Chapter 3 Balancing Costs and Benefits McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
What Is Perfect Competition? Perfect competition is an industry in which Many firms sell identical products to many buyers. There are no restrictions.
Advertisements

10 Production and Cost CHAPTER. 10 Production and Cost CHAPTER.
10 OUTPUT AND COSTS CHAPTER.
ECO 230 Principles of Economics I: Microeconomics Chapter I J.F. O’Connor 1/19/05.
WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.
CHAPTER 7 Making Decisions PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil © 2004 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
CHAPTER 7 Making Decisions PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil
Technology and Production
More on supply Today: Supply curves, opportunity cost, perfect competition, and profit maximization.
Demand, Utility, and the Value of Time Today: An introduction to a route choice situation and utility.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2009 The McGraw-Hill Companies, All Rights Reserved Chapter 6 Perfectly Competitive Supply.
Chapter 9 Profit Maximization McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Introduction to Production and Resource Use Chapter 6.
Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Managerial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 5e Chapter 2: Economists’ View of Behavior.
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Balancing Costs and Benefits
Copyright © 2008 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Managerial Economics, 9e Managerial Economics Thomas Maurice.
Part 7 Further Topics © 2006 Thomson Learning/South-Western.
Chapter 8 Cost McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 30: The Labor Market Copyright © 2013 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin 13e.
Production and Cost CHAPTER 12. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Explain how economists.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
REVENUE THEORY IB Business & Management A Course Companion 2009 THE THEORY OF THE FIRM: COSTS, REVENUES AND PROFITS.
revenue, cost and profit.
Introduction: Thinking Like an Economist 1 CHAPTER 2 CHAPTER 12 The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of economics.
Perfect Competition Chapter Profit Maximizing and Shutting Down.
Chapter 3 Balancing Costs and Benefits McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin Chapter 4 How Businesses Work.
Chapter 3: Marginal Analysis for Optimal Decision
Chapter 4 How Businesses Work McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Chapter 9 Profit Maximization McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Chapter 7 Technology and Production McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Decision-Making at the firm level - The Goal Of Profit Maximization
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
© 2005 Worth Publishers Slide 7-1 CHAPTER 7 Making Decisions PowerPoint® Slides by Can Erbil and Gustavo Indart © 2005 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved.
Financial and Managerial Accounting John J. Wild Third Edition John J. Wild Third Edition McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2009 by The McGraw-Hill Companies,
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
Introduction to Production and Resource Use Chapter 6.
The Supply Curve and the Behavior of Firms
Chapter 8 Cost McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 8 Competitive Firms and Markets The love of money is the root of all virtue. George Bernard Shaw.
MAKING ECONOMIC DECISIONS. Remember… Scarcity forces people to make decisions about how they will use their resources Economic decision-making requires.
6 CHAPTER Output and Costs © Pearson Education 2012 After studying this chapter you will be able to:  Distinguish between the short run and the long.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Production and Cost Analysis I Chapter 9.
7 Perfect Competition CHAPTER
In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:
McGraw-Hill/Irwin © 2004 The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., All Rights Reserved. Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities Chapter 6.
Chapter 3 Balancing Benefits and Costs Copyright © 2014 McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. No reproduction or distribution without the prior written.
Day Seven Costing –Basic Issues 1.Cost volume profit 2.Operating Leverage 3. Transfer Pricing 4. Overhead - what and why?
Chapter 7 The Cost of Production. Chapter 7Slide 2 Topics to be Discussed Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? Cost in the Short Run Cost in the Long Run.
11 OUTPUT AND COSTS © 2012 Pearson Addison-Wesley The Firm and Its Economic Problem A firm is an institution that hires factors of production and organizes.
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. The Theory of Consumer Choice The theory of consumer choice addresses the following questions: –Do all demand curves slope.
Production and Cost CHAPTER 13 C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to 1 Explain how.
Chapter 6: Perfectly Competitive Supply
Chapter 8 Cost. Types of Cost Firm’s total cost is the expenditure required to produce a given level of output in the most economical way Variable costs.
Chapter 8 Cost McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand 10 The Logic of Individual Choice: The Foundation of Supply and Demand The theory of.
Copyright © 2001 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Slide Some Common Pitfalls for Decision Makers.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. Production and Cost Analysis I Chapter 9.
Perfect Competition Profit Maximizing and Shutting Down.
Chapter 5 Constraints, Choices, and Demand McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
© 2010 Pearson Education Canada Output and Cost ECON103 Microeconomics Cheryl Fu.
WHAT YOU WILL LEARN IN THIS CHAPTER chapter: 9 >> Krugman/Wells Economics ©2009  Worth Publishers Making Decisions.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.1 Chapter 8: Production and Cost Analysis I Prepared by: Kevin Richter, Douglas College Charlene.
The theory of consumer choice Chapter 21 Copyright © 2004 by South-Western,a division of Thomson Learning.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Chapter 3: Supply and Demand 1.Describe how the demand curve.
12 PERFECT COMPETITION. © 2012 Pearson Education.
Chapter 7 Technology and Production McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Chapter 3 The Demand For Labor.
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 3 Balancing Costs and Benefits McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Last Chapter Review During the last chapter, we looked at the basic concepts concerning… Demand Supply Equilibrium Elasticity 3-2

