1 BOUNDS AND OTHER NO ARBITRAGE CONDITIONS ON OPTIONS PRICES First we review the topics: Risk-free borrowing and lending and Short sales.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 12: Basic option theory
Advertisements

Options Markets: Introduction
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 17 Options Markets:
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Jacoby, Stangeland and Wajeeh, Options A European Call Option gives the holder the right to buy the underlying asset for a prescribed price (exercise/strike.
Fi8000 Basics of Options: Calls, Puts
Chapter 22 - Options. 2 Options §If you have an option, then you have the right to do something. I.e., you can make a decision or take some action.
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
© Paul Koch 1-1 Chapter 10. Basic Properties of Options I. Notation and Assumptions: A. Notation: S:current stock price; K:exercise price of option; T:time.
Options Week 7. What is a derivative asset? Any asset that “derives” its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying.
Fi8000 Valuation of Financial Assets Spring Semester 2010 Dr. Isabel Tkatch Assistant Professor of Finance.
 Financial Option  A contract that gives its owner the right (but not the obligation) to purchase or sell an asset at a fixed price as some future date.
Options and Derivatives For 9.220, Term 1, 2002/03 02_Lecture17 & 18.ppt Student Version.
Chapter 19 Options. Define options and discuss why they are used. Describe how options work and give some basic strategies. Explain the valuation of options.
Chapter 131 CHAPTER 13 Options on Futures In this chapter, we discuss option on futures contracts. This chapter is organized into: 1. Characteristics of.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. 8-0 Finance Chapter Eight Properties of Stock Options.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 4th edition © 1999 by John C. Hull 7.1 Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 7.
Principles of Option Pricing MB 76. Outline  Minimum values of calls and puts  Maximum values of calls and puts  Values of calls and puts at expiration.
Principles of option pricing Option A contract that gives the holder the right - not the obligation - to buy (call), or to sell (put) a specified amount.
Class 5 Option Contracts. Options n A call option is a contract that gives the buyer the right, but not the obligation, to buy the underlying security.
Options: Introduction. Derivatives are securities that get their value from the price of other securities. Derivatives are contingent claims because their.
Chapter 28 – Pricing Futures and Options BA 543 Financial Markets and Institutions.
Chapter 20 Option Valuation and Strategies. Portfolio 1 – Buy a call option – Write a put option (same x and t as the call option) n What is the potential.
Put-Call Parity Portfolio 1 Put option, U Share of stock, P
Using Puts and Calls Chapter 19
Option Valuation. Intrinsic value - profit that could be made if the option was immediately exercised –Call: stock price - exercise price –Put: exercise.
Options Chapter 19 Charles P. Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management, Eleventh Edition, John Wiley & Sons 17-1.
1 Options Option Basics Option strategies Put-call parity Binomial option pricing Black-Scholes Model.
Introduction Terminology Valuation-SimpleValuation-ActualSensitivity What is a financial option? It is the right, but not the obligation, to buy (in the.
Professor XXXXX Course Name / # © 2007 Thomson South-Western Chapter 18 Options Basics.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2005 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 21 Option Valuation.
An Introduction to Derivative Markets and Securities
Investment and portfolio management MGT 531.  Lecture #31.
Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9
Chapter 10: Options Markets Tuesday March 22, 2011 By Josh Pickrell.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 18 Option Valuation.
Fi8000 Valuation of Financial Assets Spring Semester 2010 Dr. Isabel Tkatch Assistant Professor of Finance.
1 Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9. 2 ASSUMPTIONS: 1.The market is frictionless: No transaction cost nor taxes exist. Trading are executed.
Option Basics Professor XXXXX Course Name / Number.
Computational Finance Lecture 2 Markets and Products.
1 Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9. 2 ASSUMPTIONS: 1.The market is frictionless: No transaction cost nor taxes exist. Trading are executed.
Properties of Stock Option Prices Chapter 9
Security Analysis & Portfolio Management “Mechanics of Options Markets " By B.Pani M.Com,LLB,FCA,FICWA,ACS,DISA,MBA
Properties of Stock Options Chapter Goals of Chapter Discuss the factors affecting option prices – Include the current stock price, strike.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises Options.
Kim, Gyutai Dept. of Industrial Engineering, Chosun University 1 Properties of Stock Options.
Introduction Finance is sometimes called “the study of arbitrage”
© 2010 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible Web site, in whole or in part.
CHAPTER NINETEEN Options CHAPTER NINETEEN Options Cleary / Jones Investments: Analysis and Management.
Salaar - Finance Capital Markets Spring Semester 2010 Lahore School of Economics Salaar farooq – Assistant Professor.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Option Valuation.
Chapter 11 Options and Other Derivative Securities.
Dr. Scott Brown Stock Options. Principle 1: Lower Strike calls (and higher strike puts) must be more expensive For a Call Option, a lower strike price.
1 1 Ch20&21 – MBA 566 Options Option Basics Option strategies Put-call parity Binomial option pricing Black-Scholes Model.
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Options Chapter 17 Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management.
Class Lecture Investment Analysis Advanced Topics Options January 23, 2014.
Properties of Stock Options
1 Strategies with Options Chapter Strategies with Options No slides Use of board.
MTH 105. FINANCIAL MARKETS What is a Financial market: - A financial market is a mechanism that allows people to trade financial security. Transactions.
Lec 9 Intro to Option contracts1 Lec 1: Intro to Options Contracts (Hull Ch 9) Call Options. If you buy a CALL option on IBM, 1. You have the right, but.
Chapter 3 Insurance, Collars, and Other Strategies.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 The Binomial Solution How do we find a replicating portfolio consisting.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 Properties of Option Prices (cont’d) Early exercise for American.
Introduction to Options. Option – Definition An option is a contract that gives the holder the right but not the obligation to buy or sell a defined asset.
DERIVATIVES: OPTIONS Reference: John C. Hull, Options, Futures and Other Derivatives, Prentice Hall.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises
Fi8000 Valuation of Financial Assets
Presentation transcript:

