Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Rural Investment and Policy Analysis (RIAPA) Modeling Toolkit

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Rural Investment and Policy Analysis (RIAPA) Modeling Toolkit"— Presentation transcript:

1 Rural Investment and Policy Analysis (RIAPA) Modeling Toolkit
Rui Benfica (IFAD-SKD) and James Thurlow (IFPRI) IFAD Learning Day Workshop, 25 February 2016

2 Outline Part 1: Introduction to RIAPA
What is RIAPA? What does it add to IFAD analytics? RIAPA entry Points in IFAD’s operational Cycle Depth vs. Breadth of the Analysis Spatial Scale of the Analysis Potential RIAPA Countries RIAPA Products and Timeframe Part 2: RIAPA Demonstration (“proof of concept”) Level 1 Analysis: Identifying agricultural investment opportunities with strong links to poverty reduction Level 2 Analysis: Evaluating economic impacts of value-chain development

3 Part 1 Introducing the RIAPA Model

4 What is RIAPA? What does it add to IFAD analytics?
“Rural Investment and Policy Analysis” (RIAPA) New tool being developed by IFAD and IFPRI for analyzing the contribution of IFAD’s investments to broader rural transformation goals (e.g., poverty, food security, nutrition and employment) Ex ante economy-wide analysis of projects and programs: Identifies agricultural sectors/sub-sectors with greatest impact on poverty Helps prioritize between project design options (e.g., which crops to target?) Estimates project impacts on job markets, food security, poverty, and nutrient availability Assesses potential benefits and constraints when scaling-up interventions Unlike other approaches, RIAPA explicitly captures two important considerations for IFAD projects: Economy-wide linkages (e.g., project spillovers) Macro-micro interactions (i.e., linking production to poverty)

5 I. Project Spillovers (1)
Direct impacts on treated + Indirect impacts on control group Example: Targeted Input Subsidy Program Observed effect with no spillovers Observed effect with negative spillovers (overstates impact) Observed effect with positive spillovers (understates impact) Treated Control

6 I. Project Spillovers (2)
Larger-scale programs (if successful) are more likely to generate spillovers at local and national levels Via labor markets… Labor wages may change, affecting more than targeted households/sectors Workers move across-sectors in response Workers may migrate between cities, towns and rural areas Via product markets… Real commodity prices may rise or fall Increased competition for inputs (e.g., fertilizer) Changes in imports and exports may affect foreign exchange rates Not accounting for spillovers can greatly reduce the measured benefits of IFAD’s projects (and possible constraints to scaling-up) e.g., Spillover effects from Malawi’s Farm Input Subsidy Program (FISP) are estimated to be about a third of total program benefits

7 II. Production-Poverty Linkages (1)
Linking farming to poverty depends on many factors… Types of new jobs created and the wages they offer Displacement of existing jobs Households’ land and labor endowments and access to capital Changes in product prices, and poor households’ consumption patterns Plus macro considerations: Import competition and export opportunities Project financing mechanisms (i.e., “Robin Hood” effects)

8 II. Production-Poverty Linkages (2)
Complex projects generally have more complex linkages to poverty For example… Larger-scale projects generate more spillovers (i.e., non-targeted households may benefit or lose from an IFAD project) Value chains, by design, affect both farm and nonfarm workers and households Investing in food production affect relative food prices for many rural (and urban) consumers Promoting export-oriented crops may displace food crops (i.e., food availability may fall even through incomes are rising) Not accounting for certain “transmission channels” can understate (or overstate) a project’s contribution to poverty reduction

9 Entry Points in IFAD’s Operational Cycle
What are the knowledge gaps in IFAD’s operational cycle that RIAPA’s operationally-relevant research could address? Level 1: Informing COSOPs Understanding “business-as-usual” trends Prioritize investment areas for IFAD Measuring IFAD’s contribution to rural development and poverty reduction Level 2: Informing Concept Notes Focus on value-chain development Supplement EFAs with estimates of potential growth, employment and poverty impacts

10 Depth vs. Breadth of Analysis
COSOPs require a broad assessment of trends and opportunities PDRs require in-depth analysis of specific projects IFAD already has tools for detailed project design RIAPA can supplement EFAs Esp. for concept notes that need to show potential poverty impacts RIAPA can also help with learning from ex-post impact m evaluation studies

