Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 13.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 13."— Presentation transcript:

1 Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 13

2 Last week… Formation defenses Performance excuses Concepts
Incompetence Duress, necessity Adhesion, unconscionability (lesion) Fraud, failure to disclose Mutual mistake But not unilateral mistake Performance excuses Impossibility Frustration of purpose Concepts Efficient bearer (low cost avoider) of a risk Uniting knowledge and control

3 Remedies for breach of contract
That’s all for ways to invalidate a contract. Next, we’ll consider the remedies that are available when a contract is breached.

4 Three broad types of remedy for breach of contract
Party-designed remedies Remedies specified in the contract Court-imposed damages Court may decide promisee entitled to some level of damages Specific performance Forces breaching party to live up to contract There are three general types of remedies for breach of contract: party-designed remedies court-imposed damages specific performance Party-designed remedies are remedies specified in the contract for a particular scenario for example, a construction contract might stipulate a particular daily fee if completion of the building is delayed Court-imposed damages are what we’ve already been talking about the court may rule that the promisee is entitled to some amount of money as compensation for the breach The third alternative is for the court to require specific performance This forces the breaching party to live up to the contract This is what the dissenting opinion in Peevyhouse proposed Rather than calculating money damages, they said the coal company should be required to actually carry out the restorative work as promised. Remedies that are stipulated in the contract are fairly clear-cut although we’ll come to an example of some that are often not enforced Specific performance is also fairly clean, although we’ll discuss it a bit more later today The difficult one is when the court has to step in and calculate the appropriate level of monetary damages There are a number of different standards which can be used for this

5 Expectation damages Compensate promisee for the amount he expected to benefit from performance You agreed to buy an airplane for $350,000 You expected $500,000 of benefit from it Expectation damages: if I breach, I owe you that benefit ($500,000 if you already paid, $150,000 if you didn’t) “Positive damages” Make promisee indifferent between performance and breach We’ve already seen one: expectation damages. Expectation damages are meant to compensate the promisee for the amount he expected to benefit from performance of the promise Recall the airplane example we did a while back you contracted to buy an airplane from me for $350,000 you expected to derive $500,000 of benefit from it under expectation damages, I would owe you that benefit ($500,000 if you had already paid me, or $500,000 - $350,000 = $150,000 if you had not.) The civil law refers to these as positive damages, as they compensate you for the positive benefit you anticipated from the contract When they are calculated correctly, expectation damages make the promisee indifferent about whether the promisor performs or breaches Thus, under expectation damages, the promisor internalizes all the costs of breach, and therefore makes the efficient decision about breach.

6 Reliance damages Reimburse promisee for cost of any reliance investments made, but not for additional surplus he expected to gain Restore promisee to level of well-being before he signed the contract You contracted to buy the plane and built a hangar If I breach, I owe you what you spent on the hangar, nothing else “Negative damages” – undo the negative (harm) that occurred A second type of damages are reliance damages These compensate the promisee for any investments he made in reliance on the promise, but not for the additional surplus he expected to gain Reliance damages, therefore, restore the promisee to the level of well-being he would have had if he had not received the promise in the first place In the airplane example, suppose I chose not to deliver the plane but you had built yourself a hangar Reliance damages would require me to reimburse you the cost of the hangar, but not the surplus you expected to earn from owning the plane In the rich uncle example – the rich uncle promises his nephew a trip around the world, then changes his mind – reliance damages would pay for whatever supplies the nephew had purchased in preparation for the trip, minus whatever price he could resell them for Again, this puts the promisee back in the position he was in before the promise was made The civil law tradition refers to these as negative damages, as they undo the negative (the harm) that actually occurred in response to the promise If no investments were made in reliance on the promise, reliance damages would be 0 – sort of a “no harm, no foul” rule.

7 Opportunity cost damages
Give promisee benefit he would have gotten from his next-best option Make promisee indifferent between breach of the contract that was signed, and performance of best alternative contract You value plane at $500,000 You contract to buy plane from me for $350,000 Someone else was selling similar plane for $400,000 By the time I breach, that plane is no longer available I owe you $100,000 – the benefit you would have gotten from buying the other seller’s plane A third type of damages are opportunity cost damages If you agree to buy a plane from me, you may pass up another chance to buy a plane from someone else But if I breach our contract, that other option may no longer be available Opportunity cost damages are set to restore the promisee to the level of well-being he would have had if he had not contracted with this promisor, and instead had gone with his “next-best option” Opportunity cost damages can be seen as an extension of reliance damages, where now turning down another opportunity is seen as a form of reliance, that is, as an investment you make in reliance on the promise that was made Thus, opportunity cost damages leave the promisee indifferent between breach of the contract that was signed and fulfillment of the best alternative contract In the airplane example, you contracted to buy a plane worth $500,000 for $350,000 Suppose someone else had an equally attractive airplane for sale at $400,000 If I breach our contract, opportunity cost damages would be $100,000, since this is the surplus you would have realized by foregoing the contract with me and instead buying the other plane