1 BOUNDS AND OTHER NO ARBITRAGE CONDITIONS ON OPTIONS PRICES First we review the topics: Risk-free borrowing and lending and Short sales

2 Risk-free lending and borrowing Arbitrage: A market situation in which an investor can make a profit with: no equity and no risk. Efficiency: A market is said to be efficient if prices are such that there exist no arbitrage opportunities. Alternatively, a market is said to be inefficient if prices present arbitrage opportunities for investors in this market.

3 Risk-free lending and borrowing PURE ARBITRAGE PROFIT: A PROFIT MADE 1.WITHOUT EQUITY INVESTMENT and 2.WITHOUT ANY RISK We will assume that the options market is efficient. This assumption implies that one cannot make arbitrage profits in the options markets

4 We are now ready to analyze upper and lower BOUNDS AND OTHER NO ARBITRAGE CONDITIONS ON OPTIONS PRICES. The basic assumptions and notations that underlie the analysis are:

5 ASSUMPTIONS: 1.The market is frictionless: No transaction cost nor taxes exist. Trading are executed instantly. There exists no restrictions to short selling. 2.Market prices are synchronous across assets. If a strategy requires the purchase or sale of several assets in different markets, the prices in these markets are simultaneous. Moreover, No bid-ask spread exist only one market price.

6 ASSUMPTIONS: 3.Risk-free borrowing and lending exists at the unique risk-free rate. Risk-free borrowing and lending is done via selling short and purchasing T-bills 4.There exist no arbitrage opportunities in the options market.

7 NOTATIONS: t= the current date. S t = the current market price of the underlying asset. X= the option’s exercise (strike) price. K in the text book. T= the option’s expiration date. T-t= the time remaining to the option’s expiration. r= the annual risk-free rate.  = the annual standard deviation of the returns on the underlying asset. D= cash dividend per share.

8 NOTATIONS: C t = the current market premium of an American call. c t = the current market premium of an European call. P t =the current market premium of an American call. p t = the current market premium of an European call. In general, we express the options’ premiums as the following functions: C t, c t = c{S t, X, T-t, r, , D }, P t, p t = p{S t, X, T-t, r, , D }.

9 FINAL REMARK: Many strategies described below use lending or borrowing capital at the risk- free rate. Mostly, the amount borrowed or lent is the discounted value of the option’s exercise price. Namely, Xe -r(T-t). The assumption here is that the holder of the strategy can always buy T-bills (lend) or sell short T-bills (borrow) for exactly the amount of Xe -r(T-t). It follows that upon terminating the strategy at the option’s expiration time, the lender will receive this amount’s face value, namely, a cash flow of X. If borrowed, the borrower will pay this amount’s face value, namely, a cash flow of – X.

