Capital Structure. Effect of Corporate Taxes So far capital structure was irrelevant. What if we introduces corporate taxes? Corporate taxes are paid after.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Session 6: Capital Structure I
Advertisements

Capital Structure.
Capital Structure in a Perfect Market
Debt and Taxes Chapter 15.
CAPITAL BUDGETING WITH LEVERAGE. Introduction  Discuss three approaches to valuing a risky project that uses debt and equity financing.  Initial Assumptions.
Capital Structure Theory Under Three Special Cases
Last Lecture.. Cost of Equity Cost of Preferred Stock Cost of Debt
Chapter Outline The Capital Structure Decision
Financial Leverage and Capital Structure Policy
Capital Structure Refers to the mix of debt and equity that a company uses to finance its business Capital Restructuring Capital restructuring involves.
Cash Flows in Capital Budgeting Three approaches:  Free Cash Flow and WACC  Adjusted Present Value  Cash Flows to Equity.
Goal of the Lecture: Understand how to determine the proper mix of debt and equity to use to fund corporate investments.
Capital budgeting considering risk and leverage
CHAPTER 18: CAPITAL BUDGETING WITH LEVERAGE
Valuing Stocks Chapter 5.
Capital Structure Decision
Capital Structure: Basic Concepts
Corporate Taxes Value of the firm and WACC
P.V. VISWANATH FOR A FIRST COURSE IN FINANCE 1. 2 Corporations pay taxes on their profits after interest payments are deducted. Thus, interest expense.
Théorie Financière Structure financière et coût du capital Professeur André Farber.
Solvay Business School – Université Libre de Bruxelles 11/06/2015Vietnam Corporate Finance Choosing a Capital Structure Prof. André Farber Solvay.
Théorie Financière Structure financière et coût du capital Professeur André Farber.
FINANCE 11. Capital Structure and Cost of Capital Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Fall 2007.
QDai for FEUNL Finanças Nov 30. QDai for FEUNL Topics covered  Capital budgeting with debt Adjusted Present Value Approach Flows to Equity Approach Weighted.
How Much Does It Cost to Raise Capital? Or How Much Return Do Security-Holders Require a Company to Offer to Buy Its Securities? Lecture: 5 - Capital Cost.
Weighted Average Cost of Capital The market value of the firm is the present value of the cash flows generated by the firm’s assets: The cash flows generated.
Capital Structure: Part 1
FINANCE 11. Capital Structure and Cost of Capital Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Fall 2006.
Valuation and levered Betas
CHAPTER 16: CAPITAL STRUCTURE – BASIC CONCEPTS
Chapter 14 Berk and DeMarzo
London Business School
1 Calculating the Cost of Capital Three steps to calculate it: 1.Find the required rate of return on each kind of security the firm has issued 2.Find the.
Kelvin Xu Slides prepared by: Asthon Wu, Garrett Kuhlmann.
© 2010 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible Web site, in whole or in part.
Capital Structure.
Capital Structure Decisions
Cost of capital. What types of long-term capital do firms use? Long-term debt Preferred stock Common equity Term loans Retained earnings.
Advanced Project Evaluation
Asymmetric information and Capital Structure In contrast to the agency costs problem, here the way of financing does not affect managerial actions. However,
Capital Restructuring
1 Valuing the Enterprise: Free Cash Flow Valuation Discount estimates of free cash flow that the firm will generate in the future. WACC: after-tax weighted.
Chapter 2 - Understanding Financial Statements, Taxes, and Cash Flows 09/02/08.
VALUATION AND FINANCING
CHAPTER 9 Stocks and Their Valuation
Capital Structure Modigliani-Miller
FINANCIAL LEVERAGE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE POLICY Chapter 16.
1. 2 Learning Outcomes Chapter 11 Compute the component cost of capital for (a) debt, (b) preferred stock, (c) retained earnings, and (d) new common equity.
FIRM VALUATION. Firm Valuation Assumptions: Corporate taxes - individual taxe rate is zero Corporate taxes - individual taxe rate is zero n Capital markets.
Capital Structure with Taxes
COST OF CAPITAL AND Chapter 11. The Dividend Growth Model Approach Can be rearranged to solve for R E 1.
Financing decisions (3) Class 17 Financial Management,
Chapter 18 Principles of Corporate Finance Eighth Edition How Much Should a Firm Borrow? Slides by Matthew Will Copyright © 2006 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
Capital Structure in a Perfect Market Chapter 14.
6- 1 Outline 6: Capital Structure 6.1 Debt and Value in a Tax Free Economy 6.2 Capital Structure and Corporate Taxes 6.3 Cost of Financial Distress 6.4.
Copyright © 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved McGraw-Hill/Irwin Cost of Capital Cost of Capital - The return the firm’s.
Lecture 11 WACC, K p & Valuation Methods Investment Analysis.
Chapter 12: Leverage and Capital Structure
MODIGLIANI – MILLER THEOREM ANASTASIIA TISETSKA. AGENDA:  MODIGLIANI–MILLER I – LEVERAGE, ARBITRAGE AND FIRM VALUE  MODIGLIANI–MILLER II – LEVERAGE,
Estimating the Value of ACME 1. Steps in a valuation Estimate cost of capital (WACC) – Debt – Equity Project financial statements and FCF Calculate horizon.
Chapter 15 Debt and Taxes. Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved The Interest Tax Deduction Corporations pay taxes on.
Capital Structure Theory Chapter Sixteen. Corporate Finance Ch16 1/p17 Prof. Oh, 2012 Choosing a Capital Structure  What is the primary goal of financial.
CAPITAL STRUCTURE & COST OF EQUITY MODIGLIANI AND MILLER MODEL CAPITAL STRUCTURE & COST OF EQUITY MODIGLIANI AND MILLER MODEL
Capital Structure I: Basic Concepts.
Chapter 15 Debt and Taxes.
Capital Structure Debt versus Equity.
Out of the perfect capital market: Role of taxes
Capital Structure (How Much Debt?)
Capital Structure I: Basic Concepts.
Presentation transcript:

Capital Structure. Effect of Corporate Taxes So far capital structure was irrelevant. What if we introduces corporate taxes? Corporate taxes are paid after interest Hence, under corporate taxes debt financing has an advantage (the more debt the firm has the greater unterest it pays  the lower taxable part of income (EBT) is

The Interest Tax Deduction Safeway’s Income with and without Leverage, 2005 ($ million) Net income is lower in the levered firm, however total amount available to all investors is higher! Without leverage it is 812 Without leverage it is 812 With leverage it is = 952 > 812 With leverage it is = 952 > 812

Interest Tax Shield Hence, the gain from leverage is = 140 =  C  Interest  C  Interest is called interest tax shield. This is the difference in cash available for all investors The following is true: CF to investors with leverage = Cash flow to investors without leverage + interest tax shield Hence: PV (CF to investors with leverage) = PV (Cash flow to investors without leverage) + PV (interest tax shield), that is…

Modigliani-Miller Proposition I with corporate taxes The total value of the levered firm = the value of the firm without leverage + the present value of the interest tax shield: V L =V U +PV(Interest tax shield)

Cash flows of levered and unlevered firm By increasing the cash flows paid to debt holders through interest payments, a firm reduces the amount paid in taxes. The increase in total cash flows paid to investors is the interest tax shield. (Figure assumes a 40% marginal corporate tax rate.)

How to compute PV(interest tax shield)? Example: valuing interest tax shield without risk

The interest tax shield with permanent debt Suppose a firm borrows D and keeps it permanently, paying the same annual interest each year, i.e. perpetual consol bond (you may also think of a short debt which is rolled over). Interest is rf (assume risk-free debt) PV(Interest tax shield) =  C  (r f  D) / r f =  C  D Note: the same is true if debt is risky and is fairly priced.

Modigliani-Miller Proposition II with taxes r E = r U + (r U - r D )(1 -  C )(D/E) Proof: From MM Proposition I with taxes: V L ≡ E + D = V U +  C D From MM Proposition I with taxes: V L ≡ E + D = V U +  C D The expected per period cash flow can be written both as Dr D + Er E and V U r U +  C Dr D The expected per period cash flow can be written both as Dr D + Er E and V U r U +  C Dr D Thus, Dr D + Er E = V U r U +  C Dr D Thus, Dr D + Er E = V U r U +  C Dr D And, hence, r E = (V U /E)r U - (1 -  C )(D/E)r D And, hence, r E = (V U /E)r U - (1 -  C )(D/E)r D Using that V U = E + D -  C D, we obtain the result Using that V U = E + D -  C D, we obtain the result The same is true for beta: β E = β U + (β U - β D )(1 -  C )(D/E)