8 Example: expectation, reliance, and opportunity cost damages
You agree to sell me ticket to Wisconsin-Michigan football game for $50 Expectation damages: you owe me value of game minus $50 If I pay scalper $150, then expectation damages = $100 Reliance damages: maybe 0, or cost of face paint and giant foam finger An example I decide I want to go to the Michigan game in a few weeks One of you has a roommate with an extra ticket, and so you agree to sell it to me for $50 At the last minute, your roommate decides to go to the game, and you breach your promise. Expectation damages are supposed to make me as well-off as if you had indeed sold me the ticket for $50 It may be hard to measure exactly how well-off the football game would have made me But once you tell me my ticket is gone, I could show up at the stadium before the game and buy a ticket from a scalper Say this costs $150 This gives us an easy way to compute expectation damages If you had lived up to your promise, I’d be $100 better off, because I’d have gotten the same good (a ticket) for $50 instead of for $150 So expectation damages might be set at $100. Now consider reliance damages for the same contract Going to a football game doesn’t involve a lot of substantial investments It’s possible reliance damages would be 0 If I had already gone out and bought red-and-white face paint and a big foam finger, reliance damages might reimburse me for these purchases But reliance damages would not compensate me for the benefit I expected to get.

9 Example: expectation, reliance, and opportunity cost damages
You agree to sell me ticket to Wisconsin-Michigan football game for $50 Expectation damages: you owe me value of game minus $50 If I pay scalper $150, then expectation damages = $100 Reliance damages: maybe 0, or cost of face paint and giant foam finger When you agreed to sell me ticket, other tickets available for $70 Opportunity cost damages: $80 (I paid a scalper $150 to get in; I would have been $80 better off if I’d ignored your offer and paid someone else $70) Finally, suppose when we made the deal, there were lots of people offering tickets on Craigslist for $70 By the time you breach, these tickets were gone, so all I could do was pay a scalper $150 for a ticket The actual payoff I got was G – 150, where G is the value of attending the game If I had signed the best alternative contract, my payoff would have been G – 70 So while the contract we signed would have made me $100 better off, the best alternative would have made me $80 better off Opportunity cost damages, then, would be set at $80, to compensate me for having passed on that opportunity. Also note that these are all remedies for seller breach We could calculate what I would owe you if I changed my mind and decided not to go to the game – that is, the remedy for buyer breach – in the analogous way. In this example, a ticket to a football game is a good with many substitutes That is, there are lots of tickets to the game, and they’re all worth about the same amount So it made sense to calculate damages based on the market price of a replacement ticket When a contract is for a unique good, this doesn’t always work; but conceptually, the analysis is almost the same.

10 ³ ³ = = = ³ ³ ³ ³ Ranking damages $100 $80 $0-20 Contract I Sign
Best Alternative Do Nothing = = = Breach + Expectation Damages Breach + Opportunity Cost Damages Breach + Reliance Damages In this example, Expectation Damages >= Opportunity Cost Damages >= Reliance Damages It turns out, as long as all three are computed correctly, this should always be true The reason is simple. If I am rational and choose to sign a particular contract, it must be because that contract is at least as good for me as my best alternative Of course, doing nothing is always an option, so it stands to reason that both the contract I sign, and the next best alternative, are at least as good as doing nothing So from the point of view of my utility, Contract I sign >= Best Alternative >= Doing Nothing Following breach, expectation damages restore me to the value of performance of the contract I signed opportunity cost damages restore me to the value of performance of the next-best alternative reliance damages restore me to the value of having done nothing So Breach + Expectation Damages >= Breach + Opp Cost Damages >= Breach + Reliance D If we subtract off the value of the breached contract in each case, we see that (Of course, damages are not always calculated perfectly, so there may be instances in which this is violated. We’ll see examples of this next time.) Expectation Damages Opportunity Cost Damages Reliance Damages $100 $80 $0-20