Main Topics of Ch. 3: Balancing Benefits and Costs In chapter 1, one of the most basic principles of economics was that “Trade- offs are unavoidable”. In this chapter, we look at the basics of how we juggle these trade-offs to find the best choice. We will look at… Maximizing benefits less costs Thinking on the margin Marginal Benefit vs. Cost Sunk costs and decision-making 3-3

Maximizing Net Benefit Terms defined… Net benefit: total benefit minus total cost Total (economic) cost must include opportunity cost Opportunity cost: the cost associated with foregoing the opportunity to employ a resource in its best alternative use What is your opportunity cost to attend univ.? Right decision is the choice with the greatest difference between total benefit and total cost 3-4

Car Repair Example You own an old car that you use for delivering pizza, but now want to sell it. You know that if some repairs are made, the value of the car will increase. The more time the mechanic spends repairing the car, the more it will be worth. Also, the more time the mechanic spends, the more it will cost you. 3-5

Car Repair Example: Benefit Schedule The mechanic’s time is available in one- hour increments Maximum repair time is 6 hours The more time the car is repaired, the more it is worth Table 3.1: Benefits of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Benefit ($)

Car Repair Example: Cost Schedule Table 3.2: Costs of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Cost of Mechanic and Parts ($) Lost Wages from Pizza Delivery Job ($) Total Cost ($) The mechanics time costs you money. Also, remember your opportunity cost with your pizza job!

Car Repair Example: Maximizing Net Benefit How should you decide how many hours is the “right” number to have your car repaired? Recall that every hour in the shop will bring both benefits and costs Choose the number of hours where benefits exceed costs by the greatest amount 3-8

Table 3.3: Total Benefit and Total Cost of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Benefit ($) Total Cost ($) Net Benefit ($) Car Repair Example: The Right Decision 3-9

Table 3.3: Total Benefit and Total Cost of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Benefit ($) Total Cost ($) Net Benefit ($) Car Repair Example: The Right Decision 3-10

Table 3.3: Total Benefit and Total Cost of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Benefit ($) Total Cost ($) Net Benefit ($) Best Choice Car Repair Example: The Right Decision 3-11

465 Car Repair Example: Graphical Approach (Figure 3.1) Data from Table 3.3 are shown in this graph Costs are in red; benefits are in blue The best choice is where benefits > costs and the distance between them is maximized This is at 3 hours, net benefit = $910 Total Benefit, Total Cost ($) Repair Hours Best Choice 3-12

Maximizing Net Benefit: Finely Divisible Actions Many decisions involve actions that are more finely divisible E.g. mechanic’s time available by the minute In these cases, you can use benefit and cost curves rather than points or a schedule to make the best decision Underlying principle is the same: maximize net benefit 3-13

Car Repair Example: Finely Divisible Benefit Horizontal axis measures hours of mechanic’s time Vertical axis measures in dollars the total increase in your car’s value B(H)=654H-40H 2 Total Benefit ($) Hours (H) (a): Total Benefit B 3-14

Car Repair Example: Finely Divisible Cost Vertical axis measures total cost in dollars Includes opportunity cost C(H)=110H+40H Hours (H) (b): Total Cost Total Cost ($) C 3-15

Car Repair Example: Finely Divisible Net Benefit Best choice is 3.4 hours of repair, maximizes net benefit Net benefit with finely divisible choices is greater than in previous example; more flexibility allows you to do better Total Benefit Total Cost ($) (c): Total Benefit versus Total Cost Hours (H) 3.4 B C

Net Benefit Curve (Figure 3.3) Can also graph the net benefit curve Vertical axis shows B-C, net benefit Best choice is the number of hours that corresponds to the highest point on the curve, 3.4 hours Hours (H) 3.4 Net Benefit ($) B – C 3-17

Thinking on the Margin Thinking like an economist Another approach to maximizing net benefits Capture the way that benefits and costs change as the level of activity changes just a little bit For any action choice X, the marginal units are the last  X units, where  X is the smallest amount you can add or subtract. Ie. the mechanic may charge by the hour, ½ hour or even by the minute. 3-18

