Download presentation
Presentation is loading. Please wait.
Published byOwen Lloyd Modified over 8 years ago
1
Political Economy of Resource Taxation in Petroleum-Producing Countries Joris Morbee KULeuven CES and KULeuven Energy Institute joris.morbee@econ.kuleuven.be International Energy Workshop – IEW 2009 Session “Policy Instruments 1” June 17 th 2009, Fondazione Giorgio Cini, Venice
2
1 Bumper sticker spotted in Berkeley, California An alternative question would be: What are the taxes that oil-rich countries impose on extraction of their oil resources?
3
2 Why is there such a wide variation in taxation of resource extraction? *Including royalties, government share of oil, corporate income taxes and other taxes Source:Himona, I. (2005); Tordo, S. (2006) "Government take"* of petroleum extraction As % of companies' petroleum revenues Indonesia Brunei Turkmenistan Colombia China Australia Bolivia USA EXAMPLES This paper aims to explain the underlying causes of these differences The paper uses a combination of: –Resource economics –Political economy Practical relevance is for: –Companies deciding on international investment strategy –Governments deciding where to focus diplomatic efforts
4
3 Literature on resource-abundant countries is focused mostly on the "resource curse", in particular the "Dutch disease" *"Resource curse" is the phenomenon that although natural resources seem desirable at first sight, abundance of natural resources can distort a country’s economy and make the country on balance worse off Dutch disease Resource curse* Topic in literature Political economy theories Description Resource-abundance shifts production factors away from other sectors, leading to vulnerability and lower long-term welfare See: van Wijnbergen (1984), Krugman (1987) Quali- tative Model- based Resource-abundance leads to "petro-state", focused on distribution of rent See: Auty and Gelb (2001) (classify states according to Lal's (1995) typology), Karl (1997) Formal models of rent-seeking and probabilistic voting See: Torvik (2002), Robinson et al. (2006), van der Ploeg (2008) My paper uses a similar formal approach, but adds an empirical test on 46 countries
5
4 The model in this paper considers government revenues from both existing reserves and undeveloped/undiscovered reserves Resources Billion barrels of oil Revenue $ per barrel Medium termLong term ReservesUndeveloped / undiscovered reserves Oil price p Tax p Investor profits Billion $ Tax revenues Billion $ TRTR T U1 T U2 Government will try to maximize: T = T R + T U1 + P · T U2 T R, T U1 and T U2 depend on tax rate , while P depends on government type
6
5 T U1 and T U2 depend on the tax rate Resources Billion barrels of oil Probability of discovery in medium term ReservesUndeveloped / undiscovered reserves 100% Best exploration blocks Worst exploration blocks With higher tax rate, oil companies will initially only invest in the best blocks, leading to shift of revenues from T U1 to T U2
7
6 Lal (1995) classifies governments along two dimensions Myanmar Ghana Singapore Brunei "Autonomous" (=Dictatorship) Russia India Malaysia US Autonomy (Notation: ) "Factional" (=Multi-party) "Predatory""Benevolent" Benevolence (Notation: ) Source:Auty & Gelb (2001), Lal (1995) = 0 = 1 = 1 = 0 EXAMPLES
8
7 The type of government has an impact on the government's maximization problem Predatory government = 0 All values of Benevolent government = 1 Government's maximization problem: choose to...... maximize T = T R + T U1 + T U2... maximize T = T R + T U1 + P re-election · T U2... maximize T = T R + T U1 + ( + (1 – ) · (g 0 + g(T R )) ) T U2 (g 0 + g(T R )) Non-exporting countries ( = 0): is nearly irrelevant for government budget:* P re-election = g 0 / n = g 0 Exporting countries ( = 1): re-election depends on rent distribution potential of government:** P re-election = (g 0 + g(T R )) *n = number of competing factions; 1 / n **g' > 0 ; g'' < 0
9
8 As a result, the tax rate depends on political and geological characteristics As mentioned before, the maximization problem of the government is the following: Choose to maximize T = T R + T U1 + ( + (1 – ) · (g 0 + g(T R )) ) T U2 The optimal value depends in particular on – (level of "autonomy" of the government, e.g., = 1 is a dictatorship) – ("benevolence" of the government, e.g., = 0 is a fully corrupt state) – (whether the country is a petroleum exporter or not) In addition, the optimal depends on: – The size of (existing) reserves – The size of undeveloped / undiscovered reserves The mathematical model allows us to analyze how each of these variables impacts the tax rate Function of