11 Hawkins v McGee (“hairy hand case”)
Hawkins had a scar on his hand McGee promised surgery to “make the hand a hundred percent perfect” Surgery was a disaster, left scar bigger and covered with hair In the examples so far – the airplane, and the football ticket – we could use market prices to calculate damages In some situations, the value of a contract is subjective, making things a bit harder Still, the principle is the same, it’s just a question of how to actually do the calculation. A dramatic example of this is a 1929 case from New Hampshire, Hawkins v McGee, “the hairy hand case.” George Hawkins had a scar on his hand from touching an electrical wire when he was young A local doctor, McGee, approached him about having the scar removed, and promised to “make the hand a hundred percent perfect hand.” Skin from Hawkins’ chest was grafted onto his hand But the surgery was a disaster: the scar ended up bigger than before, and covered with hair Hawkins successfully sued McGee; the issue on appeal was how high to set the damages. To get a view of what’s going on, consider Hawkins’ preferences over two types of goods: his hand, and money. (Indifference curves.)

12 Hawkins v McGee (“hairy hand case”)
$ + Expectation Damages + Opp Cost Damages Expectation Damages Reliance Damages Opp Cost Damages + Reliance Damages Initial Wealth To get a view of what’s going on, consider Hawkins’ preferences over two types of goods: his hand, and money. He could have a scar on his hand; a perfect hand; he could have gone to a different doctor who promised him improvement but not perfection; and he could have the hairy hand he had after surgery. Indifference curves. Hawkins started out at the red dot – with a scarred hand, and some initial amount of money. The doctor promised him the green dot – a perfect hand (but less money, since he would have to pay for the surgery) Now he’s stuck with a hairy hand. And about to get more money (damages). Reliance damages would get him back to the same level of well-being as before The next-best doctor might have gotten him to the orange dot – a pretty good hand. Opportunity cost damages would get him to the level of well-being he would have had by going to the next-best-doctor Expectation damages would get him to the level of well-being he expected from the successful operation. (Of course, there is still the question of how to calculate these indifference curves, since they are clearly subjective There is also the question of whether it even makes sense to think that money can compensate for something like a disfiguring injury But this is at least the principle.) Once again, we see that the promised benefit (performance) is better than the next-best option, which is better than doing nothing So expectation damages are bigger than opportunity cost damages, which are bigger than reliance damages This ranking should hold whenever all three damage levels are calculated correctly Hand Hairy Scarred Next best doctor 100% Perfect

13 Recapping different types of damages
Expectation damages Give promisee benefit he would have had from performance Opportunity cost damages Give promisee benefit he would have had from next-best contract Reliance damages Give promisee benefit he would have had from doing nothing Expectation Dam ³ Opp Cost Dam ³ Reliance Dam But order can be reversed when calculated incorrectly We saw that the promised benefit (performance) is better than the next-best option which is better than doing nothing So expectation damages are bigger than opportunity cost damages, which are bigger than reliance damages This ranking should hold whenever all three damage levels are calculated correctly However, there are instances when this may not occur, leading to a different ranking The book gives an example where someone promises to deliver to me a tiny diamond from my great-grandmother’s engagement ring The diamond is very small, and worth very little objectively, but it has a great sentimental value to me In anticipation of receiving it, I commission a very expensive setting for the stone I’m motivated by sentimental value, but the market value of the ring, even with the stone, is less than its cost Now, after I’ve bought and paid for the setting, the promisor breaches. Expectation damages should get me back to the level of well-being I expected to be at with the diamond But that level is based on a high subjective valuation A court could refuse to enforce that level of damages, and instead base expectation damages on the market value of the ring in its setting But this could be less than the price I paid for the setting On the other hand, reliance damages would at least reimburse me the cost of the setting In a sense, this is what happened in Peevyhouse The Peevyhouses’ subjective valuation for their farm, in its original condition, appeared to be very high The court refused to base damages on this subjective value, instead limiting damages to the reduction in market value, which was only $300

14 Other court-ordered remedies
Restitution Return money that was already received Disgorgement Give up wrongfully-gained profits There are three other types of damages that are sometimes ordered, which aren’t all that interesting, but are worth knowing. Restitution is basically just forcing someone to pay back whatever money they’ve already received I contract to buy a house and make a down payment The seller breaches If nothing else, he is required to return my down payment This is sort of a minimal remedy, but it at least is very easy to implement. Disgorgement is a similar concept, requiring someone to give up whatever profits they have wrongfully gained Directors of a corporation have a duty to stockholders to act in a certain way This is a very vague duty, not a list of specific things they are required to do Suppose a director acts in a disloyal way, which is costly to the company but profitable to himself Disgorgement damages would require the director to give up whatever profits he earned to the victim, in this case, the stockholders Perfect disgorgement damages take away the director’s incentive to commit fraud

