Market and welfare effects of Doha reform scenarios: implications for Southeast Asia Kym Anderson and Will Martin Development Research Group The World.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
DOHA and the EU. Intro Trade of industrial goods Trade in services Trade in agricultural goods Trade and the Environement.
Advertisements

Indias Trade Policy Choices MANAGING DIVERSE CHALLENGES SANDRA POLASKI A. GANESH-KUMAR SCOTT MCDONALD MANOJ PANDA SHERMAN ROBINSON February 2008.
Winners and Losers: Impact of the Doha Round on Developing Countries FINDINGS FROM A GLOBAL GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL Director, Trade, Equity and Development.
The Benefits of a New WTO Agreement for Agri-food Trade Shiferaw Adilu Alberta Agriculture and Food.
Ongoing reforms in most developing countries, little change in industrial and some developing countries Ongoing reforms in most developing countries,
Global Sugar Policy Reform John Beghin and Amani El-Obeid Economics and CARD Iowa State University Silverado Symposium on Agricultural Policy Reform University.
NS3040 Fall Term 2014 US/WTO Doha Round. U.S. and the Doha Round Jeffrey Schott, “What Should the United States Do About Doha?” Peterson Institute for.
Global Trade Reform Under The Doha Development Agenda: Implication for Sub-Saharan Africa Kym Anderson and Will Martin Development Research Group The World.
Notes, ECON 4415, lecture 1: International trade institutions Focus: Theory + institutions Reference: Hoekman and Kostecki (2001) Some parts ”should be.
Trade Reform, the Doha Development Agenda, and the World Bank Kym Anderson University of Adelaide, Australia and Development Research Group, World Bank.
WTO AGRICULTURAL NEGOTIATIONS Portfolio Committee Agriculture and Land Affairs April 2003 Günter Müller Directorate: International Trade National Department.
Sample exam paper Economics of Food Markets Alan Matthews.
Trade, Growth, and Poverty Reduction William R. Cline Center for Global Development and Institute for International Economics.
Determination of Trade Policy in the real world  Political  Economical – Optimum Tariff Rate  Strategic Game Playing between Countries Negotiations.
1 [Giovanni Anania, IAAE Congress, Durban, August 2003] The Fischler reform of the CAP and the WTO negotiations Giovanni Anania Department of Economics.
The Doha Endgame SS Economics of Food Markets Alan Matthews.
Figure 13.1 Tariff-inclusive price. Fig Fig
Thom Achterbosch LEI EU - India regional trade agreement – a quantitative assessment.
Quantifying the impacts of agricultural trade liberalisation Lecture 23 Economics of Food Markets Alan Matthews.
The EU’s CAP and the likely impact of a Doha Agreement Lecture 24. Economics of Food Markets Alan Matthews.
Impact of MFA Phase-Out on the World Economy -- An Intertemporal, Global General Equilibrium Analysis Xinshen Diao Trade and Macroeconomic Division International.
AGRICULTURAL POLICY REFORM IN THE WTO The Road Ahead.
Quantifying the impacts of agricultural trade liberalisation Lecture 27 Economics of Food Markets Alan Matthews.
INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL ENVIRONMENT and EXPORT CREDITS UPDATE
Agricultural policy reform under the WTO and Doha Kym Anderson Development Research Group, World Bank PREM Week, Washington DC, 25 April 2005.
WTO’s Doha round in an era of high food prices Kym Anderson University of Adelaide, Australia Review session for Ch. 3 of the Monterrey Consensus, on International.
Free Trade Agreements: Helping U.S. Businesses Export.
Analysis of Doha Agriculture Negotiation Issues Relevant to Developing and Least Developed Countries Alexander Sarris February 2014.
WTO Agreement on Agriculture: What’s it all about? What should be our advocacy?
Africa Regional Workshop on WTO Negotiations Trade Preferences : EPA /WTO Negotiations 02 September 2005 Cape Town, South Africa Paulina M. Elago Deputy.
Bi-lateral FTAs, RTAs and Unilateral Liberalization: The South Asian Trade Highways Presented at the ARTNeT-PEP Policy Forum on “Trade, Investment and.
Poverty and the WTO: Impacts of the Doha Development Agenda Thomas W. Hertel and L. Alan Winters Purdue University and Development Research Group, The.
1 Nepal’s WTO Membership and the Agriculture Sector Navin Dahal South Asia Watch on Trade Economics and Environment.