11 Spatial Scale of Analysis
RIAPA compromises between having a detailed spatial focus, and the time and cost of implementing and conducting the analysis E.g., local models are usually for once-off analysis and require primary data collection, which means more time and resources (e.g., surveys)

12 Potential RIAPA Countries
RIAPA relies on existing country data i.e., Social Accounting Matrices (SAMs) and national household surveys Data exists for most IFAD countries Except in West and Central Africa (WCA) National SAMs need to be disaggregated across subnational regions IFAD is partnering with global SAM data networks to reduce burden on in-house resources

13 RIAPA Products and Timeframe
RIAPA will have a fairly standardized approach and sets of products RIAPA is expected to take about 8 weeks to implement, including drafting (and revising) research briefs/reports

14 Part 2.1 Informing COSOPs Identifying agricultural sectors (value-chains) with the strongest linkages to rural poverty

15 Using RIAPA to Identify Opportunities
Which agricultural activities or subsectors are most effective at reducing rural and national poverty? Answer depends on the structural macro-micro relationships: Factor and skill intensity of production (land, labor and capital) Poor households ownership of factor resources Changes in product prices (for own produced goods and for goods in domestic and foreign markets) Poor households consumption patterns

16 Malawi RIAPA Model 58 economic sectors: 16 factors of production:
27 in agriculture (incl. crops, livestock, forestry and fishing) 20 in industry (incl. food processing) 11 in services (incl. trade, transport and finance) 16 factors of production: Rural and urban workers by three education levels Crop land and livestock by small/medium/large smallholders, and estates Agricultural and nonagricultural capital 30 representative households: Rural and urban households by per capita expenditure quintiles Rural further separated by small/medium/large smallholders, and nonfarm Reference: Diao, Thurlow, Benin, Fan Strategies and Priorities for African Agriculture: Economywide Perspectives from Country Studies. Washington DC: IFPRI.

17 Malawi Case Study Run model over 2010-2020
Baseline is a continuation of recent trends Then accelerate growth in each agricultural subsector by increasing total factor productivity (TFP) Measure change in final year poverty rate (using microsimulation model) Agricultural Growth Rural Poverty Crop GDP 2010 Baseline (business-as-usual) Counterfactual (accelerated growth) 2015 2020 Poverty rate 2010 2015 2020 Impact

18 Results: Baseline Scenario

19 Closing Yield Gaps Target the same increase in total agricultural GDP
For smaller crops, this requires larger yield increases

20 Identifying Priority Sectors
Poverty effect: Some sub-sectors are better at reducing poverty We use poverty growth elasticities (PGEs) to measure how effective growth in a sector is in reducing poverty 𝑃𝐺𝐸= ∆ GDP growth rate ∆ poverty headcount rate Growth linkage effect: Some sectors are able to generate growth outside of agriculture (either directly along own value chain, and indirectly via other value chains) We use economy-wide linkage ratios (ELRs) to measure how effective growth in an agricultural sector in generating growth in nonagricultural sectors 𝐸𝐿𝑅= ∆ nonagricultural GDP ∆ agricultural GDP

21 Results: Ranking Activities
National PGE Rural PGE ELR Vegetables -4.42 -4.30 0.26 Cotton -3.33 -3.47 -0.26 Forestry -2.84 -2.83 0.15 Pulses -2.23 -2.33 0.07 Tobacco -1.75 -1.69 2.53 Fisheries -1.55 -1.41 0.66 Maize -1.34 -1.40 0.25 Fruits -1.21 -1.19 0.46 Groundnuts -0.97 -1.22 -0.54 Cassava -0.96 -0.89 Other export crops -0.87 -0.91 0.79 Other cereals -0.60 -0.62 0.21 Livestock -0.58 -0.45 0.18 Poultry -0.51 -0.44 0.51 Potatoes -0.42 0.34 Agricultural activities with strong poverty reducing linkages and positive nonagricultural growth effects Poverty-reducing agricultural activities with little or no downstream processing

22 Summary RIAPA Level 1 analysis is useful for..
Projecting “business-as-usual” agricultural and poverty trends Identifying agricultural activities whose growth is most effective at reducing poverty, and/or generating stronger downstream growth (e.g., value chains) Can also look at productivity gains in the trade and processing sectors Can also prioritize based on nutrition and environmental outcomes, etc. Can be run at national level and for subnational regions Limitations of Level 1 analysis: Focuses on individual sectors, rather than whole value-chains Does not identify specific investments or characteristics of new value chains

23 Informing Project Concept Notes
Part 2.2 Informing Project Concept Notes Measuring the agricultural and poverty impacts of projects with major value-chain components

24 Malawi Case Study Highly dependent on tobacco for both export earnings and smallholder incomes Government is exploring options to diversify exports e.g., soybeans, groundnuts, biofuels Existing crops are not export-oriented and so new value-chains will need to be developed Reference: Schuenemann, Thurlow and Zeller Leveling the field for biofuels: Comparing the economic and environmental impacts of biofuel and other export crops in Malawi. Discussion Paper 1500, IFPRI.