10 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 1.Call values at expiration: (3.1) page 102 C T = c T = Max{ 0, S T – X }. Proof: At expiration the call is either exercised, in which case CF = S T – X, or you let the option expire worthless, in which case, CF = 0.

11 RESULTS FOR CALLS(P104): 2.Minimum call value: A call premium cannot be negative. At any time t, prior to expiration, C t, c t  0. Proof: The current market price of a call is the NPV[Max{ 0, S T – X }]  0. 3.Maximum Call value: C t  S t. Proof: The call is a right to buy the stock. Investors will not pay for this right a price that is higher than what the value the right to buy gives them, I.e., the stock itself.

12 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 4.Lower bound: American call value: At any time t, prior to expiration, C t  Max{ 0, S t - X}. Proof: Assume to the contrary that C t < Max{ 0, S t - X}. Then, buy the call and immediately exercise it for an arbitrage profit of: S t – X – C t > 0. Contradiction of the no arbitrage profits assumption.

13 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 11. The money value of calls: The higher the exercise price, the lower is the value of a call. Proof: Let X 1 c 1 or, c 2 - c 1 > 0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell c(X 2 ) c ( S T – X 2 ) Buy c(X 1 ) -c 1 0 S T – X 1 S T – X 1 Total ? 0 S T – X 1 X 2 - X 1 In the absence of arbitrage the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

14 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 12. The money value of calls: Let X 1 < X 2 then C 1 - C 2  X 2 - X 1 Proof: Let X 1 < X 2 be the exercise prices or two American calls on the same underlying asset and the same time to expiration. Assume that C 1 - C 2 > X 2 - X 1 or, equivalently: C 1 - C 2 – (X 2 - X 1 ) > 0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell C(X 1 ) C 1 0 -(S T –X 1 ) -(S T –X 1 ) Buy C(X 2 )-C S T –X 2 Lend – (X 2 - X 1 ) X 2 -X 1 +i X 2 - X 1 +i X 2 - X 1 +i Total ? X 2 -X 1 +i X 2 -S T +ii i = interest Even if the sold call is exercised before Expiration, the total value in hand is >0.

15 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 13. The money value of calls: Let X 1 <X 2 then c 1 -c 2  (X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) Proof: Let X 1 < X 2 for two European calls on the same underlying asset and the same time to expiration. Assume that c 1 -c 2 > (X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) or, c 1 -c 2 -(X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) >0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell c(X 1 ) c 1 0 -(S T –X 1 ) -(S T –X 1 ) Buy c(X 2 )-c S T –X 2 Lend -(X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) X 2 -X 1 X 2 -X 1 X 2 -X 1 Total? X 2 -X 1 X 2 - S T 0 In the absence of arbitrage, the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

16 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 5. Lower bound: European call value: At any time t, prior to expiration, c t  Max{ 0, S t - Xe -r(T-t) }. Proof: If, to the contrary, c t < Max{ 0, S t - Xe -r(T-t) }, then, 0 < S t - Xe -r(T-t) - c t At expiration Strategy I.C.F S T X Sell stock short S t -S T -S T Buy call - c t 0 S T - X Lend funds - Xe -r(T-t) X X Total ? X – S T 0 In the absence of arbitrage, the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

17 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 6. The market value of an American call is at least as high as the market value of a European call. C t  c t  Max{ 0, S t - Xe -r(T-t) }. Proof: An American call may be exercised at any time, t, prior to expiration, t<T, while the European call holder may exercise it only at expiration.

18 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 7. The time value of calls: The longer the time to expiration, the higher is the value of a call. Proof: Let T 1 < T 2 for two calls on the same underlying asset and the same exercise price. To show that c 2 > c 1 assume, to the contrary, that c 1 > c 2 or, c 1 - c 2 > 0. At expiration T 1 Strategy I.C.F S T1 X Sell c(T 1 ) c 1 0 -(S T1 –X) Buy c(T 2 ) - c 2 c(TV) C(T 2 -T 1 ) Total ? c(TV) ?

