Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

COMSOC ’06 6 December 2006 Rob LeGrand

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "COMSOC ’06 6 December 2006 Rob LeGrand"— Presentation transcript:

1 Fixed-size Minimax for Committee Elections: Approximation and Local Search Heuristics
COMSOC ’06 6 December 2006 Rob LeGrand Washington University in St. Louis Evangelos Markakis University of Toronto Aranyak Mehta IBM Almaden Research Center

2 Electing a committee from approval ballots
approves of candidates 4 and 5 11110 00011 n = 5 candidates m = 6 ballots 01111 00111 10111 00001 What’s the best committee of size k = 2?

3 Sum of Hamming distances
11110 00011 k = 2 winners 2 4 4 5 01111 11000 00111 4 3 sum = 22 10111 00001

4 Fixed-size minisum Minisum elects winner set with smallest sumscore
11110 00011 k = 2 winners 4 2 1 01111 00011 00111 2 1 sum = 10 10111 00001 Minisum elects winner set with smallest sumscore Easy to compute (pick candidates with most approvals)

5 Maximum Hamming distance
11110 00011 k = 2 winners 4 2 1 01111 00011 00111 2 1 sum = 10 max = 4 10111 00001

6 [Brams, Kilgour & Sanver, ’04]
Fixed-size minimax [Brams, Kilgour & Sanver, ’04] 11110 00011 k = 2 winners 2 2 2 1 01111 00110 00111 2 3 sum = 12 max = 3 10111 00001 Minimax elects winner set with smallest maxscore Harder to compute?

7 (generalization of EM)
Complexity Endogenous minimax = EM = BSM(0, n) Bounded-size minimax = BSM(k1, k2) Fixed-size minimax = FSM(k) = BSM(k, k) NP-hard [Frances & Litman, ’97] (generalization of EM) ?

8 (generalization of EM)
Complexity Endogenous minimax = EM = BSM(0, n) Bounded-size minimax = BSM(k1, k2) Fixed-size minimax = FSM(k) = BSM(k, k) NP-hard [Frances & Litman, ’97] (generalization of EM) (this paper)

9 no known constant-factor approx.
Approximability Endogenous minimax = EM = BSM(0, n) Bounded-size minimax = BSM(k1, k2) Fixed-size minimax = FSM(k) = BSM(k, k) has a PTAS* [Li, Ma & Wang, ’99] no known PTAS; no known constant-factor approx. * Polynomial-Time Approximation Scheme: algorithm with approx. ratio 1 + ε that runs in time polynomial in the input and exponential in 1/ε

10 Approximability has a PTAS* has a 3-approx. no known PTAS;
Endogenous minimax = EM = BSM(0, n) Bounded-size minimax = BSM(k1, k2) Fixed-size minimax = FSM(k) = BSM(k, k) has a PTAS* [Li, Ma & Wang, ’99] no known PTAS; has a 3-approx. (this paper) * Polynomial-Time Approximation Scheme: algorithm with approx. ratio 1 + ε that runs in time polynomial in the input and exponential in 1/ε

11 Approximating FSM 11110 k = 2 winners 00011 00111 00111 00001 choose
a ballot arbitrarily 10111 01111

12 Approximating FSM 11110 k = 2 winners 00011 00111 coerce to size k
00101 00001 choose a ballot arbitrarily 10111 01111 outcome = k-completed ballot

13 Approximation ratio ≤ 3 optimal FSM set 11110 2 00011 2 1 00111 00110
00001 2 10111 2 01111 ≤ OPT OPT = optimal maxscore

14 Approximation ratio ≤ 3 optimal FSM set chosen ballot 11110 2 00011 2
00111 1 00110 00111 3 00001 2 10111 2 01111 ≤ OPT ≤ OPT OPT = optimal maxscore

15 (by triangle inequality)
Approximation ratio ≤ 3 optimal FSM set chosen ballot k-completed ballot 11110 2 00011 2 1 00111 1 1 00110 00111 00011 3 00001 2 10111 2 01111 ≤ OPT ≤ OPT ≤ OPT (by triangle inequality) OPT = optimal maxscore ≤ 3·OPT