Weighted Average Cost of Capital With Taxes Suppose a firm with tax rate  C borrows D at interest rate r per year. Then its net annual cost of debt service is: rD -  C rD = r(1 -  C )D Hence, the effective after-tax borrowing rate is r(1 -  C ) WACC:

Weighted Average Cost of Capital With Taxes WACC Remember: WACC is the cost of capital for FCF generated by assets, calculated for unlevered firm. All effect of leverage is in WACC, not in FCF

In contrast to the no taxes case, leverage reduces WACC now: Using r E = r U + (r U - r D )(1 -  C )(D/E), r WACC = r U -  C r U (D/E)/(1+(D/E)) – decreases in D/E

Using WACC to value the Interest Tax Shield with a Target Debt-Equity Ratio

Recapitalizing to Capture the Benefits of the Tax Shield Midco industries has 20 mln shares outstanding traded at $15 per share and no debt Consistently stable earnings tax rate = 35% Recap plan: borrow $100 mln and use the money to repurchase shares What’s going to happen with the stock price?

Tax consequences: V U = 20 mln  $15 = $300 mln V U = 20 mln  $15 = $300 mln PV(interest tax shield) =  C D = 35%  $100 mln = $35 mln PV(interest tax shield) =  C D = 35%  $100 mln = $35 mln V L = V U +  C D = $335 mln V L = V U +  C D = $335 mln E = V L – D = $235 mln E = V L – D = $235 mln In total shareholders will receive full $335 mln = E + $100 mln in cash for sold shares. Hence, they will receive a gain of $35 mln – the full value of the interest tax shield In total shareholders will receive full $335 mln = E + $100 mln in cash for sold shares. Hence, they will receive a gain of $35 mln – the full value of the interest tax shield

The share repurchase: The price before announcement is $15, but the firm won’t be able to repurchase for such price. Why? The price before announcement is $15, but the firm won’t be able to repurchase for such price. Why? Because if it does it will buy 100 mln / 15 = 6.67 mln shares, and the rest will be mln shares. Since E = $235 mln, the stock price after the repurchase would be 235/13.33 = $ > $15  nobody would sell for $15 Because if it does it will buy 100 mln / 15 = 6.67 mln shares, and the rest will be mln shares. Since E = $235 mln, the stock price after the repurchase would be 235/13.33 = $ > $15  nobody would sell for $15 No arbitrage pricing: No arbitrage pricing: (20 mln – $100 mln/price)  price = $235 mln  price = $16.75  price = $16.75 The company can offer more than $16.75, but then everybody wants to sell and rationing is needed (to avoid discrimination shares can be bough from everybody on a pro rata basis). The company can offer more than $16.75, but then everybody wants to sell and rationing is needed (to avoid discrimination shares can be bough from everybody on a pro rata basis).

Market Value Balance Sheet for the Steps in Midco’s Leveraged Recapitalization

Introducing personal taxes So far, with only corporate taxes debt has clear advantage over equity How are previous results affected by tax advantage of equity at personal level? Consider a firm with risk free debt D which generates X (EBIT) in t=0,1,2,... Consider a firm with risk free debt D which generates X (EBIT) in t=0,1,2,... corporate tax rate:  C corporate tax rate:  C personal tax rate on debt:  pD personal tax rate on debt:  pD personal tax rate on equity (dividend + capital gains):  pE <  pD personal tax rate on equity (dividend + capital gains):  pE <  pD

Each period, the cash flow after corporate and personal taxes is [(1-  pE )(1-  C )(X-r D D)] + (1-  pD )r D D, which can be rewritten as (1-  pE )(1-  C )X + [(1-  pD ) - (1-  pE )(1-  C )]r D D Discounting now the stream of [(1-  pD ) - (1-  pE )(1-  C )]r D D at (1-  pD )r D (assuming perpetuity) we get the total tax advantage (tax shield) of debt: [1- (1-  pE )(1-  C )/(1-  pD )]r D D MM Proposition I becomes: V L = V U + [1- (1-  pE )(1-  C )/(1-  pD )]r D D Depending on the relationship between (1-  pE )(1-  C ) and (1-  pD ), either debt or equity will be the preferred sourse of financing. Hence, introducing personal taxes can explain why equity is used