10
9 The model results are consistent with empirical findings *OLS on dataset of 46 countries, assembled from BP (2008), USGS (2000), Himona, I. (2005), Tordo, S. (2006), Lal (1995) and the author's own assessment of political regimes in a number of countries based on public sources Government "autonomy" ( ) Government "benevolence" ( ) Size of (existing) reserves Size of undeveloped / undiscovered reserves Country is petroleum- exporter According to the modelAccording to empirical testing* Depends on circumstances Proven under conditions (subject of research) Not significant Significant at p = 0.014 level Significant at p = 0.108 level Significant at p = 0.020 level Significant at p = 0.045 level Proven mathematically Impact on resource tax rate
11
10 Results of the paper already explain a substantial part of the differences in tax rates Colombia USA China Indonesia 58.8 0 4.0 10.0 7.9 60.7 Resource tax rate in % Resulting tax rate Undis- covered reserves ReservesAutono- mous govern- ment Ex- porting countryRegression constant Application of regression coefficients Tax rate in reality 65 58.8 10.1 0.4 2.1 0 67.2 70 58.8 0 7.3 20.1 0 46.0 58.8 10.1 1.1 3.1 7.9 74.8 40 87
12
11 Next steps Improve political economy model: turn it into a full-fledged probabilistic voting model Add instruments to the regression (e.g., settler mortality as an instrument for institutional quality) Use standard datasets as proxies for and , e.g.: –Heterogeneity indices for –Corruption indices for Anchor paper in political economy and resource economics literature
13
12 Appendix
14
13 Details about the data sample and the regression results Source:Dataset assembled from BP (2008), USGS (2000), Himona, I. (2005), Tordo, S. (2006), Lal (1995) and the author's own assessment of political regimes in a number of countries based on public sources
15
14 References Auty, R. M. (1993). Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The Resource Curse Thesis. London/New York: Routledge. Auty, R. M. (2001). Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Auty, R. M. and A. H. Gelb (2001). “Political Economy of Resource-Abundant States”. In: Auty (2001). Besley, T. (2006). Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bohn, H. and R. T. Deacon (2000). “Ownership Risk, Investment, and the Use of Natural Resources”. The American Economic Review 90(3): 526-549. BP (2008). Statistical Review of World Energy June 2008, London, BP p.l.c. Davis, G. (1995). “Learning to Love the Dutch Disease: Evidence from the Mineral Economies”. World Development 23(10): 1765-1779. Himona, I. (2005). Oil & Gas: Nigerian Oil & Gas: Vital Statistics. Morgan Stanley Report 10718962. Karl, T. L. (1997). The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley: University of California Press. Krugman, P. (1987). “The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scale economies”. Journal of Development Economics 27: 41- 55. Lal, D. (1995). “Why growth rates differ. The political economy of social capability in 21 developing countries”. In: B. Koo and D. Perkins (eds.), Social Capability and Long-Run Economic Growth. Basingstoke: Macmillan: 288-309. Robinson, J. A., R. Torvik and T. Verdier (2006). “Political foundations of the resource curse”. Journal of Development Economics 79(2): 447-468. Sachs, J. and A. Warner (1995). Natural resource abundance and economic growth. NBER Working Paper 5398. Tordo, S. (2006). Fiscal Systems for Hydrocarbons: Design Issues. World Bank Working Paper No. 123. Torvik, R. (2002). “Natural resources, rent seeking and welfare”. Journal of Development Economics 67: 455-470. USGS (2000). Assessment of World Energy. Report of the United States Geological Survey van der Ploeg, F. (2008). Why do many resource-rich countries have negative genuine saving? Anticipation of better times, or rapacious rent-seeking. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 7021. van Wijnbergen, S. (1984). “The ‘Dutch disease’: A Disease After All?”. The Economic Journal 94(373): 41-55.
Similar presentations
© 2024 SlidePlayer.com Inc.
All rights reserved.