16 Better in practice? So far, we can guarantee a winner set no more than 3 times as bad as the optimal. Nice in theory . . . How can we do better in practice? Try local search

17 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k 01001 4

18 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k In c, swap up to r 0-bits with 1-bits in such a way that minimizes the maxscore of the result 11000 10001 5 4 01100 01001 00101 4 4 4 01010 00011 4 4

19 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k In c, swap up to r 0-bits with 1-bits in such a way that minimizes the maxscore of the result 01010 4

20 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k In c, swap up to r 0-bits with 1-bits in such a way that minimizes the maxscore of the result 01010 4

21 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k In c, swap up to r 0-bits with 1-bits in such a way that minimizes the maxscore of the result Repeat step 2 until maxscore(c) is unchanged n times Take c as the solution 11000 10010 5 4 01100 01010 00110 4 4 3 01001 00011 4 4

22 Local search approach for FSM
Start with some c  {0,1}n of weight k In c, swap up to r 0-bits with 1-bits in such a way that minimizes the maxscore of the result Repeat step 2 until maxscore(c) is unchanged n times Take c as the solution 00110 3

23 Specific FSM heuristics
Two parameters: where to start vector c: a fixed-size-minisum solution a k-completion of a ballot (3-approx.) a random set of k candidates a k-completion of a ballot with highest maxscore radius of neighborhood r: 1 and 2

24 Heuristic evaluation Real-world ballots from GTS 2003 council election
Found exact minimax solution Ran each heuristic 5000 times Compared exact minimax solution with heuristics to find realized approximation ratios example: 15/14 = maxscore of solution found = 15 maxscore of exact solution = 14 We also performed experiments using ballots generated according to random distributions (see paper)

25 Average approx. ratios found
radius = 1 radius = 2 fixed-size minimax 1.0012 1.0000 3-approx. 1.0017 random set 1.0057 highest-maxscore 1.0059 performance on GTS ’03 election data n = 24 candidates, k = 12 winners, m = 161 ballots

26 Largest approx. ratios found
radius = 1 radius = 2 fixed-size minimax 1.0714 1.0000 3-approx. random set highest-maxscore performance on GTS ’03 election data n = 24 candidates, k = 12 winners, m = 161 ballots

27 Conclusions from all experiments
All heuristics perform near-optimally highest ratio found: 1.2 highest average ratio < 1.04 When radius is larger, performance improves and running time increases The fixed-size-minisum starting point performs best overall (with our 3-approx. a close second)

28 Manipulating FSM Voters are sincere Another optimal solution: 00101
00110 00011 2 2 1 01111 00011 00111 2 1 max = 2 10111 00001 Voters are sincere Another optimal solution: 00101

29 Manipulating FSM A voter manipulates and realizes ideal outcome 00110
11110 00011 2 2 2 1 01111 00110 00111 2 3 max = 3 10111 00001 A voter manipulates and realizes ideal outcome

30 Nonmanipulable “FSM”? Electing a set found using our 3-approximation for FSM gives a nonmanipulable procedure: For the voters whose ballots are not chosen, voting insincerely cannot affect the outcome For the voter whose ballot is chosen, the outcome will be one of the sets of size k closest to the voter’s wishes

31 Both can be approximated with ratio 3
Conclusions BSM and FSM are NP-hard Both can be approximated with ratio 3 Polynomial-time local search heuristics perform well in practice some retain ratio-3 guarantee Exact FSM can be manipulated Our 3-approximation for FSM is nonmanipulable

32 Future work Investigate weighted version of minimax [Brams, Kilgour & Sanver, ’06] What is the best approximation ratio for FSM achievable in polynomial time? (Is there a PTAS?) What is the nonmanipulable FSM approximation algorithm with the best ratio? Thanks!


Download ppt "COMSOC ’06 6 December 2006 Rob LeGrand"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google