Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Presentation is loading. Please wait.

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 20.

Similar presentations


Presentation on theme: "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 20."— Presentation transcript:

1 Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 20

2 1  Midterm will be graded by Tuesday  No lecture Tuesday (too many people planning to be gone for Thanksgiving)  I’ll hold office hours during that time so you can pick up exams  HW3 online today, due December 8 Logistics

3 2 The legal process

4 3  Developed theories of property/nuisance law, contract law, and tort law  Looked at how rules of legal liability create incentives  Thought about how these rules can be chosen to try to achieve efficient outcomes Over the last 2 ½ months, we have…

5 4  To achieve efficiency, we’ve generally tried to set a party’s liability equal to the harm he caused someone else  Damages in nuisance law  Expectation damages in contract law  Compensatory damages in tort law  That way, he internalizes the externality he imposes, leading to efficient decisions  In doing this, we’ve been making two big assumptions:  The legal system works flawlessly  The legal system costs nothing Over the last 2 ½ months, we have…

6 5  I hit you with my car and did $10,000 worth of damage  We both know I was negligent  But courts aren’t perfect  If we go to trial, 80% chance I’ll be found liable, 20% I won’t  If I’m held liable, damages are correctly set at $10,000  So on average, if we go to trial, you expect to recover $8,000  But if we go to trial, we both have to hire lawyers  Suppose this costs us each $3,000  Now your expected gain from going to trial is $8,000 – 3,000 = 5,000  And my expected cost is $8,000 + 3,000 = 11,000 An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

7 6  So…  Going to trial gains you $5,000 (in expectation)  Going to trial costs me $11,000 (in expectation)  Maybe we can settle out of court  If we avoid going to court and I pay you any settlement between $5,000 and $11,000, we’re both better off  So maybe this happens  But… An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

8 7  Suppose I’m more pessimistic about my chances than you  You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable  I think I’m 90% likely to be found liable  You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000  I think my expected cost is $9,000 + 3,000 = $12,000  Now the range of possible settlements is even wider  Any settlement between $5,000 and $12,000 is a Pareto- improvement over going to trial  So settling is more likely An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

9 8  Now instead, suppose I’m more optimistic about my chances than you  You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable  I think I’m only 10% likely to be found liable  You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000  I think my expected cost is $1,000 + 3,000 = $4,000  Now an out-of-court settlement is impossible  There are no settlements that you and I would both agree to An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

10 9  And, even if our beliefs are compatible and there are settlements that we would both prefer to trial…  …private information might lead to failure to reach a settlement  Remember from before: if our threat points are private information, we might fail to reach an agreement because each of us is holding out for too big a share  So even if we had the same beliefs about what will happen at trial, private information could prevent settlement An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

11 10  So when litigation is costly…  If the two parties agree on the likely outcome of a trial, there are gains from settling out of court, and a range of settlements they would both prefer to going to trial  If the two parties are relatively pessimistic, settlement is even more likely  If the two parties are relatively optimistic, settlement may be impossible  Even if the two have the same beliefs or are relatively pessimistic, private information may lead to failures in bargaining An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

12 11  Under strict liability…  We said injurers internalize cost of accidents  efficient precaution  But this assumes cost of being sued = damage done  If courts are unpredictable and litigation is costly, private cost of being sued for damages could be > or < cost of accident  Which could lead to too much or too little precaution  But also…  If settlement talks break down and cases go to trial…  …then total social cost of an accident includes the harm done, and the resources expended during the trial!  If trial costs $6,000, then social cost of the accident isn’t $10,000, but $16,000 – which increases the efficient level of precaution! So what?