15 Other court-ordered remedies
Restitution Return money that was already received Disgorgement Give up wrongfully-gained profits Specific Performance Promisor is forced to honor promise Civil law: often ordered instead of money damages Common law: money damages more common; S.P. sometimes used when seller breaches contract to sell a unique good Like injunctive relief Specific Performance is when, instead of ordering money damages, the court orders the promisor to live up to the promise I contract to buy a particular house from you It’s a beautiful house, in a historical neighborhood, and there are no others like it available After we sign an agreement, you find a more eager buyer, and try to breach our agreement The court might order you to follow through with the sale to me – this would be specific performance In some civil law countries, specific performance rather than monetary damages is the traditional remedy for breach of contract In common law, when a good has substitutes, money damages are traditionally the remedy, since the promisee can use that money to buy a substitute good if he so chooses Specific performance is sometimes ruled for sale of goods without any substitutes Specific performance can also be seen as an analog to injunctive relief in property law – your promise now belongs to me, so you’re not allowed to get out of it unless I choose to release you

16 Other court-ordered remedies
Restitution Return money that was already received Disgorgement Give up wrongfully-gained profits Specific Performance Promisor is forced to honor promise Civil law: often ordered instead of money damages Common law: money damages more common; S.P. sometimes used when seller breaches contract to sell a unique good Like injunctive relief Specific performance is also a sensible remedy choice when it is very difficult for the court to compute the appropriate level of damages For example, when the valuation of the good is very subjective This is what the dissenting opinion in Peevyhouse suggested The Peevyhouses’ subjective valuation for their property in its original condition was clearly high, and hard to assess Rather than take a stab at computing damages, the dissent would have ordered the coal company to clean up its mess as promised As always, the two sides could have then negotiated around the ruling if transaction costs were low Of course, specific performance is sometimes impossible In the Hawkins case, it was impossible for the doctor to undo the damage to Hawkins’ hand, much less restore it to the promised level So only monetary damages were sensible

17 Party-designed remedies
Remedy for breach could be written directly into contract But common law courts don’t always enforce remedy terms Liquidated damages – party-specified damages that reasonably approximate actual harm done by breach Penalty damages – damages greater than actual harm done Civil law courts are generally willing to enforce penalty damages But common law courts often do not We mentioned that in some cases, the remedy for breach can be built directly into the contract Some contracts stipulate an amount of money that a party would have to pay if he were to breach the contract Others might specify a “performance bond” – an amount of money deposited with a third party, that would be paid to the promisee upon breach Or a contract might specify a different process for resolving any disputes, such as agreeing to submit to binding arbitration or some other process (This is what happens with disputes among diamond merchants, which are never resolved in court.) For some reason, courts are often hesitant to enforce remedy terms in contracts Rather than enforce the contract as written, courts sometimes set aside remedy clauses and impose their own remedies One type of remedy that courts will often refuse to enforce is penalty damages Penalty damages are damages that are greater than the actual harm that occurred (“Liquidated damages” refer to party-specified damages that are a reasonable estimate of the actual harm done by the breach; penalty damages are any damages that are greater than that) Civil law courts generally enforce penalty damages But common law courts often set aside penalty damages, and only enforce liquidated damages

18 Penalty Damages Peevyhouse v Garland Coal
Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Penalty Damages Peevyhouse v Garland Coal Peevyhouses only wanted farm strip-mined if it would be restored to original condition after Suppose coal extracted worth $70,000 Garland paid $25,000 for rights to mine it Restoration work would cost $30,000 Diminution of value was $300 So liquidated damages would be $300 Suppose Peevyhouses got $40,000 of disutility from land being left in poor condition It’s unfortunate that penalty clauses are often not enforced, because they could be useful in some instances In particular, they could be helpful when one party to a contract places a high subjective value on performance Go back to coal mining example we saw earlier, Peevyhouse v Garland Coal The Peevyhouses only wanted their farm strip-mined if the land could be restored to its original condition They seemed to value the condition of their farm much more highly than “market value” Had they known the coal company would refuse to perform the restoration work, and instead only pay them damages, they might have refused to agree to the contract in the first place We can illustrate this with a simple dynamic game Suppose the coal extracted was worth $70,000 (net of costs), and Garland Coal agreed to pay $25,000 to mine it Recall that restoration work would have cost around $30,000, but damages for refusing to do it were assessed at $300 Suppose that the Peevyhouses got $40,000 of disutility from the land not being restored

