Chapter 4 Utility.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter Four Utility. Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x  y: x and y are equally preferred. u x y: x is preferred at least.
Advertisements

Chapter 4 Utility Functions. Utility Ordinal Utility: The only property of a utility assignment is “how it orders the bundles of goods.” The size of the.
Chapter 3. * Prerequisite: A binary relation R on X is said to be Complete if xRy or yRx for any pair of x and y in X; Reflexive if xRx for any x in X;
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the same level of utility
Chapter Four Consumer Choice.
Consumer Choice From utility to demand. Scarcity and constraints Economics is about making choices.  Everything has an opportunity cost (scarcity): You.
PREFERENCES AND UTILITY
Axioms of Rational Choice
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions   A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’)
Utility.
Consumers’ preferences
Chapter Five Choice. Economic Rationality u The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those.
Axioms of Rational Choice
Utility Functions A utility function U(x) represents a preference relation if and only if: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’  x” U(x’) = U(x”).
Chapter Four Utility. Utility Functions u A preference relation that is complete, reflexive, transitive and continuous can be represented by a continuous.
Utility.
Chapter Five Choice.
Chapter Four Utility.
Consumer preferences and utility Modelling consumer preferences.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Utility. Utility Functions u Utility is a concept used by economists to describe consumer preferences. u Utility function is a function that assigns a.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization
The rules of the game Lectures Seminars The marking: exams and exercises.
Chapter Five Choice 选择. Structure 5.1 The optimal choice of consumers 5.2 Consumer demand  Interior solution (内解)  Corner solution (角解)  “Kinky” solution.
Chapter 5 Choice.
Theoretical Tools of Public Economics Math Review.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2015 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London.
Consumer behaviour: Ordinal approach Now, we go to the ordinal approach. Ordinalist cares only about ranking. It doesn’t matter if we say U(A) = 20, U(B)
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Chapter 3: Consumer BehaviorSlide 2 Topics to be Discussed Consumer Preferences Budget Constraints Consumer Choice Marginal.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics 1.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
Chapter 3 Consumer Preferences.
Chapter 3 Consumer Behavior. Question: Mary goes to the movies eight times a month and seldom goes to a bar. Tom goes to the movies once a month and goes.
Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility
1 Intermediate Microeconomics Utility Theory. 2 Utility A complete set of indifference curves tells us everything we need to know about any individual’s.
1 Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY Copyright ©2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.
Chapter 3 Preferences.
© 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 4 Utility. © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. 2 Preferences - A Reminder u x y: x is preferred strictly to y.  x.
L03 Utility. Big picture u Behavioral Postulate: A decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from the set of affordable alternatives. u Budget.
Chapter 4 UTILITY.
Chapter Four Utility 效用.
Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice
L03 Utility. Quiz How much do you like microeconomics A: I love it (unconditionally) B: I cannot live without it C: I would die for it D: All of the above.
Chapter 4 Utility Utility: conceptually an indicator of a person’s overall well-being How do we quantify? Can we do interpersonal comparisons? What does.
 This will explain how consumers allocate their income over many goods.  This looks at individual’s decision making when faced with limited income and.
1 Indifference Curves and Utility Maximization CHAPTER 6 Appendix © 2003 South-Western/Thomson Learning.
Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and the Concept of Utility.
UTILITY. Chapter 11 What is Utility? A way of representing preferences Utility is not money (but it is a useful analogy) Typical relationship between.
Course: Microeconomics Text: Varian’s Intermediate Microeconomics
Preferences and Utility
Chapter 3 Preferences Intermediate Microeconomics:
Chapter 6 Demand Key Concept: the demand function x1 (p1, p2, m)
4 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
Chapter 4 Utility Key Concept: Utility, an indicator of a person’s overall well-being We only use its ordinal property in most cases. Marginal utility.
Chapter Six Demand.
Preferences and Utility
Chapter Four Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
L03 Utility.
Utility Functions f ~ p p
Subject:Economics Class:1st Semester
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 4 Utility

Introduction Last chapter we talk about preference, describing the ordering of what a consumer prefers. For a more convenient mathematical treatment, we turn this ordering into a mathematical function.

Utility Functions A utility function U: R+nR maps each consumption bundle of n goods into a real number that satisfies the following conditions: x’ x” U(x’) > U(x”) x’ x” U(x’) < U(x”) x’ ~ x” U(x’) = U(x”). p p

Utility Functions Not all theoretically possible preferences have a utility function representation. Technically, a preference relation that is complete, transitive and continuous has a corresponding continuous utility function.

Utility Functions Utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept. The number assigned only matters about ranking, but the sizes of numerical differences are not meaningful. For example, if U(x) = 6 and U(y) = 2, then bundle x is strictly preferred to bundle y. But x is not preferred three times as much as is y.

An Example Consider only three bundles A, B, C. The following three are all valid utility functions of the preference.