Marginal Cost The marginal cost of an action at an activity level of X units is equal to the extra cost incurred due to the marginal units, divided by the number of marginal units 3-19

Car Repair Example: Marginal Cost Marginal cost measures the additional cost incurred from the marginal units (  H) of repair time If C(H) is the total cost of H hours of repair work, the extra cost of the last  H hours is  C = C(H) – C(H-  H) To find marginal cost, divide this extra cost by the number of extra hours of repair time,  H 3-20

Car Repair Example: Marginal Cost So the marginal cost of an additional hour of repair time is: Using the data from Table 3.2 (p65), if H= 3, we see: 3-21

Car Repair Example: Marginal Cost Schedule Table 3.5: Total Cost and Marginal Cost of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Cost ($) Marginal Cost (MC) ($/hour)

Marginal Benefit The marginal benefit of an action at an activity level of X units is equal to the extra benefit produced due to the marginal units, divided by the number of marginal units 3-23

Car Repair Example: Marginal Benefit Marginal benefit measures the additional benefit gained from the marginal units (  H) of repair time This parallels the definition and formula for marginal cost 3-24

Car Repair Example: Marginal Benefit The marginal benefit of an additional hour of repair time is: Using the data from Table 3.1 (p65), if H= 3, we see: 3-25

Car Repair Example: Marginal Benefit Schedule Table 3.6: Total Benefit and Marginal Benefit of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Total Benefit ($) Marginal Benefit (MB) ($/hour)

Marginal Analysis and Best Choice Comparing marginal benefits and marginal costs can show whether an increase or decrease in a level of an activity raises or lowers the net benefit Increase level if MB of doing so is greater than MC; if MC of last increase was greater than MB, decrease the level At the best choice, a small change in activity level can’t increase the net benefit Get as close to MB=MC as possible 3-27

Marginal Analysis and Best Choice Table 3.7: Marginal Benefit and Marginal Cost of Repairing Your Car Repair Time (Hours) Marginal Benefit (MB) ($/hour) Marginal Cost (MC) ($/hour) > > > < < <550 Best Choice 3-28 No Marginal Improvement can be made. Why? Under what situation could this be improved?

Marginal Analysis with Finely Divisible Actions Can conduct the same analysis if choices are finely divisible by using marginal benefit and marginal cost curves Derive marginal benefit and marginal cost from total benefit and total cost curves Marginal benefit at H hours of repair time is equal to the slope of the line drawn tangent to the total benefit function at that point Usually called simply the “slope of the total benefit curve” at point D 3-29

Car Repair Example: Finely Divisible Marginal Benefit Let  H' = the smallest possible change in hours of car repair Adding the last  H‘ of repairs increases total benefit from point F to point D in Figure 3.4 (on the next slide), this equal to: Recall that marginal benefit (slope) is  B' /  H' Since the vertical axis measures hours of work and the horizontal axis measures total benefit, then marginal benefit equals “rise” over “run” between points F and D. 3-30

Relationship between Total Benefit and Marginal Benefit (Figure 3.4) Slope = MB Slope = MB = Slope = MB = Hours (H) Total Benefit ($) F E D 3-31

Relationship between Total Benefit and Marginal Benefit Tangents to the total benefit function at three different numbers of hours (H = 1, H = 3, H = 5) Slope of each tangent equals the marginal benefit at each number of hours Figure (b) shows the MB curve: note how the MB varies with the number of hours Marginal benefit curve is described by the function MB(H)= H 3-32

Relationship between Total Benefit and Marginal Benefit (Figure 3.5) Total Benefit ($) Hours (H) B (a): Total Benefit Slope = MB = 574 Slope = MB = 414 Slope = MB = Marginal Benefit ($/hour) MB (b): Marginal Benefit 654 Hours (H) 3-33

Relationship between Total Cost and Marginal Cost Parallels relationship between total benefit curve and marginal benefit When actions are finely divisible, the marginal cost when choosing action X is equal to the slope of the total cost curve at X 3-34

Relationship between Total Cost and Marginal Cost Tangents to the total cost curve at three different numbers of hours (H = 1, H = 3, H = 5) Slope of each tangent equals the marginal cost at each number of hours Figure (b) shows the MC curve: note how the MC varies with the number of hours Marginal cost curve is described by the function MC(H)= H 3-35

Relationship between Total Cost and Marginal Cost (Figure 3.6) Total Cost ($) (a): Total Cost(b): Marginal Cost Hours (H) 0 C Slope = MC = 190 Slope = MC = 350 Slope = MC = Marginal Cost ($/hour) Hours (H) MC 3-36