19 Liquidated damages If damages limited to liquidated damages…
Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Liquidated damages Peevyhouses Sign Don’t Garland Coal (0, 0) Restore property Don’t, pay damages (25,000, 15,000) (-14,700, 44,700) If damages limited to liquidated damages… Peevyhouses have no reason to believe restorative work will get done So Peevyhouses better off refusing to sign Even though mining and restoring Pareto-dominates

20 Penalty damages If penalty clauses in contracts enforceable…
Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Penalty damages Peevyhouses Sign Don’t Garland Coal (0, 0) Restore property Don’t, pay penalty One way to address this in a contract would have been to write into the contract a $40,000 penalty in the event that the restorative work was not completed If this was enforceable, it would ensure that the mining company followed through with the restorative work That is, it would change the game to this: Now, the Peevyhouses are assured of getting their land restored So they’re happy to agree to the contract But, if common law courts don’t uphold penalty clauses, this won’t work Another example: suppose you’re hiring a contractor to build a house, and you place a very high value on its being completed by a particular date You are happy to pay $200,000 to get the house built, but insist on a $50,000 penalty if it’s not ready on that date Now suppose there are lots of contractors who could potentially build the house If you offer this deal to lots of them, the ones who accept are likely the ones who are most confident in their ability to finish the house on time Since you value this highly, this may be efficient And this may be the easiest (or the only) way for you to elicit this information If there is no penalty clause, every contractor will try to convince you he’s 100% certain he’ll finish on time But if someone accepts the $50,000 penalty clause, they’re probably pretty sure (25,000, 15,000) (25,000, 5,000) If penalty clauses in contracts enforceable… Write contract with $40,000 penalty for leaving land unrestored Now restoration work would get done, so Peevyhouses willing to sign But if courts won’t enforce penalty damages, this won’t work

21 Penalty clauses Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a $50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000 performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem! So in some instances, penalty damages seem beneficial Especially if one party would not agree to a mutually beneficial contract without them So it seems like the fact that they’re not enforced is a problem However, it turns out, most things you could accomplish with penalties, you could restate in a different way with a performance bonus Go back to the house-building example I’m happy to pay $200,000 to get the house built by a certain date But I insist on a $50,000 penalty if it’s not ready on time We could alternatively write the contract this way: I pay $150,000 for the building of the house And I pay an additional $50,000 performance bonus if the house is completed by a certain date Courts generally have no problem enforcing contracts with bonuses in them, so this would likely be enforced as written But it has the same effect as the contract with the penalty (Under either contract, the builder gets $200,000 for finishing the house on time, and $150,000 for finishing it late.)

22 Penalty clauses Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a $50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000 performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem! Similarly, Peevyhouse example Peevyhouses get $25,000 for mining rights, $40,000 penalty if land is not restored Equivalently, get $65,000 for mining rights, pay $40,000 bonus if restoration is completed But, if intent of contract is too transparent, still might not be enforced Similarly, go back to the Peevyhouse example Instead of a $40,000 penalty that might not be upheld, the Peevyhouse contract also could have been rewritten as a bonus We imagined that Garland paid $25,000 to mine the coal Suppose the contract were written in this way: Garland pays the Peevyhouses $65,000 to mine the coal The Peevyhouses pay Garland a $40,000 bonus if the resoration work is completed This would create exactly the same incentives as a $40,000 penalty clause (In this case, though, the intent of the contract might have been so transparent that it still might not have been enforced)

23 Effects of different remedies on…. decision to perform or breach
Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance

24 Costs High – Renegotiate
Plane worth $500,000 to you Price $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 Remedies and breach Expectation Damages Specific Performance Costs Low – Perform Costs High – Perform Costs High – Breach Costs Low – Perform Costs High – Perform Costs High – Renegotiate I get 100,000 -650,000 -150,000 I get 100,000 -650,000 -400,000 You get 150,000 150,000 150,000 You get 150,000 150,000 400,000 For example, let’s compare a contract enforced by specific performance – the promisor is not allowed to breach unless the promisee agrees – versus a promise enforced by expectation damages Let’s stick with the example of the airplane I agreed to build for you The plane will give you a value of $500,000; we agree on a price of $350,000 I expect the plane to cost me $250,000 to build, but there is some chance it will instead cost me $1,000,000 Expectation damages Specific performance by renegotiating the contract, we create a total surplus of $500,000 (beyond our outside options if you forced me to build the plane) Suppose that our negotiations lead us to divide this additional surplus evenly This would lead you to get $250,000 beyond your outside option, which was $150,000, so your payoff would be $400,000 I would get $250,000 beyond my outside option, which was -650,000, which would be -400,000 (So this means, in return for getting out of the contract, I pay you $400,000) As long as transaction costs are low, either remedy will lead to the same outcome When it is efficient to breach, expectation damages lead me to breach without permission Under specific performance, when it is efficient to breach, renegotiation will lead us to some sort of agreement to let me off the hook. But when the transaction costs of renegotiating our contract are too high… Expectation damages still allow me to breach Specific performance would lead to inefficient performance I would have to build you the plane, even though it costs me more than your benefit Total 250,000 -500,000 Total 250,000 -500,000 Transaction costs low  either leads to efficient breach, but seller prefers “weaker” remedy Transaction costs high  S.P. leads to ineff. performance

25 Remedies and breach Opportunity cost damages, or reliance damages
Inefficient breach when transaction costs are high Renegotiate contract to get efficient performance when transaction costs are low Like nuisance law: any remedy leads to efficient breach with low TC But only expectation damages do when TC are high Unfortunate contingency and fortunate contingency We can do the same type of analysis with other types of damages – opportunity cost damages, or reliance damages With high transaction costs, either of these would lead to inefficient breach – sometimes, I would choose to breach, even when that’s inefficient With low transaction costs, when performance is efficient but I would otherwise choose to breach, we can simply renegotiate the contract and get performance So just like in nuisance law, any remedy leads to efficient performance when transaction costs are low But only expectation damages do it without renegotiation; and only expectation damages get efficient breach even when transaction costs are high An increase in the cost of performance is referred to as an unfortunate contingency On the other hand, I may want to break my promise because I discover another buyer who values my product more than you do This is referred to as a fortunate contingency Earlier, we saw the example where you contracted to buy my painting, but my rich cousin appeared and valued it much more highly than you did We can do the same exercise as before with the different remedies, and see the same thing With low transaction costs, any remedy will lead to efficient breach, but with different allocations of surplus An example of this is done in the textbook (p. 267) Once again, specific performance is the most advantageous to the buyer, and higher damages are better for the buyer than lower damages.

26 Efficient signing Specific Performance
If costs stay low, I get $350,000 - $250,000 = $100,000 profit If costs rise, I take $400,000 loss Am I willing to sign this contract? Even expectation damages face this problem Expectation damages: costs stay low, same $100,000 profit Costs rise, $150,000 loss If probability of high costs is ½, I won’t sign contract Expectation damages lead to efficient breach, but may not lead to efficient signing Suggests expectation damages might be good default rule, but not good mandatory rule One further point that we mentioned earlier but didn’t talk much about: efficient signing. With specific performance, in the example above, we saw that when costs stay low and I perform, I get a profit of $100,000 (the price you pay, $350, minus the costs I incur, $250) When costs rise and I need to renegotiate to get out of the contract, if gains from trade were split evenly, I would take a $400,000 loss Which begs the question: would I have been willing to sign this contract in the first place? It turns out, expectation damages face this problem too When my costs remain low and I perform, I get the same profit of $100,000 And when my costs jump up and I breach, I owe $150,000 (expectation damages) If the probability my costs rise is small enough, that’s no big deal I take the risk of owing you expectation damages, because my profits in the cases where I don’t breach are large enough that it’s worth the risk. But if the probability my costs rise is high, then my expected profit from this contract is negative For example, suppose the probability of a dramatic rise in costs is ½ Then my expected payoffs from agreeing to build you the airplane are ½ (100,000) + ½ (-150,000) = -25,000 So now there’s no way I’d agree to the contract in the first place This is the point we mentioned before: Expectation damages lead to efficient breach, but they may lead to inefficient signing (If I’m the only airplane manufacturer available, it’s still efficient for us to sign this contract – it generates positive expected surplus – but under expectation damages, I would not sign this contract.) This suggests that, even if expectation damages make a sensible default rule, it’s efficient for parties to be able to specify a different damages rule in the contract That is, even if expectation damages are often efficient, they are not always efficient, so there’s no reason for them to be mandatory

27 Effects of different remedies on…. decision to perform or breach
Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance

28 Paradox of compensation
Remedy for breach sets incentive for both promisor and promisee Promisor: perform or breach Promisee: how much to rely Generally impossible to set both incentives efficiently at the same time Example: should anticipated benefit from reliance be included in expectation damages?