19 RESULTS FOR CALLS: Case 1. The calls are American style. The question is whether C(T 2 -T 1 ) - (S T1 –X) ? If > 0 the proof is completed. If < 0, the open call can be exercised immediately for (S T1 –X) and the proof is complete. Case 2. The calls are European style. In this case, result 5. Guarantees that the cash flow above is >0 because c t1  S t1 - Xe -r( T2-T1).

20 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 8. Cash dividends and calls: Cash dividends and calls: It is not optimal to exercise an American call prior to its expiration if the underlying stock does not pay out any dividend during the life of the option. Proof: If an American call holder wishes to rid of the option at any time prior to its expiration, the market premium is greater than the intrinsic value because the time value is always positive. 9. The American feature is worthless if the underlying stock does not pay out any dividend during the life of the call. Mathematically: C t = c t. Proof: Follows from result 8. above.

21 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 10. Early exercise of Unprotected American calls on a cash dividend paying stock. (Section 8.7): Consider an American call on a cash dividend paying stock. It may be optimal to exercise this American call an instant before the stock goes X dividend. Two condition must hold for the early exercise to be optimal: First, the call must be in-the-money. Second, the $[dividend/share], D, must exceed the time value of the call at the x dividend instant. To see this result Consider:

22 RESULTS FOR CALLS: FACTS: 1. The share price drops by $D/share when the stock goes x-dividend. 2. The call value decreases when the price per share falls. 3.The exchanges do not compensate call holders for the loss of value that ensues the price drop on the x-dividend date. Time line tAtA t XDIV t PAYMENT S CUMD S XDIV 4. S XDIV = S CDIV - D.

23 Early exercise of Unprotected American calls on a cash dividend paying stock: The call holder goal is to maximize the Cash flow from the call. Thus, at any moment in time, exercising the call is inferior to selling the call. This conclusion may change, however, an instant before the stock goes x dividend: ExerciseDo not exercise Cash flow: S CD – X; c{S XD, X, T- t XD- } Substitute: S CD = S XD + D. Cash flow: S XD –X + D; S XD – X + TV. Conclusion: Early exercise of American calls may be optimal. If the call is in the money and D > TV, early exercise is optimal.

24 Early exercise of Unprotected American calls on a cash dividend paying stock: This result means that an investor is indifferent to exercising the call an instant before the stock goes x dividend if the x dividend stock price S * XD satisfies: S * XD –X + D = c{S * XD, X, t XD -t}. It can be shown that this implies that the price price S * XD exists if : D > X[1 – e -r(T – t) ].

25 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 14. The money value of calls: Let X 1 < X 2 < X 3 and X 2 =  X 1 + (1 -  )X 3 for 0 <  < 1. The premiums on the three calls must satisfy: c 2   c 1 + (1 -  )c 3 At Expiration STRATEGY ICF S T X 3 Buy  calls X 1 -  c 1 0  (S T – X 1 )  (S T – X 1 )  (S T – X 1 ) Sell one call X 2 c (S T – X 2 ) -(S T – X 2 ) Buy 1-  calls X 3 - (1-  )c (1-  )(S T –X 3 ) Total c 2 -  c 1 -(1-  )c 3 0  (S T –X 1 ) (1-  )(X 3 -S T ) 0 All the cash flows at expiration are non negative. Hence, the Initial Cash Flow cannot be positive! I.e., c 2 -  c 1 -(1-  )c 3  0. Or, c 2   c 1 + (1 -  )c 3. Remark: When  = 1/2, the strategy is called a Butterfly. In this case, 2X 2 = X 1 + X 3 and the result asserts: 2 c 2  c 1 + c 3

26 RESULTS FOR CALLS: Example: Let $80, $95 and $100 be the exercise prices of three calls on the same underlying asset and the same expiration. Observe that: $95 = (.25)$80 + (.75)$100. Thus, in this case,  = ¼. Result 14. Asserts that c(95)  ¼c(80) + ¾c(100). Or, 4c(95)  c(80) + 3c(100). If the latter inequality does not hold, then 4c(95) > c(80) + 3c(100) or, 4c(95) - c(80) - 3c(100) > 0 and arbitrage profit can be made by the Strategy: Buy the $80 call Sell four $95 calls Buy three $100 calls.

27 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 15. Volatility: The higher the price volatility of the Underlying asset, the higher is the Call value. Proof: The call holder never loses more than the initial premium. The upside gain, however, is unlimited. Thus, higher volatility increases the potential gain while the potential loss remains Unchanged.

