce the good. P Q D S Because the height of the S curve tells us seller’s costs, we can determine the following: The sellers of the first 15 units have cost < $30, so it is worthwhile for them to produce the good. The other sellers have cost > $30, so they will not sell the good if P = $30. CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 35

36 Does Eq’m Q Maximize Total Surplus?
At Q = 20, cost of producing the marginal unit is $35 value to consumers of the marginal unit is only $20 Hence, can increase total surplus by reducing Q. This is true at any Q greater than 15. P Q D S CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 36

37 Does Eq’m Q Maximize Total Surplus?
At Q = 10, cost of producing the marginal unit is $25 value to consumers of the marginal unit is $40 Hence, can increase total surplus by increasing Q. This is true at any Q less than 15. P Q D S CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 37

38 Does Eq’m Q Maximize Total Surplus?
The market eq’m quantity maximizes total surplus: At any other quantity, can increase total surplus by moving toward the market eq’m quantity. D S CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 38

39 Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand
Passages from The Wealth of Nations, 1776 “Man has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can interest their self-love in his favor, and show them that it is for their own advantage to do for him what he requires of them… It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest…. Adam Smith, CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 39

40 Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand
Passages from The Wealth of Nations, 1776 “Every individual…neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it…. He intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. an invisible hand Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.” Adam Smith, CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 40

41 The Free Market vs. Govt Intervention
The market equilibrium is efficient. No other outcome achieves higher total surplus. Govt cannot raise total surplus by changing the market’s allocation of resources. Laissez faire (French for “allow them to do”): the notion that govt should not interfere with the market. CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS

42 The Free Market vs. Central Planning
Suppose resources were allocated not by the market, but by a central planner who cares about society’s well-being. To allocate resources efficiently and maximize total surplus, the planner would need to know every seller’s cost and every buyer’s WTP for every good in the entire economy. This is impossible, and why centrally-planned economies are never very efficient. CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS

43 CONCLUSION This chapter used welfare economics to demonstrate one of the Ten Principles: Markets are usually a good way to organize economic activity. Important note: We derived these lessons assuming perfectly competitive markets. In other conditions we will study in later chapters, the market may fail to allocate resources efficiently… CONSUMERS, PRODUCERS, AND THE EFFICIENCY OF MARKETS 43


Download ppt "Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google