GLOBALIZATION The Aftermarket’s Economic Opportunity Eliminating Trade Barriers The following is a excerpt from a presentation by AAIA CEO Kathleen Schmatz.
One law firm around the world One law firm around the world Status of GATS Negotiations David Hartridge Hanoi, Vietnam August 5, 2003.
1 China’s WTO Accession: Some Lessons for Vietnam Will Martin World Bank 3 June 2003.
Seminar on: The WTO Doha Development Agenda Dr. Kui-Wai Li APEC Study Center City University of Hong Kong November 2, 2005 Economism is a Paradigm of “More.
John Panzer World Bank February 2007 Global Economic Prospects, 2007 Managing the Next Wave of Globalization in North Africa.
TRALAC ANNUAL CONFERENCE WTO/EPA ISSUES 13 October 2005 Cape Town, South Africa Paulina M. Elago Deputy Director: TFCBP TRADE HUB GABORONE.
Agriculture Negotiations: Moving Forward Ashok Gulati IFPRI Director in Asia WTO and The Doha Round: The Way forward ICRIER-SRTT Conference 6-7 April,
National Consultation of Project on “Doha Round and South Asia – Linking Civil Society with Trade Negotiations New Delhi “Development Dimensions” 17 September,
1 Aid for Trade: Complements for Development Joseph E. Stiglitz Columbia University, and the Initiative for Policy Dialogue.
EPAs and Access to Markets for Agricultural Products Reneth Mano Dept of Agricultural Economics University of Zimbabwe.
1 DOHA WORK PROGRAMME CURRENT SITUATION AND ISSUES FOR PAKISTAN Presentation at the EC-Pakistan TRTA Seminar at Islamabad By Dr. Manzoor Ahmad Ambassador.
1 Implications of a Doha Agreement for Agricultural Markets in Sudan Imad Eldin Elfadil Abdel Karim University of Khartoum - Sudan David Abler Penn State.
Agriculture: the heart of the DDA Kym Anderson Development Research Group World Bank African/LDCs Ambassadors Seminar on Doha, Washington DC, 13 March.
Agricultural Trade, Rural Development, and Policy Coherence Association for International Agriculture and Rural Development June 7, 2004 John Nash The.
Expectations from LDCs WTO 10 th Ministerial Conference in Nairobi
AFRICAN PERSPECTIVES ON THE DOHA ROUND ERASTUS J. O. MWENCHA, MBS COMESA SECRETARY GENERAL.
WTO – EU, US and DC’s Suspension of the Negotiations Søren E. Frandsen.
THE ROLE OF TRADE: SOUTH-SOUTH AND GLOBAL Ing. MARCELO REGUNAGA New Delhi, November 2003.
The Doha Round of WTO Negotiations: The U.S. Perspective Robert L. Thompson Chairman International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council and Gardner.
The Developing Countries’ Emerging Role in the Global Market Robert L. Thompson Chairman International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 24 May.
An overview of the Doha Development Agenda CARSTEN FINK Trade Policy and WTO Accession A Training of Trainers Course for Russia and the CIS March 22, 2006.
1 Trade, Equity and Development in the Doha Negotiations December 5, 2005.
WTO Hong Kong Ministerial Gains & Losses for India Pradeep S. Mehta CUTS International Jaipur, India
Day 4: Doha agricultural reform prospects and implications for Iran 4-day course on Agricultural Trade Policy and WTO Tehran, Iran, May 2005.
Eric Wailes and Alvaro Durand-Morat University of Arkansas, Division of Agriculture Impacts of WTO Policy on U.S. Rice Policy.
Non-agricultural market access negotiations Marc Bacchetta ERSD WTO.
Multilateral Trade Negotiations: Update on The Doha Development Round A European Perspective Dr Rolf Moehler.
WTO’s Doha Development Agenda and South Asian Agriculture
Day 3: The Doha Development Agenda: Progress and Prospects
The Potential Impact of the Doha Round on Grains
Improved market access for Russia or own liberalization as part of WTO accession: What will raise Russian income and reduce poverty more?                     
Modeling full global trade policy reform and Doha scenarios
NS3040 Summer Term 2018 US/WTO Doha Round
GTAP-AGR Modification occurs in production structure of ag sectors and segregation of factor markets between farm and non-farm uses. Farm production included.
The 2008 Market Access Proposals and Developing Countries
International Monetary Fund April 2019 Sub-Saharan Africa
Presentation transcript:

Market and welfare effects of Doha reform scenarios: implications for Southeast Asia Kym Anderson and Will Martin Development Research Group The World Bank Washington DC