28 RESULTS FOR CALLS: 16.The interest rate: The Higher the risk-free rate, the Higher is the call value. Proof: The result follows from result 6: C t  c t  Max{ 0, S t - Xe -r(T-t) }. With increasing risk-free rates, the difference S t - Xe -r(T-t) increases and the call value must increase as well.

29 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 17.Put values at expiration: P T = p T = Max{ 0, X - S T }. Proof: At expiration the put is either exercised, in which case CF = X - S T, or it is left to expire worthless, in which case CF = 0.

30 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 18.Minimum put value: A put premium cannot be negative. At any time t, prior to expiration P t, p t  0. Proof: The current market price of a put is the NPV[Max{ 0, X - S T }]  0. 19a.Maximum American Put value: At any time t < T, P t  X. Proof: The put is a right to sell the stock for X, thus, the put’s price cannot exceed the maximum value it will create: X, which occurs if S drops to zero.

31 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 19b.Maximum European Put value: P t  Xe -r(T-t). Proof: The European put may be exercised only at expiration. The maximum revenue it can create at that time is X, ( in case S drops to zero), thus, at any time point before expiration, the European put cannot exceed the NPV{X}.

32 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 20. Lower bound: American put value : At any time t, prior to expiration, P t  Max{ 0, X - S t }. Proof: Assume to the contrary that P t < Max{ 0, X - S t }. Then, buy the put and immediately exercise it for an arbitrage profit of: X - S t – P t > 0. A contradiction of the no arbitrage profits assumption.

33 RESULTS FOR PUTS(P116): 21. Lower bound: European put value: At any time t, t < T, p t  Max{ 0, Xe -r(T-t) - S t }. Proof: If, to the contrary, p t < Max{ 0, Xe -r(T-t) - S t } then, 0 < Xe -r(T-t) - S t - p t At expiration StrategyI.C.F S T X Buy stock-S t S T S T Buy put - p t X - S T 0 Borrow Xe -r(T-t) - X - X Total? 0 S T - X In the absence of arbitrage, the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

34 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 22. The market value of an American put is at least as high as the market value of a European put. P t  p t  Max{0, Xe -r(T-t) - S t }. Proof: An American put may be exercised at any time, t, prior to expiration, t<T, while the European put holder may exercise it only at expiration.

35 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 23. The time value of puts: The longer the time to expiration, the higher is the value of an American put. Proof: Let T 1 < T 2 for two American puts on the same underlying asset and the same exercise price. To show that P 2 > P 1 assume, to the contrary, that P 1 > P 2 or, P 1 - P 2 > 0. At expiration T 1 Strategy I.C.F S T1 < X S T1 < X Sell P(T 1 ) P 1 -(S T1 –X) 0 Buy P(T 2 ) -P 2 P(T 2 -T 1 ) P(TV) Total ? ? P(TV) You may exercise the put. The result follows.

36 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 24. American put is always priced higher than its European counterpart. P t  p t Proof: An American put may be exercised at any time, t, prior to expiration, t<T, while the European put holder may exercise it only at expiration. Moreover, if The price of the underlying asset fall below a certain threshold price, it becomes Optimal to exercise the American put and earn X – S t. At that very same moment the European put holder wants to (optimally) Exercise the put but cannot because it is a European put. The next figure demonstrates the relationship Between the American and European puts premiums.

37 RESULTS FOR PUTS(P176,7): 24. American put is always priced higher than its European counterpart.P t  p t S* S** X P/L X S Xe -r(T-t) P p For S< S** the European put premium is less than the put’s intrinsic value. For S< S* the Americanan put premium coincides with the put’s intrinsic value.

