Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 15.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
ECON 1450 – Professor Berkowitz Lectures on Chapter 2 Tort Law Area of Common Law concerned with accidental injuries Potential defendant engages in activity.
Advertisements

What You’ll Learn How to define negligence (p. 88)
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Negligence and Strict Liability Section 4.2.
Q UINCY COLLEGE Paralegal Studies Program Paralegal Studies Program Litigation and Procedure Negligence and Strict Liability Litigation and Procedure Negligence.
Business Law Tort Law.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 10.
Chapter 18: Torts A Civil Wrong
Law I Chapter 18.
Tort Law Part 2 Negligence and Liability. Negligence Most common tort Accidental or Unintentional Tort Failure to show a degree of care that a “reasonable”
Chapter 18 Torts.
Chapter 16 Lesson 1 Civil and Criminal Law.
Chapter 3 Tort Law.
Economics of Tort Law. CBO Study. The Economics of U.S. Tort Liability: A Primer, October 2003.
Public Injury vs. Public Offenses
Private Wrongs: Torts Negligence and Strict Liability Chapter 14.
Tort Law – Unintentional torts
Hazards Liability and Tort Lecture 8. Outline Another economic role for the government is regulating hazards and risks Factory producing explosives (location.
Economics of Tort Law. What is a tort?  Contract law: injury from a broken promise  Tort law: injury without any promises Intentional tort (≈ crime)
Click your mouse anywhere on the screen to advance the text in each slide. After the starburst appears, click a blue triangle to move to the next slide.
Professor Charles H. Smith Negligence, Product Liability and Damages (Chapter 15) Summer 2009.
Strict Liability and Torts and Public Policy Mrs. Weigl.
 A body of rights, obligations, and remedies that is applied by courts in civil proceedings to provide relief for persons who have suffered harm from.
Chapter 18.  Criminal Law: crime against the state  Civil Law: person commits a wrong, not always a violation of law  Plaintiff-the harmed individual,
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Intentional Torts Section 4.1.
 1. Duty-The accused wrongdoer owed a duty of care to the injured person  2. Breach of Duty- the defendant’s conduct breached that duty  3. Causation-defendant’s.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 17.
Chapter 5 Torts and Civil Law.
Unit 6 – Civil Law.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 16.
CHAPTER 7 Negligence And Strict Liability.
Tort Law Summary. Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law It is a “wrong” which.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 15.
Negligence. Homework 20.1 and 20.2 – read Chapter and 20.2 – read Chapter 20.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 14.
Chapter 20 Negligence. The failure to exercise a reasonable amount of care in either doing or not doing something resulting in harm or injury.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 16.
Torts A.K.A. civil law. What’s a Tort? Torts more or less means “wrongs” Refers to civil laws Based on both common law (decisions made by judges) and.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 15.
Tort Law Summary. Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law Entitles you to sue for damages in a civil court of law It is a “wrong” which.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013 Lecture 16.
Defences for Negligence. The best defence is Negligence did not exist, or the defendant didn’t owe the plaintiff a duty of care. The best defence is Negligence.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 6.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2015 Lecture 15.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2012 Lecture 16.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013 Lectures
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Intentional Torts Section 4.1.
Civil Law An overview of Tort Law – the largest branch of civil law Highlight the differences between tort law and criminal law How torts developed historically.
Chapter 20. Conduct that falls below the standard established by law for protecting others against unreasonable risks of harm Surgeon forgets to remove.
TORTS: A CIVIL WRONG Chapter 18. TORTS: A CIVIL WRONG Under criminal law, wrongs committed are called crimes. Under civil law, wrongs committed are called.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2009 Lecture 10.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 15.
4Chapter SECTION OPENER / CLOSER: INSERT BOOK COVER ART Negligence and Strict Liability Section 4.2.
Negligence Tort law establishes standards for the care that people must show to one another. Negligence is the conduct that falls below this standard.
Negligence SLO: I can understand the three types of torts, including negligence, intentional torts, and strict liability. I can identify relevant facts.
Certain professionals, such as doctors, pilots, and plumbers, are held to the standards of reasonably skilled professionals in their field. Even minors.
The Law of Torts I’m going to sue you!.
Negligence Mr. Lugo.
Civil Law An overview of Tort Law – the largest branch of civil law
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2016 Lecture 16.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 15.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2013 Lecture 17.
Torts “ Civil Wrongs” Chapter 17
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2017 Lecture 16.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Fall 2012 Lecture 15
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2010 Lecture 16.
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2011 Lecture 15.
Lesson 6-1 Civil Law (Tort Law).
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2016 Lecture 17.
Tort Law Summary.
Part D-I The Economics of Tort Law
Presentation transcript:

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2010 Lecture 15

1  HW3 due Friday (5 p.m.)  Second midterm next Wednesday (November 10)  Covers property and contract law – no torts Logistics