A new empirical study of the Doha Development Agenda Part I: What ’ s at stake in the Doha Round? Part II: How far might Doha take the world towards global free trade? Part III: Lessons and implications, particularly for Southeast Asia

What differentiates our new study? Its point of departure is the WTO ’ s July 2004 Framework agreement It examines in detail each of the 3 agric pillars plus preferences, cotton subsidies, special and differential treatment, and NAMA And it ‘ adds up ’ the consequences of current policies and prospective Doha reforms using the new GTAP protection database for 2001 which includes, for the first time: bound as well as applied tariffs non-reciprocal as well as reciprocal preferential tariffs key trade policy changes to the start of 2005

Why a strong focus on agriculture … when the sector contributes <4% of global GDP and 9% of int ’ l merchandise trade? Because while OECD manufacturing tariffs have fallen by 9/10ths over the past 60 years to <4%, agric protection has risen and its applied (bound) tariffs now average nearly 5 (10) times manuf tariffs globally; And because the vast majority of the world ’ s poor rely on farming for a living

Why focus on agriculture (cont.) True, the harm to some DC farmers from OECD agric protection is reduced via non- reciprocal preference schemes such as ACP, EBA, CBI and AGOA But those schemes, like agric export subsidies, rely on undesirable exceptions to worthy WTO rules And those schemes exclude some significant DCs (e.g. China, Vietnam) and so may harm more poor farmers (through trade diversion) than they help

Applied tariffs of importing regions, 2001 (according to GTAP Version 6.05 database) High-income countries Developing countries Agric & food 1618 Textiles & apparel 817 Other merchandise 19 ALL MERCHANDISE 310

Applied tariffs of importing regions, 2001 (according to GTAP Version 6.05 database) IndonesiaThailandVietnamOther Dev. East Asia Agric & food Textiles & apparel Other merchandise ALL MERCHANDISE

Outline of presentation What ’ s at stake: what are the potential welfare gains from full global trade reform, by country/region, due to: developed rel. to developing countries ’ policies? agriculture relative to manufacturing policies? within agric, tariffs relative to export subsidies and domestic support? How close could Doha get us to completely free merchandise trade, in welfare terms, based on July 2004 Framework agreement? Implications for ASEAN and other DCs

Modeling Doha reform packages using World Bank’s Linkage Model Recursive dynamic CGE model We start with GTAP Version 6.05 protection and trade data for 2001 We project on-going reforms from 2001 to 2004 (Uruguay Round including ATC, EU25 enlargement, WTO accession for China etc.) Then we assume no further reform as global economy grows to 2015 (according to World Bank population, income, etc. projections), to get our global baseline scenario for 2015

Welfare cost of current protection policies by 2015 Larger than GTAP estimates as of 2001, because Linkage Model: projects world economy to 2015 includes some dynamics has larger trade elasticities than GTAP model Global cost of current tariffs and agric subsidies would be $278 billion p.a. by 2015 which is 0.7% of global income Would be much higher if the model had a stronger trade- growth linkage and included imperfect competition, economies of scale and an opening up of services markets

Aside: Why not negotiate cuts in trade measures only and forget about agric domestic support? Because the EU is the biggest export subsidizer, and it would insist on the US (the biggest domestic subsidizer) cutting its domestic support before agreeing to eliminate EU export subsidies (so as to share the political pain)? -- see next 2 two tables

Agric export subsidy rates, 2001 (%, as in GTAP database Version 6.05) EUNorwaySwitzUSJapan Sugar73 Dairy Rice15(?) Beef4010 O. meat107 C grain11 Wheat6

Share of PSE from domestic support (%, , from OECD) Share (%) US65 EU43 Japan10 Other OECD25

Cost of current policies, by region (as % of GDP in 2015) % Indonesia 0.8 Korea/Taiwan 3.5 Thailand 4.0 China 0.1 Vietnam 5.3 Other EA DCs 1.7 Singapore/HK 2.5 ALL DCs 0.9 ALL HICs 0.6

Factor price effects of current policies, by region (% in 2015) Unskilled wages Skilled wages Capital Indonesia Thailand Vietnam Korea/Taiwan China Japan Other EA DCs

Key elements of the Doha Agenda as shown in the July 2004 Framework agreement 3 agricultural pillars (including cotton) Non-agricultural market access Services Trade facilitation Special and differential treatment (SDT) for developing and esp. least-developed countries (DCs and LDCs)