Marginal Benefit Equals Marginal Cost at a Best Choice At the best choice of 3.4 hours, the No Marginal Improvement Principle holds so MB = MC At any number of hours below 3.4, MB > MC, so a small increase in repair time will improve the net benefit At any number of hours above 3.4, MC > MB, so that a small decrease in repair time will improve net benefit 3-37

Marginal Benefit Equals Marginal Cost at a Best Choice (Figure 3.7) Marginal Benefit, Marginal Cost ($/hour) Hours (H) MC MB

Slopes of Total Benefit and Total Cost Curves at the Best Choice MC = MB at the best choice of 3.4 hours of repair Therefore, the slopes of the total benefit and total cost curves must be equal at this point Tangents to the total benefit and total cost curves show this relationship 3-39

Slope of Total Benefit and Total Cost Curves (Figure 3.8) Hours (H) Total Benefit Total Cost ($) B C

Marginal Anal. – 2 Steps to Finding the Best Choice Step 1: Identify any interior actions that satisfy the No Marginal Improvement Principle. MB=MC Step 2: Compare the net benefits of the best interior action to those from the boundary actions. Best choice is the one with the highest net benefit. 3-41

Marginal Anal. – Mechanic Ex. Step 1: MB=MC Marginal Benefit Eq. = MB(H)= H Marginal Cost Eq. = MC(H)= H H=110+80H H=3.4 ($924.80…remember…the total benefit equation is 654H-40H²) Step 2: Compare to boundary #s H=0 ($0) H=6 ($385 ~ rounded to nearest $5) …remember…the total benefit equation is 110H- 40H²) Which is the best choice? 3-42

Sunk Costs and Decision Making A sunk cost is a cost that the decision maker has already incurred, or A cost that is unavoidable regardless of what the decision maker does. Sunk cost examples….? Sunk costs affect the total cost of a decision Sunk costs do not affect marginal costs So sunk costs do not affect the best choice 3-43

Car Repair Example: Best Choice with a Sunk Cost Figure 3.9 shows a cost-benefit comparison for two possible cost functions with sunk fixed costs: $500 and $1100. In both cases, the best choice is H = 3.4: the level of sunk costs has no effect on the best choice Notice that the slopes of the two total cost curves, and thus the marginal costs, are the same 3-44

Best Choice with a Sunk Cost (Figure 3.9) 500 Hours (H) C C´C´ B Total Benefit, Total Cost ($)

More Sunk Costs Knowing what will happen before the money is sunk can prevent you from even spending the initial money. Chunnel Example est. cost = 3 B. Pounds 1987 est. revenue = 4 B sunk cost = 2.5 B est. addit. Cost = 2 B. Finish or abandon project? Why? 3-46

Summary Maximize benefits less cost Best choice yields the highest net benefit of all alternatives Thinking on the Margin Looking at marginal benefits can influence decision making No Marginal Improvement Principle… Sunk Costs The size of the sunk costs has no effect on the best choice. The act of sinking a cost can matter 3-47

Problem “If the cost of repairing your car goes up, you should do less of it.” Is this statement correct? If you think the answer is yes, explain why. If you think the answer is no, give an example in which the best choice is higher when the cost is higher. 3-48

Problems “If the cost of repairing your car goes up, you should do less of it.” If this statement correct? If you think the answer is yes, explain why. If you think the answer is no, give an example in which the best choice is higher when the cost is higher. In the absence of any other changes (specifically changes to benefits), this statement is correct. The only way that a higher cost could inspire a higher best choice would be if the benefits also increase, and if the benefits increased by more than the costs. (Note that if benefits and costs both increase by the same amount, the best choice should remain unchanged.) 3-49

Problems Chunnel Example est. cost = 3 B. Pounds 1987 est. revenue = 4 B sunk cost = 2.5 B est. addit. Cost = 2 B. Finish or abandon project? Why? How much could the additional costs add up to before the Chunnel project would be abandoned…why? 3-50

Problem How much could the additional costs add up to before the Chunnel project would be abandoned…why? Once the investors expenses are incurred, they are sunk and no longer relevant to a decision to continue or no. If the cost of quitting is ₤0, the benefit of abandoning the project is also ₤0, since there would be no revenue earned. So, we need to compare the benefit to the cost of completing the project. The benefit of completing the project is ₤4 million in revenue that they expect to earn. If the cost of completing the project is ₤X million, then the net benefit is ₤(4 – X) million. So long as X < 4, this net benefit would be positive, making it greater than the net benefit of quitting. In other words, given that the initial ₤2.5 million is a sunk cost, investors will complete the project as long as they can break even starting from the present. 3-51