25 Using RIAPA for Value Chain Analysis
1. Characterize the new value chain Identify key stages in the supply chain Estimate labor and other inputs used at each stage (i.e., production costs) Determine market for finished product (i.e., export or domestic) 2. Insert new value chain into RIAPA and run simulations Outcome (poverty) Time (project horizon) Baseline (without value chain) Counterfactual (with value chain) Project Impact

26 Stages in Malawi’s Biofuel Value-Chain
Typical two step production process Farming of biofuel feedstock crop (e.g., sugarcane) Processing of feedstock into liquid biofuel Transaction costs generate incomes for traders and transporters Moving goods from farm to processing plant and then to export market Stage 1 Feedstock farming Stage 2 Biofuel processing Transport to processing plant Transport to border for export

27 Sugarcane-Ethanol “Technologies”
Farming System Options Irrigated outgrowers Rainfed outgrowers Liquid yield (liter/mt) 70.0 Feedstock required (1000 mt) 14,286 Land yield (mt/ha) 99.0 42.0 Land required (ha) 144,000 340,000 Workers employed (people) 53,669 100,634 Feedstock 53,298 100,263 Processing 371 Capital needs (units) 12,142 9,984

28 Comparing Biofuel and Existing Crops

29 Simulating Biofuels Expansion
Jointly model feedstock and downstream biofuels processing Biofuels sectors start very small and are then expanded by injecting capital Capital for biofuels production is from foreign direct investment All profits are repatriated Biofuels sectors compete for land and labor resources, and demand intermediate inputs All biofuels are exported (equivalent to reducing fuel imports) Product markets Labor Exports Capital Raw feedstock Agro-processing Trade & transport Land Services Industry Agriculture House-holds Supply Domestic sales Repatriated profits

30 Results: Macroeconomic Impacts
Large increase in exports Exchange rate appreciates Existing export crops decline Effect on food crops depends on land displacement We assume almost no new lands are cleared for biofuel crop cultivation (+14,000 hectares) National GDP rises Biofuel crops generate more GDP per hectare and worker than the activities it displaces

31 Results: Land Use Change
Rainfed farmers have lower yields and so need more feedstock land Leads to a displacement of food crops and falling food production

32 Results: Household Incomes and Poverty
Welfare and poverty improves in the irrigation scenario Esp. for poorer farm households Incomes increase from higher land and labor productivity Food prices fall Poverty worsens in rainfed scenario Income gains are modest because of negligable productivity increase Food prices rise

33 Results: Biofuels vs. Other Export Crops
Compare biofuels to other smallholder export crops Tobacco Soybeans Biofuel outperforms… No food crop displacement Larger national GDP and household welfare gain Larger reduction in poverty

34 Summary In Malawi, only irrigated smallholder value chains generate unambiguous benefits Increase national GDP and household welfare Reduce poverty and food insecurity Outperforms other (selected) smallholder export crops RIAPA Level 2 analysis is useful for.. Measuring benefits and trade-offs between different value chains Linking value chain development to poverty and food security Can also link to nutrition, GHG emissions, water use, etc. Can be run at national level and for subnational regions

35 Some Questions for Discussion
For RIAPA to be successful and sustainable, it needs to be: Useful for addressing IFADs needs (i.e., operationally-relevant) Accessible to in-house analysts (i.e., standardized inputs and outputs) Maintainable (e.g., minimize time spent building and updating datasets) Is RIAPA’s focus on COSOPs and concept notes correct? Is the information that RIAPA generates operationally relevant? Is RIAPA’s timeframe too long? Would results be timely enough? Is it possible to supply the value chain data RIAPA needs?


Download ppt "Rural Investment and Policy Analysis (RIAPA) Modeling Toolkit"

Similar presentations


Ads by Google