2 Let’s recap our story so far…

3  Efficiency  Maximizing total surplus realized by everyone in society  Scarce resources are owned by whoever values them most  Actions are taken if social benefit exceeds social cost  Design a legal system that leads to efficient outcomes  Once we set up the rules, we don’t expect people to act based on what’s efficient  We expect people to do whatever’s in their own best interest  So the goal is set up the rules such that people acting in their own best interest will naturally lead to efficiency Our story so far

4  Coase gives us one way to do that  If property rights are clearly defined and tradable, and there are no transaction costs, people have incentive to trade until each resource is efficiently owned  So initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency  But if there are transaction costs, we may not get efficiency this way  Led us to two normative views of the legal system:  1. Minimize transaction costs (“lubricate” private exchange)  2. Allocate rights as efficiently as possible  Tradeoff between injunctive relief and damages Our story so far

5  Property law works well for simultaneous trade  Contracts allow for non-simultaneous trade  Contract law can…  Enable cooperation  Encourage efficient disclosure of information  Secure optimal commitment to performance  Secure efficient reliance  Supply efficient default rules and regulations  Foster enduring relationships Our story so far

6  So far, we’ve been talking about voluntary exchange  Coase is predicated on exchange being voluntary for both parties  Contracts are an extension of voluntary trade  Up next: involuntary trade  You’re bicycling to class, I’m texting while driving and I hit you  You didn’t want to deal with me, I didn’t want to deal with you… Our story so far

7  To put it another way…  Property law covers situations where transaction costs are low enough to get agreement ahead of time  Exceptions to property law – private necessity, eminent domain – when this isn’t the case  Contract law covers situations when transaction costs are low enough for us to agree to a contract, high enough that we may not want to renegotiate the contract later  Tort law covers situations where transaction costs are too high to agree to anything in advance Our story so far

8 Tort law

9  Tort, noun. from French word meaning injury  Contract law: situations where someone harms you by breaking a promise they had made  Tort law: situations where someone harms you without having made any promises  “If someone shoots you, you call a cop. If he runs his car into yours, you call a lawyer.” Tort law

10  I hit you with my car, do $1,000 worth of damage  You’re $1,000 worse off  (No damage to me or my car)  Should I have to pay you damages? As always, we’ll be focused on achieving efficiency –1,000 Combined payoffs –50,000–1,0000My payoff 49,0000–1,000Your payoff I owe $50,000I owe $1,000I owe nothing

11 Something to remember distribution but not efficiency efficiency

12  Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes?  Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law)  Accidental harms: trickier  Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents” Tort law

13  Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes?  Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law)  Accidental harms: trickier  Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents”  Unlike nuisance law, injunctive relief is not an option  Unlike contract law, no agreement ahead of time  Cooter and Ulen: essence of tort law is “the attempt to make injurers internalize the externalities they cause, in situations where transaction costs are too high to do this through property or contract rights” Tort law

14  Plaintiff – person who brings a lawsuit  Defendant – person who is being sued  In a nuisance case, the defendant caused a nuisance, plaintiff was bothered by it, might be asking for injunction or damages  In a contract case, defendant breached a contract or violated its terms  In a tort case, defendant caused some harm to plaintiff, plaintiff is asking for damages  Plaintiff is the victim (person who was harmed)  Defendant is the injurer (person who caused the harm) Cast of characters

15  Harm  Causation  Breach of Duty “Classic” legal theory of torts

16  For a tort to exist, the plaintiff needs to have been harmed  “Without harm, there is no tort”  Gas company sold gas with a defective additive  Dangerous for cars with turbocharged carburetors  You have a car with normal carburetors  You might be angry; but you weren’t harmed, so you can’t sue  Similarly, no compensation for exposure to risk  Manufacturer exposed workers to some chemical  Exposure will cause 15% of them to develop cancer later in life  Can’t sue now – have to wait, see who gets cancer, then they can sue Element 1: Harm

17 Element 1: Harm Money Health  Perfect compensation  restores victim to original level of well-being  generally done through money damages

18 Perfect Compensation Emotional harm Pain and suffering Loss of companionship Medical costs Lost income Damaged property Intangible harmsTangible harms  In theory, perfect compensation should cover all losses  Historically, courts have been less willing to compensate for intangible or hard-to-measure losses  Over time, U.S. courts have started compensating for more intangible harms  Pro: the closer liability is to actual harm done, the better the incentive to avoid these harms  Con: disparity in award sizes, unpredictability

19  Harm  Causation  Breach of Duty “Classic” legal theory of torts

20  For a tort to exist, the defendant needs to have caused the harm to the plaintiff  Cause-in-fact  “But for the defendant’s actions, would the harm have occurred?” Element 2: Causation