29 Incentives for reliance (airplane example)
Plane worth $500,000 to you Price $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 $x investment  600Öx increase in value of performance Incentives for reliance (airplane example) Additional value of plane Designer hangar with Starbucks - $480,000 Functional heating - $240,000 Metal poles, rigid roof - $120,000 Plywood frame, canvas roof - $60,000 Tarp and rope - $6,000 benefit Investment in hangar $100 $10,000 $40,000 $160,000 $640,000

30 Three questions Let p be probability of breach Three questions
Plane worth $500,000 to you Price $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 $x investment  600Öx increase in value of performance Three questions Let p be probability of breach Three questions What is the efficient level of reliance? What will promisee do if expectation damages include anticipated benefit from reliance? What will promisee do if expectation damages exclude anticipated benefit from reliance?

31 Three questions Let p be probability of breach Three questions
Plane worth $500,000 to you Price $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 $x investment  600Öx increase in value of performance Three questions Let p be probability of breach Three questions What is the efficient level of reliance? x = $90,000 (1 – p)2 What will promisee do if expectation damages include anticipated benefit from reliance? x = $90,000 What will promisee do if expectation damages exclude anticipated benefit from reliance? Total social gain when costs stay low: 500, sqrt(x) – 250,000 – x Total social gain when costs go up: – x If probability costs rise is p, expected total social gain is (1-p) (250, sqrt(x) – x) + p (-x) 250,000 (1-p) (1-p) sqrt(x) – x Choose x to maximize this: derivative is 600 (1-p) /(2sqrt(x)) – 1 = 0 x = 90,000 (1 – p)2 x = 90,000 (1 – p)2 is the efficient level of reliance When expectation damages include anticipated benefit, private gain to promisee when costs stay low: 500, sqrt(x) – 350,000 – x = 150, sqrt(x) – x Private gain to promisee when costs go up: 150, sqrt(x) – x Expected private gain to promisee is 150, sqrt(x) – x Choose x to maximize this: derivative is 600/(2Öx) – 1 = 0 x = 90,000 So promisee would invest x = $90,000 in reliance When expectation damages exclude anticipated benefit, Private gain to promisee when costs stay low: 500, sqrt(x) – 350,000 – x = 150, sqrt(x) – x Private gain to promisee when costs go up: 150,000 – x Expected private gain to promisee is 150,000 + (1 – p) 600 sqrt(x) – x Choose x to maximize this: derivative is 600 (1 – p)/(2sqrt(x)) – 1 = 0 So promisee would invest x = $90,000 (1-p)2 in reliance

32 So… To get efficient reliance, we need to exclude gains from reliance in calculation of expectation damages But then promisor’s liability < promisee’s benefit, leading to inefficient breach With low transaction costs, we can fix this through renegotiation But what about unobservable actions the promisor needs to take, to make breach less likely? Investment in performance So if damages include the gains from reliance, this leads to overreliance But if the level of damages excludes the gains from reliance, this leads to efficient reliance But we also know that if the level of damages exclude the gains from reliance, and the buyer relies anyway, that this will lead to inefficient breach That is, since the seller’s liability from breach is lower than the buyer’s gain from performance, there will be some instances where the seller breaches even though efficiency requires performance We said before that with no transaction costs, this problem can be solved When breach would be inefficient, the parties can contract around it Since it’s generally very clear whether a party has breached a contract or not, this shouldn’t be a particular problem. However, there are situations in which a promisor can take actions to make performance less costly Or, to put it another way, to lessen the probability that breach is necessary A contractor could buy raw materials ahead of time, to avoid the risk of changing prices A manufacturer could start a project earlier and frontload the labor to avoid the risk of a strike If a project were to require a building permit or zoning easement, he could lobby the local government (or bribe someone) to decrease the chances of hitting a snag. This sort of investment in performance, however, may be unobservable, or unverifiable So even when this sort of investment is efficient, it may be very hard to build it into the contract (It’s very hard to enforce a contract specifying “how hard I have to try” to convince the zoning board to approve your project.) So investment in performance may only occur when it is in the promisor’s best interest

33 Effects of different remedies on…. decision to perform or breach
Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance

34 Investment in performance (continuing with airplane example)
Some investment I can make to reduce likelihood that breach becomes necessary Suppose probability of breach is initially ½… but for every $27,726 I invest, I cut the probability in half Invest nothing  probability of breach is 1/2 Invest $27,726  probability is 1/4 Invest $55,452  probability is 1/8 Any investment z  probability is .5 * (.5) z / 27,726 Wrote it this way so p = .5 e – z / 40,000 We’ll stick with the airplane example Suppose there is some investment I can take that reduces the chance that my costs go up I can buy some of my supplies ahead of time This will reduce the risk of having to breach But I can’t completely insulate myself from risk Suppose that for each $27,726 I invest, I can reduce the probability I will need to breach by ½ That is, if I invest $27,726, the probability of breach goes from ½ to ¼ If I invest another $27,726, it goes down to 1/8 And so on For any investment z, then, we can write the probability that breach is still required as ½ * ½ ^(z / 27,726) The reason I chose the number 27,726 is that we can rewrite this probability as ½ e^{- z/40,000) which makes it much easier to work with.

35 Investment in performance (continuing with airplane example)
Suppose you’ve built a $90,000 hangar Increases value of performance by $180,000… …so value of performance is $150,000 + $180,000 = $330,000 Probability of breach = .5 e – z/40,000 Let D = damages I owe if I breach Same questions as before: What is efficient level of investment in performance? How much will I choose to invest in performance?

36 Investment in performance (continuing with airplane example)
Suppose you’ve built a $90,000 hangar Increases value of performance by $180,000… …so value of performance is $150,000 + $180,000 = $330,000 Probability of breach = .5 e – z/40,000 Let D = damages I owe if I breach Same questions as before: What is efficient level of investment in performance? Enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/430,000 How much will I choose to invest in performance? Enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/(100,000 + D) Efficient level? Social surplus is 330, ,000 if costs stay low, 0 if costs rise So expected social surplus is (1 – p(z)) (430,000) – z 430,000 – 430,000 * 0.5 * e–z/40,000 – z Take derivative to maximize this: – 430,000 * 0.5 * (–1/40,000) e– z/40,000 – 1 = 0 Could solve for z, but simpler to solve for p(z) 0.5 * e– z/40,000 = 40,000 / 430,000 = p(z) Efficient level of investment in performance is enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/430,000 What will promisor actually do? Private gain to promisor is 100,000 when costs stay low, -D when costs go up, minus whatever he invests in performance Expected private gain is (1 – p(z)) 100,000 + p(z) (-D) – z 100,000 – p(z) (100,000 + D) – z 100,000 – (100,000 + D) * 0.5 * e–z/40,000 – z – (100,000 + D) * 0.5 * (–1/40,000) e– z/40,000 – 1 = 0 Again, solve for p(z) 0.5 * e– z/40,000 = 40,000 / (100,000 + D) = p(z) For any level of liability D, promisor invests enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/(100,000+D)

37 What do these results mean?
What is the efficient level of investment in performance? Enough so that p(z) = 40,000/430,000 What will promisor do under various rules for damages? Enough so that p(z) = 40,000/(100,000 + D) So if D = 330,000, efficient investment in performance D = 330,000 is promisee’s benefit, including reliance So expectation damages, with benefit of reliance, leads to efficient investment in performance If D < 330,000, too little investment in performance If D > 330,000, too much Makes sense – think about externalities The efficient level of investment leads to a 40,000/430,000 chance of breach Damages which are set equal to D lead to a self-interested promisor to allow a probability of breach of 40,000/(D + 100,000) So when damages are set to 330,000 – damages include the benefit from reliance – the investment in performance is efficient When damages are lower than that, the seller will underinvest in performance, leaving the risk of breach inefficiently high When damages are higher than this, the seller will overinvest in performance And what’s the overall lesson? Making the seller liable for reliance – that is, increasing expectation damages to include benefit due to reliance – leads the seller to invest efficiently in performance; just like it led to efficient breach But it leads the buyer to overinvest in reliance On the other hand, making the seller not liable for reliance – leaving expectation damages where they were without reliance – leads to underinvestment in performance But it leads to the efficient level of reliance So like we saw last week with the sailboat example from Friedman: The level of damages leads to multiple different incentives And it’s impossible to come up with a level of damages that makes everyone behave efficiently We already saw one attempt to get around this problem: limit damages to the efficient level of reliance, not the actual level of reliance that way, the promisee has no incentive to overinvest in reliance, so he invests the efficient amount but the promisor still internalizes the full cost of breach so he invests the efficient amount in performance Textbook gives another clever, if unrealistic, solution, which is where we’ll start on Thursday

38 Effects of different remedies on…. decision to perform or breach
Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance That’s it for today Wednesday, we’ll finish up contract law


Download ppt "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 13."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google