38 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 25. The money value of puts: The higher the exercise price, the higher is the value of a put. Proof: Let X 1 p 1 assume, to the contrary, that p 2 0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell p(X 1 ) p 1 S T – X 1 00 Buy p(X 2 ) -p 2 X 2 –S T X 2 - S T 0 Total ? X 2 - X 1 X 2 - S T 0 In the absence of arbitrage, the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

39 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 26. The money value of puts: Let X 1 < X 2 then P 2 - P 1  X 2 - X 1 Proof: Let X 1 < X 2 be the exercise prices or two American puts on the same underlying asset and the same time to expiration. Assume that P 2 - P 1 > X 2 - X 1 or, equivalently: P 2 - P 1 – (X 2 - X 1 ) > 0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell P(X 2 ) P 2 S T –X 2 S T –X 2 ) 0 Buy P(X 1 )-P 1 X 1 – S T 00 Lend – (X 2 - X 1 ) X 2 -X 1 +i X 2 - X 1 +i X 2 - X 1 +i Total ? i S T -X 1 +i X 2 - X 1 +i i = interest Even if the sold put is exercised before expiration, the total value in hand is >0.

40 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 27. The money value of puts: Let X 1 <X 2 then p 2 -p 1  (X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) Proof: Let X 1 < X 2 for two European puts on the same underlying asset and the same time to expiration. Assume that p 2 -p 1 > (X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) or, p 2 - p 1 -(X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) >0. Then, At expiration Strategy ICF S T X 2 Sell p(X 2 ) p 2 S T –X 2 S T –X 2 0 Buy p(X 1 )-p 1 X 1 – S T 00 Lend -(X 2 -X 1 )e -r(T-t) X 2 -X 1 X 2 -X 1 X 2 -X 1 Total? 0 X 2 - S T X 2 -X 1 In the absence of arbitrage, the initial cash flow cannot be positive.

41 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 28. Volatility: The higher the price volatility of the underlying asset, the higher is the put value. Proof: The put holder never loses more than the initial premium. The upside gain, however, is increasing from zero to X. Thus, higher volatility increases the potential gain while the potential loss remains Unchanged.

42 RESULTS FOR PUTS: 29. The interest rate: The higher the risk-free rate, the lower is the put value. Proof: Follows from result 22: C t  c t  Max{ 0, Xe -r(T-t) -S t }. With increasing risk-free rates, the difference Xe -r(T-t) - S t decreases and the put value decrease too.

43 RESULTS for PUTS and CALLS: (Section 8.4) 30. The put-call parity. European options: The premiums of European calls and puts written on the same non dividend paying stock for the same expiration must satisfy: c t - p t = S t - Xe -r(T-t). The parity may be rewritten as: c t + Xe -r(T-t) = S t + p t. Below, we prove the latter version of the parity.

44 RESULTS for PUTS and CALLS: Proof. Consider the following two portfolios: A: Long the stock and the put. B: Long the call and lend Xe -r(T-t). Portfolio A: At expiration StrategyI.C.F S T X Buy stock-S t S T S T Buy put - p t X - S T 0 Total -(S t +p t ) X S T Portfolio B: At expiration StrategyI.C.F S T X Buy call- c t 0 S T -X Lend - Xe -r(T-t) X X Total -(c t + Xe -r(T-t) ) X S T Portfolios A and B have identical cash flows At expiration for all possible prices. Thus, their initial values are equal: c t + Xe -r(T-t) = S t + p t.

45 RESULTS for PUTS and CALLS: 31. Synthetic European options: The put-call parity c t - p t = S t - Xe -r(T-t) can be rewritten as a synthetic call: c t = p t + S t - Xe -r(T-t), Or as a synthetic put: p t = c t - S t + Xe -r(T-t). Observe that the parity implies that at-the- money calls are priced higher than their counterpart puts. For at-the-money options, c t = p t + S t - Xe -r(T-t) becomes: c t = p t + X - Xe -r(T-t) > p t.

46 RESULTS for PUTS and CALLS: 32. The put-call parity. European options: Suppose that European puts and calls are written on a dividend paying stock and suppose that there will be two dividend Payments: D 1 at t1 and D 2 at t2. The option’s premiums must satisfy the following equation: c t -p t = S t -Xe -r(T-t) – D 1 e -r(t1-t) – D 2 e -r(t2-t) The proof follows the same path of result 30.But the stock will pay dividend twice at t1 and t2. Thus, borrowing the discounted value of the dividends and paying them upon receiving the dividends will leave the strategy unaffected and the result follows.

47 RESULTS for PUTS and CALLS: 34. The put-call parity. American options: The put-call parity for European options asserts that: c t - p t = S t - Xe -r(T-t). This result does not necessarily hold for American options. The premiums on American options satisfy the following inequalities: S t - X < C t - P t < S t - Xe -r(T-t).