21  For a tort to exist, the defendant needs to have caused the harm to the plaintiff  Cause-in-fact  “But for the defendant’s actions, would the harm have occurred?”  Proximate cause  Immediate cause – defendant’s action can’t be too distant from the harm  Palsgraf v Long Island Railway (NY Ct Appeals, 1928):  Guard pushed a passenger to help him onto train, passenger dropped fireworks he was carrying, they went off, explosion knocked down scales at the other end of the platform, which fell on Mrs. Palsgraf  Guard’s actions were not the proximate cause Element 2: Causation

22 “A tree fell on a moving trolly, injuring passengers. One of them sued. He succeeded in demonstrating that in order for the trolly to be where it was when the tree fell on it the driver had to have driven faster than the speed limit at some point during the trip. Breaking the law is per se negligence, so the driver was legally negligent whether or not his driving was actually unsafe. If he had not driven over the speed limit, the trolly would not have been under the tree when it fell, so, the plaintiff argued, the driver’s negligence caused the injury.”  Court ruled driver’s negligence “had not caused the accident in the legally relevant sense” Element 2: Causation

23  Harm  Causation  Breach of Duty “Classic” legal theory of torts

24 Element 3: Breach of Duty Harm Causation Breach of duty (fault) Harm Causation NegligenceStrict Liability  When someone breaches a duty he owes to the defendant, and this leads to the harm, the injurer is at fault, or negligent  Injurers owe victims the duty of due care  Negligence rule: I’m only liable if I failed to take the required standard of care – not if I was careful and the accident happened anyway (Sometimes required, sometimes not)

25 “A tree fell on a moving trolly, injuring passengers. One of them sued. He succeeded in demonstrating that in order for the trolly to be where it was when the tree fell on it the driver had to have driven faster than the speed limit at some point during the trip. Breaking the law is per se negligence, so the driver was legally negligent whether or not his driving was actually unsafe. If he had not driven over the speed limit, the trolly would not have been under the tree when it fell, so, the plaintiff argued, the driver’s negligence caused the injury.” Hence the language in the trolly example

26  If I breach my duty of due care and injure you, I am liable  If I exercise the appropriate level of care but still injure you, I’m not liable  How is the standard of care determined?  That is, how careful do I have to be to avoid liability, and who decides?  Is it negligent to drive 40 MPH on a particular road at a particular time of day? What about 41 MPH? 42? So under a negligence rule…

27  Some settings: government imposes safety regulations that set standard for negligence  Speed limits for highway driving  Requirement that bicycles have brakes  Workplace regulations  Some standards are left vague  “Reckless driving” may depend on road, time of day, weather…  Common law focuses on duty of reasonable care  Level of care a reasonable person would have taken  (Civil law relies less on “reasonableness” tests, tries to spell out what level of care is required) How is the standard of care determined?

28  Strict liability rule: plaintiff must prove harm and causation  Negligence rule: must prove harm, causation, and negligence  A little history  Early Europe: strict liability was usual rule  By early 1900s, negligence became usual rule  Second half of 1900s, strict liability became more common again, especially for manufacturer liability in American consumer products  U.S. manufacturers now held liable for harms caused by defective products, whether or not they were at fault Strict liability versus negligence

29  Harm  Causation  Breach of Duty “Classic” legal theory of torts

30 Economic model

31  The more carefully I drive, the less likely I am to hit you  But, driving more carefully is also more costly to me  Must be some efficient level of care  Similarly…  Construction company can reduce accidents with better safety equipment, better training, working shorter days, all of which cost money  Manufacturer can reduce accidents by designing/inspecting products more carefully – again, more expensive Precaution

32 Lots of things both victims and injurers can do to reduce number (or harm) of accidents study warning on medicine improve warning on medicine medicine causes side effects handle bottles carefully improve quality control by bottler exploding coke bottle back up data at riskbetter design of softwaresoftware fails walk more safelydrive more safelycar hits pedestrian park car in safer spacedrive more safely moving car hits parked car fireproof house manufacture wiring more carefully faulty electrical wiring causes house fire Victim’s PrecautionInjurer’s PrecautionAccident Cooter and Ulen, p. 338

33  Precaution: anything either injurer or victim could do to reduce likelihood of an accident (or damage done)  The next two questions should be obvious…  How much precaution do we want?  What is efficient level of precaution?  How do we design the law to get it? We will call all these things precaution

34  Car hits a bicycle  In real life: driver probably has insurance  In real life: some damage to bicycle, some damage to driver’s car  In real life: driver and bicyclist may not even know what the law is  We’ll simplify things a lot, by assuming…  Only one party is harmed  Parties know the law, don’t have insurance (for now)  We’ll focus on one party’s precaution at a time To answer these questions, we’ll introduce a very simple model of accidents