13 12 The legal process

14 13  Once an accident has happened…  Victim could sue or not sue  The victim and injurer might quickly settle out of court  If the case proceeds to trial, the first step (in the U.S.) is a pre-trial exchange of information  After that, victim and injurer might still settle out of court  If the case goes to trial, victim (now plaintiff) might win or lose  Losing side at trial can choose to appeal (or not) The legal process

15 14  Tort law: efficiency meant minimizing the total social cost of accidents  Actual cost of accidents  Plus cost of actions taken to prevent them (precaution)  Goal of the legal process: minimize its social costs  Direct (administrative) costs  Error costs The goal of the legal process

16 15  Administrative costs  Hiring judges, building courthouse, paying jurors…  More complex process  higher cost  Error costs  Any legal process is imperfect  Errors are any judgments that differ from theoretically perfect ones  An error in computing damages after the fact only affects distribution, not efficiency  But anticipated errors affect incentives, which may lead to actions which aren’t efficient  Error costs are costs of distortions in actions people take (precaution, activity levels, etc.) due to flaws in legal system Administrative costs and error costs

17 16  So theoretically, for efficient legal process is the one that minimizes the sum of…  The direct costs of administering the system, and  The economic effects of errors due to that process not being perfect The goal of the legal process

18 17 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process

19 18  In a rational world, victim compares cost of filing a lawsuit to expected gain from suing  How to calculate expected value of a legal claim? Why sue?

20 19 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose

21 20 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $100 – $20 = $80–$20 10%90% –$10$0 50% $100 – $20 = $80–$20 $30

22 21 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $100 – $20 = $80–$20 10%90% –$10$0 50% $100 – $20 = $80–$20 $30$50 – $1 = $49 70%30% 70% * $49 + 30% * $30 = $43.30

23 22 Why sue? Sue? Settle immediately or exchange info? Settle then or go to trial? Win or lose at trial? Appeal? Don’t FileFile Settle“Discovery” SettleTrial WinLose NoYes Win or Lose Appeal? WinLose $43.30 – $3.30 70%30% $50 – $1$43.30 70% * $49 + 30% * $40 = $46.30

24 23 Why sue? Sue? Don’t FileFile $46.30$46.30 – filing costs$0  Decision to sue  If expected value of legal claim > filing costs, we expect victim to file a claim  If expected value of legal claim < filing costs, we expect victim not to

25 24  So there are three things that directly influence the number of lawsuits  The number of injuries  The cost of filing a complaint  The expected value of a claim  Holding everything else constant…  More injuries should mean more claims  Holding fixed the number of accidents, lower filing costs, or higher expected value of claims, mean more claims  But things can sometimes get more complicated… So there are three things that directly influence the number of lawsuits

26 25 So there are three things that directly influence the number of lawsuits Number of lawsuits Typical level of damages

27 26  Expected value of claims should vary widely Filing costs Probability Expected value of claims Filing Fee SUE DON’T SUE

28 27  Recall the efficient legal system minimizes the sum of administrative costs and error costs  Higher filing fees  fewer lawsuits  lower administrative costs  But, higher filing fees  more injuries go “unpunished”  greater distortion in incentives  higher error costs  Filing fee is set optimally when these balance on the margin:  Administrative cost of an additional lawsuit = error cost of providing no remedy in the marginal case Filing costs

29 28  Error costs  If we’re only concerned with efficiency, we don’t care about distributional effects  That is, we don’t care if a particular victim is or isn’t compensated  So the size of error costs depends on how much peoples’ behavior responds to the incentives caused by liability  “The social value of reducing errors depends on whether the errors affect production or merely distribution”  When errors have large incentive effects, filing fees should be low  When errors have small incentive effects, efficiency requires higher filing fees Filing costs

30 29  As long as there are any filing fees or other costs to litigation, some harms will be too low to justify a lawsuit  When harm is small to each individual but large overall, one solution is a class action lawsuit Filing costs Probability Expected value of claims Filing Fee SUE DON’T SUE

31 30  One or more plaintiffs bring lawsuit on behalf of a large group of people harmed in a similar way  Example: California lawsuit over $6 bounced-check fee  Court must “certify” (approve) the class  Participating in a class-action suit eliminates victim’s right to sue on his own later  If suit succeeds, court must then approve plaintiff’s proposal for dividing up the award among members of the class  Class-action suits are desirable when individual harms are small but aggregate harms are large…  Especially when avoidance of liability has strong incentive effect  But there’s also a danger Class Action Lawsuits