Utility Functions There is no unique utility function representation of a preference relation. Suppose U(x1,x2) = x1x2 represents a preference relation. Consider the bundles (4,1), (2,3) and (2,2). U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4. That is, (2,3) (4,1) ~ (2,2). p

Utility Functions p Define V = U2. Then V(x1,x2) = x12x22 and V(2,3) = 36 > V(4,1) = V(2,2) = 16. So again, (2,3) (4,1) ~ (2,2). V preserves the same order as U and so represents the same preferences. p

Utility Functions p Define W = 2U + 10. Then W(x1,x2) = 2x1x2+10. So, W(2,3) = 22 > W(4,1) = W(2,2) = 18. Again, (2,3) (4,1) ~ (2,2). W preserves the same order as U and V and so represents the same preferences. p

Utility Functions f ~ f ~ If U is a utility function that represents a preference relation and f is a strictly increasing function, then V = f(U) is also a utility function representing . Clearly, V(x)>V(y) if and only if f(V(x)) > f(V(y)) by definition of increasing function. ~ f ~ f

Ordinal vs. Cardinal As you will see, for our analysis of consumer choices, an ordinal utility is enough. If the numerical differences are also meaningful, we call it cardinal. For example, money, weight, height are all cardinal.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles. Equal preference  same utility level. Therefore, all bundles on the same indifference curve must have the same utility level.

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves

Utility Functions & Indiff. Curves

Goods, Bads and Neutrals A good is a commodity which increases your utility (gives a more preferred bundle) when you have more of it. A bad is a commodity which decreases your utility (gives a less preferred bundle) when you have more of it. A neutral is a commodity which does not change your utility (gives an equally preferred bundle) when you have more of it.

Goods, Bads and Neutrals Utility Utility function Units of water are goods Units of water are bads Water x’ Around x’ units, a little extra water is a neutral.

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves Consider V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2. What do the indifference curves look like? What relation does this function represent for these two goods?

Perfect Substitutes x2 x1 + x2 = 5 x1 + x2 = 9 x1 + x2 = 13 V(x1,x2) = x1 + x2. x1 5 9 13 These two goods are perfect substitutes for this consumer.

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves Consider W(x1,x2) = min{x1,x2}. What do the indifference curves look like? What relation does this function represent for these two goods?

Perfect Complements x2 45o W(x1,x2) = min{x1,x2} 8 min{x1,x2} = 8 5 3 min{x1,x2} = 3 x1 3 5 8 These two goods are perfect complements for this consumer.

Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements In general, a utility function for perfect substitutes can be expressed as u (x, y) = ax + by; And a utility function for perfect complements can be expressed as: u (x, y) = min{ ax , by } for constants a and b.

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves A utility function of the form U(x1,x2) = f(x1) + x2 is linear in just x2 and is called quasi-linear. For example, U(x1,x2) = 2x11/2 + x2.

Quasi-linear Indifference Curves x2 Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the others. x1

Some Other Utility Functions and Their Indifference Curves Any utility function of the form U(x1,x2) = x1a x2b with a > 0 and b > 0 is called a Cobb-Douglas utility function. For example, U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x21/2, (a = b = 1/2), and V(x1,x2) = x1 x23 , (a = 1, b = 3).

Cobb-Douglas Indifference Curves x2 All curves are hyperbolic, asymptoting to, but never touching any axis. x1

Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions By a monotonic transformation V=ln(U): U( x, y) = xa y b implies V( x, y) = a ln (x) + b ln(y). Consider another transformation W=U1/(a+b) W( x, y)= xa/(a+b) y b/(a+b) = xc y 1-c so that the sum of the indices becomes 1.

Marginal Utilities Marginal means “incremental”. The marginal utility of commodity i is the rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity of commodity i consumed changes; i.e.

Marginal Utilities For example, if U(x1,x2) = x11/2 x22, then

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of Substitution The general equation for an indifference curve is U(x1,x2) º k, a constant. Totally differentiating this identity gives

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of Substitution It can be rearranged to

Marginal Utilities and Marginal Rates of Substitution can be furthermore rearranged to This is the MRS (slope of the indifference curve).

A Note In some texts, economists refer to the MRS by its absolute value – that is, as a positive number. However, we will still follow our convention. Therefore, the MRS is

MRS and MU Recall that MRS measures how many units of good 2 you’re willing to sacrifice for one more unit of good 1 to remain the original utility level. One unit of good 1 is worth MU1. One unit of good 2 is worth MU2. Number of units of good 2 you are willing to sacrifice for one unit of good 1 is thus MU1 / MU2.

An Example Suppose U(x1,x2) = x1x2. Then so

An Example U(x1,x2) = x1x2; x2 8 MRS(1,8) = -8/1 = -8 MRS(6,6) = - 6/6 = -1. 6 U = 36 U = 8 x1 1 6

MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions A quasi-linear utility function is of the form U(x1,x2) = f(x1) + x2. Therefore,

MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions MRS = - f′(x1) depends only on x1 but not on x2. So the slopes of the indifference curves for a quasi-linear utility function are constant along any line for which x1 is constant. What does that make the indifference map for a quasi-linear utility function look like?

MRS for Quasi-linear Utility Functions x2 Each curve is a vertically shifted copy of the others. MRS = -f(x1’) MRS = -f(x1”) MRS is a constant along any line for which x1 is constant. x1’ x1” x1

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution Applying a monotonic (increasing) transformation to a utility function representing a preference relation simply creates another utility function representing the same preference relation. What happens to marginal rates of substitution when a monotonic transformation is applied?

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution For U(x1,x2) = x1x2 , MRS = -x2/x1. Create V = U2; i.e. V(x1,x2) = x12x22. What is the MRS for V? which is the same as the MRS for U.

Monotonic Transformations & Marginal Rates of Substitution More generally, if V = f(U) where f is a strictly increasing function, then The MRS does not change with a monotonic transformation. Thus, the same preference with different utility functions still show the same MRS.