35  Unilateral harm – just one victim  Precaution – costly actions that make accident less likely  Could be taken by either victim or injurer  We’ll focus on one at a time  Notation  x – the amount of precaution that is taken  w – the cost of each “unit” of precaution  so total cost of precaution is wx  p(x) – probability of an accident, given precaution x  p is decreasing in x  A – cost of accident (to victim)  so expected cost of accidents is p(x) A Model of unilateral harm x level of precaution w marginal cost of precaution p(x) probability of an accident A cost of an accident

36 Model of unilateral harm x level of precaution w marginal cost of precaution p(x) probability of an accident A cost of an accident Precaution (x) $ p(x) A (Cost of Accidents) wx (Cost of Precaution) wx + p(x) A (Total Social Cost) x* (Efficient Level of Precaution)

37 efficient precaution:min x { wx + p(x) A } w + p’(x) A = 0 w= – p’(x) A  Under reasonable assumptions (p(x) convex)…  x < x*  w < – p’(x) A MSC < MSB  more precaution efficient  x > x*  w > – p’(x) A MSC > MSB  less precaution efficient  x = x*  MSC = MSB Model of unilateral harm x level of precaution w marginal cost of precaution p(x) probability of an accident A cost of an accident marginal social cost of precaution marginal social benefit of precaution

38 Model of unilateral harm x level of precaution w marginal cost of precaution p(x) probability of an accident A cost of an accident x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*x < x*x > x*

39  We haven’t yet said who is taking precaution  Some situations, only injurer can reduce accidents  Some situations, victim can too  Bilateral precaution is a little bit tricky, but if we look at the two parties one at a time, everything works fine  Wednesday: consider effect of different liability rules on precaution Model of unilateral harm

40 Effect of Liability Rules on Precaution

41  Three rules we’ll consider:  No liability  Strict liability  Negligence Effect of liability rules on precaution

42  In a world with no liability…  Victim bears the cost of any accidents, plus the cost of any precaution he takes  Injurer bears cost of any precaution he takes, does not have to pay for accidents Rule 1: No Liability

43 Rule 1: No Liability Injurer precaution x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*  Injurer’s private cost is just wx  Injurer minimizes private cost by setting x = 0 Private cost to injurer

44 Rule 1: No Liability Victim precaution x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*  Victim’s private cost is wx + p(x) A  To minimize this, victim takes efficient level of precaution Private cost to victim

45  So in a world with no liability…  Injurer takes inefficiently low level of precaution  (zero, or minimal amount)  Victim takes efficient amount of precaution Rule 1: No Liability

46  Perfect compensation: damages D = A  Under strict liability…  Injurer pays damages for any accidents he causes  So injurer bears cost of accidents, plus his own precaution  Victim pays only for his precaution Rule 2: Strict Liability

47 Rule 2: Strict Liability Injurer precaution x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*  Injurer’s private cost is wx + p(x) A  Injurer minimizes this by taking efficient level of precaution Private cost to injurer

48 Rule 2: Strict Liability Victim precaution x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*  Victim’s private cost is wx  No incentive to take any precaution, victim sets x = 0 Private cost to victim

49 Effect of liability rules on precaution EfficientZeroStrict Liability ZeroEfficientNo Liability Injurer precaution Victim precaution

50  When it’s the injurer who can take precautions, a rule of strict liability is more efficient  When it’s the victim who can take precautions, a rule of no liability is more efficient  Each rule works well for one incentive, poorly for other  Similar to paradox of compensation we saw in contract law  Negligence rule may allow us to get both incentives right So for accidents with unilateral precaution…

51  “Simple Negligence” rule  Legal standard of care x n  Injurer is liable for damages if precaution level was below the legal standard of care  x < x n  D = A  x  x n  D = 0  So on our graph from before, private cost to injurer is…  wx + p(x) Afor x < x n  wxfor x  x n Rule 3: Simple Negligence

52 Rule 3: Simple Negligence Injurer precaution x $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x n = x*  Private cost is wx + p(x) A if x < x n, only wx otherwise  If standard of care is set efficiently (x n = x*), injurer minimizes private cost by taking efficient precaution Private cost to injurer

53 Rule 3: Simple Negligence Victim precaution $ p(x) A wx wx + p(x) A x*  What about victim?  We just said, injurer will take efficient precaution  Which means injurer will not be liable  So victim bears costs of any accidents  (Victim bears residual risk)  So victim’s private cost is wx + p(x) A  Victim minimizes private cost by taking efficient level of precaution too! Private cost to victim (assuming injurer takes efficient level of precaution and is therefore not liable for damages)

54 Effect of liability rules on precaution Efficient Simple Negligence, with x n = x* EfficientZeroStrict Liability ZeroEfficientNo Liability Injurer precaution Victim precaution