32 31  Agency problem  Client wants lawyer to work on case until marginal cost of more work equals marginal benefit  This is hard to achieve through a contract, because lawyers face their own incentives  One solution: 100% commission (client “sells lawsuit to lawyer”)  But this is illegal  Common solution: reputation Lawyers and clients

33 32 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process

34 33  Trials are costly to both parties  If both parties agree on expected outcome of a trial, both are better off agreeing to out-of-court settlement on similar terms  If two sides are relatively optimistic about their chances in court, this may be impossible  After lawsuit filed but before trial, parties have opportunity to negotiate a settlement, and to exchange information relevant to trial  Some information exchange is mandatory  “Discovery” process in U.S. – each side must supply opponent with evidence they plan to use, answer questions about case  In Europe, no pre-trial discovery; instead, first stage of trial involves similar sharing of information in front of judge  Does voluntary pooling of information promote settlement?  Does involuntary pooling of information promote settlement? Exchange of Information

35 34  Parties tend to disclose information that corrects the other side’s relative optimism  I hit you with my car  I think your injuries were minor, damages might be $1,500  You know they were serious, have x-rays and doctor’s reports to prove it, know damages will be $15,000  Going to trial costs us each $3,000  As things stand: I expect trial to cost me $4,500; you expect to gain $12,000; settlement seems unlikely  But you’re happy to show me your evidence  Once I see it, I might offer a bigger settlement, we both avoid cost of trial  Parties tend to withhold information that would correct other side’s relative pessimism  Either way, voluntary exchange of information tends to encourage settlement Voluntary exchange of information

36 35  Cooter and Ulen: Trials occur when the parties are relatively optimistic about their outcome, so that each side prefers a trial rather than settlement on terms acceptable to the other side. When the parties are relatively optimistic, at least one of them is uninformed. Pooling of information before trial that reduces relative optimism promotes settlement. Furthermore, by revealing private information to correct the other side’s false optimism, the party making the disclosure increases the probability of settling on more favorable terms. Voluntary exchange of information

37 36  Involuntary disclosure will tend to reveal information the parties would otherwise choose to withhold  This is usually information that corrects relative pessimism  So forced disclosure may make settlement less likely  On the other hand, involuntary disclosure reduces uncertainty, makes two sides’ threat points more clear  May make reaching a settlement easier  So overall effect is unclear  Involuntary disclosure may also delay settlement until after disclosure occurs What about involuntary exchange of information?

38 37  Disclosure (“discovery”) rule in the U.S. very extensive  Parties reveal basic arguments they’ll make, evidence that supports them, names of witnesses, nature of each witness’s testimony  Each side can inspect other’s evidence, question its witnesses  Witnesses or evidence not disclosed during discovery may not be allowed at trial  Most European countries have little or no pre-trial discovery  Europe: juries rarely used in civil cases  Delays and interruptions less costly, more common  Under civil law, judges take more active role in developing arguments and exploring evidence What about involuntary exchange of information?

39 38  Voluntary disclosure encourages settlements  Fewer trials, simpler/quicker trials  lower administrative costs  Settlement terms get closer to likely trial outcome; if this judgment would likely be correct, this reduces error costs  Involuntary disclosure  Might lead to more or fewer trials  Should lead to simpler, shorter trials  Discovery is also a costly process  Overall effect on administrative costs could be positive or negative  Pools much of the information that would come out at trial, so settlements should deviate less from trial outcomes  So involuntary disclosure should reduce error costs Effect of information disclosure on administrative and error costs

40 39 Stages of the legal process… decision to pursue a legal claim bargaining over out-of-court settlements pre-trial exchange of information trial itself appeals process


Download ppt "Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 20."

Similar presentations


Ads by Google