Prospective Doha packages We focus on agric market access in particular because it is by far the biggest potential contributor to global and DC welfare gains So we assume no services reform, no new trade facilitation, but: phase out of agricultural export subsidies reduce agricultural domestic support and cut agric and non-agric bound tariffs under various alternative market access packages

Agricultural market access Tiered formula, as sought by Harbinson, for cutting bound tariffs (with SDT) It yielded almost no gains to DCs especially if 2% of products are exempted as ‘sensitive’ So we increased each cut by 10 percentage points We compare it with a proportional cut of same average size for HICs and for DCs And we look at effects of imposing a tariff cap of 200%

Agricultural domestic support Cut in bound AMS need not reduce applied support, because of binding overhang (with ref. prices) and overhang can be increased by abolishing admin prices used to calculate market price support We apply a tiered reduction in bound AMS 75% if AMS>20%, otherwise 60% Leads to only 4 countries reducing support: US 28%, Norway 18%, EU 16%, Australia 10%

Non-agric market access and SDT 50% cut in bound rates for high-income countries, 33% for DCs, 0% for LDCs We also examine the effects of DCs (including LDCs) becoming full participants in Doha agric and NAMA cuts, recalling from earlier Rounds that DCs only got what they gave, in terms of increased market access (see Finger 1974, 1976; Finger and Schuknecht 2001)

Services and trade facilitation These areas offer great potential gains, especially for developing countries See Hertel/Keeney chapter of our book But few significant signs of commitment have been forthcoming yet and quantification of their effects is problematic Hence we assume zero changes for these items in our modeled Doha scenarios

Results from Doha agric reform Tiered formula cut with SDT as per Harbinson gives the world $54 billion, but little goes to DCs So we increased all cuts by 10 percentage points, which gave a $72 billion global gain Even then, only $7 billion go to DCs & if HICs exempt just 2% sensitive products (DCs 4%), global gain shrinks to $16 billion and DCs lose –although a 200% tariff cap reduces much of that shrinkage If tiered formula is replaced by proportional one of same average cuts for HICs and for DCs, global gain is nearly as high ($64 billion) Why bother to negotiate over a complex tiered formula?

Adding non-agric market access Adding 50%/33%/0% cut to non-agric bound tariffs boosts global gain from agric tiered formula from $72 to $94 billion pa That $94 billion gets the world 1/3 rd of the way to the potential gains from complete global free trade in merchandise (but that share is much smaller as % of gains from removing also all services trade barriers, unless services markets are also opened up) If DCs and LDCs forego SDT in market access, global gain goes up to $103 billion

Implications for DCs Scenario 5 package would give DCs only 1/6 th their potential gain from a move to global free trade ($14 b. out of $87 billion) Even if DCs incl. LDCs were to forego SDT, as in Scenario 6, their gain rises by only $1.7 b. To gain more, DCs with v. high tariff bindings such as Indonesia have to liberalize more Isn ’ t it better to do that under Doha, so as to get reciprocity and/or more aid, than unilaterally?

DC welfare gains from Scenario 5 (percent change from baseline income in 2015)

DC welfare gains from Scenario 6 (Percent change from baseline income in 2015)

DC gains from full liberalization (Percent change from baseline income in 2015)

Other lessons and policy implications Potential gains from further trade reform are huge Even after UR and recent accessions to WTO and EU  Must find the political will for Doha success DCs would gain disproportionately from reform Notwithstanding non-reciprocal tariff preferences But as much would come from South-South as South- North trade growth, hence imptc of DC lib’n too After outlawing export subsidies, agric tariff cuts are the highest priority from a welfare viewpoint and if Doha is to be pro-development/pro-poor

Lessons and implications (cont) Cuts in agric tariffs and domestic support bindings need to be large to get beyond binding overhang Even large cuts in agric tariffs do little if ‘sensitive’ and ‘special’ products are exempt Unless a tariff cap of, say, 100% is enforced DCs would have to make few cuts because of their huge binding overhang So can afford to tone down their demands for SDT (and ‘special’ products) and trade it for greater access to HIC markets (& fewer HIC ‘sensitive’ product exemptions)

Lessons and implications (cont) Removal of cotton subsidies in US and EU would raise DC share of global cotton exports from 56% to 85% Adding non-agric market access to Doha package could double the welfare gains to DCs even with SDT, bringing global gains to 1/3 rd of potential from full merchandise liberalization And it helps balance the N-S exchange of ‘concessions’ Some LDCs lose slightly because they do not reform enough to get sufficient efficiency gains to offset their terms of trade losses