A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time Carl Lindberg 2006-10-06.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Chapter 9: Factor pricing models
Advertisements

COMM 472: Quantitative Analysis of Financial Decisions
LECTURE 8 : FACTOR MODELS
Chapter 11 Optimal Portfolio Choice
Performance Evaluation and Active Portfolio Management
FINANCE 8. Capital Markets and The Pricing of Risk Professor André Farber Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles Fall 2007.
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter.
LECTURE 5 : PORTFOLIO THEORY
Today Risk and Return Reading Portfolio Theory
Empirical Financial Economics 4. Asset pricing and Mean Variance Efficiency Stephen Brown NYU Stern School of Business UNSW PhD Seminar, June
Mutual Investment Club of Cornell Week 8: Portfolio Theory April 7 th, 2011.
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
Chapter 6 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
CORPORATE FINANCIAL THEORY Lecture 2. Risk /Return Return = r = Discount rate = Cost of Capital (COC) r is determined by risk Two Extremes Treasury Notes.
The Lognormal Distribution
AN INTRODUCTION TO PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
1 ASSET ALLOCATION. 2 With Riskless Asset 3 Mean Variance Relative to a Benchmark.
Chapter 2 Diversification and Risky Asset Allocation
Ewa Lukasik - Jakub Lawik - Juan Mojica - Xiaodong Xu.
Topic 4: Portfolio Concepts. Mean-Variance Analysis Mean–variance portfolio theory is based on the idea that the value of investment opportunities can.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible website, in whole or in part. Chapter.
Version 1.2 Copyright © 2000 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any part of the work should be mailed to:
Portfolio Management-Learning Objective
Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Seventh Edition by Frank K. Reilly & Keith C. Brown Chapter 7.
STOCHASTIC DOMINANCE APPROACH TO PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION Nesrin Alptekin Anadolu University, TURKEY.
Some Background Assumptions Markowitz Portfolio Theory
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management Chapter 7.
Empirical Financial Economics Asset pricing and Mean Variance Efficiency.
Chapter 13 CAPM and APT Investments
Capital Market Theory Chapter 20 Jones, Investments: Analysis and Management.
Investment and portfolio management MGT 531. Investment and portfolio management  MGT 531.
Lecture 10 The Capital Asset Pricing Model Expectation, variance, standard error (deviation), covariance, and correlation of returns may be based on.
© Markus Rudolf Page 1 Intertemporal Surplus Management BFS meeting Internet-Page: Intertemporal Surplus Management 1. Basics.
TOPIC THREE Chapter 4: Understanding Risk and Return By Diana Beal and Michelle Goyen.
And, now take you into a WORLD of……………...
Online Financial Intermediation. Types of Intermediaries Brokers –Match buyers and sellers Retailers –Buy products from sellers and resell to buyers Transformers.
STRATEGIC FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Hurdle Rate: The Basics of Risk II KHURAM RAZA.
Chapter 06 Risk and Return. Value = FCF 1 FCF 2 FCF ∞ (1 + WACC) 1 (1 + WACC) ∞ (1 + WACC) 2 Free cash flow (FCF) Market interest rates Firm’s business.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk.
1 Derivatives & Risk Management: Part II Models, valuation and risk management.
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
MEIE811D Advanced Topics in Finance Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model Yuna Rhee Seyong Park Robert C. Merton (1971) [Journal.
Computational Finance 1/34 Panos Parpas Asset Pricing Models 381 Computational Finance Imperial College London.
Fundamentals of Futures and Options Markets, 5 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull Value at Risk Chapter 18.
Chp.5 Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous Time Model Hai Lin Department of Finance, Xiamen University.
Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management First Canadian Edition By Reilly, Brown, Hedges, Chang 6.
Value at Risk Chapter 16. The Question Being Asked in VaR “What loss level is such that we are X % confident it will not be exceeded in N business days?”
Finance 300 Financial Markets Lecture 3 Fall, 2001© Professor J. Petry
Risk and Return: Portfolio Theory and Assets Pricing Models
PORTFOLIO OPTIMISATION. AGENDA Introduction Theoretical contribution Perceived role of Real estate in the Mixed-asset Portfolio Methodology Results Sensitivity.
Return and Risk: The Asset-Pricing Model: CAPM and APT.
Primbs1 Receding Horizon Control for Constrained Portfolio Optimization James A. Primbs Management Science and Engineering Stanford University (with Chang.
Chapter 7 An Introduction to Portfolio Management.
OPTIONS PRICING AND HEDGING WITH GARCH.THE PRICING KERNEL.HULL AND WHITE.THE PLUG-IN ESTIMATOR AND GARCH GAMMA.ENGLE-MUSTAFA – IMPLIED GARCH.DUAN AND EXTENSIONS.ENGLE.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Risk and Return: Capital Market Theory Chapter 8.
Expected Return and Risk. Explain how expected return and risk for securities are determined. Explain how expected return and risk for portfolios are.
1 CAPM & APT. 2 Capital Market Theory: An Overview u Capital market theory extends portfolio theory and develops a model for pricing all risky assets.
Capital Market Theory: An Overview
Chapter 10 Capital Markets and the Pricing of Risk
Market-Risk Measurement
Topic 4: Portfolio Concepts
Return and Risk: The Capital Asset Pricing Models: CAPM and APT
Portfolio Risk Management : A Primer
TOPIC 3.1 CAPITAL MARKET THEORY
Saif Ullah Lecture Presentation Software to accompany Investment Analysis and.
Financial Market Theory
The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 2000
Corporate Financial Theory
Presentation transcript:

A 1/n strategy and Markowitz' problem in continuous time Carl Lindberg

Topics I.Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem II.A new stock price model III.The optimal strategy

I. Portfolio optimization and Markowitz’ problem’s problem 1.Introduction to portfolio optimization 2.Markowitz’ one-period problem 3.The Black-Scholes model 4.Markowitz’ problem in continuous time 5.The problem with estimating rates of return 

1. Introduction to portfolio optimization Natural idea: The investor wants to make money on the stock market Specify stochastic model for stock prices Fit model to data Choose optimality criterion Calculate optimal trading strategy

2. Markowitz’ one-period problem Stock return model Correlated normal variables One-period Investor trades in n stocks at time 0, holds position until time T. Trading strategies  i : Proportion of initial wealth W(0) held in stock i 1-   n : Proportion of W(0) held in bond Markowitz  =(  1,...,  n ) Find strategy  =(  1,...,  n ) that minimizes variance of terminal wealth W  (T) while expected growth larger than predetermined constant

Stock prices: volatilitiesBrownian motions independent 3. The Black-Scholes model Black-Scholes is the standard model in finance: Mathematically tractable: Stocks are geometric Brownian motions Theoretically convenient: Market arbitrage free and complete Fits data reasonably well Parameters can in principle be estimated using normal statistical theory

4. Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Stock price model Black-Scholes model Continuous time Investor can trade in all n stocks at all times Trading strategies  i (t): Proportion of wealth W(t) held in stock i at time t 1-  1 (t)-...-  n (t): Proportion of W(t) held in bond at time t Markowitz  (t)=(  1 (t),...,  n (t)) Find admissible strategy  (t)=(  1 (t),...,  n (t)) that minimizes variance of terminal wealth W  (T) while expected growth larger than predetermined constant: Progressively measurable and bounded

5. The problem with estimating rates of return  Portfolio optimization has not received the same attention from the financial industry as option pricing theory The predominant explanation is that the rates of return are very hard to estimate accurately This gives extremely unstable portfolio weights when we apply the optimal strategies with parameters estimated from data with standard statistical methods

5. The problem with estimating rates of return  Assume yearly returns for a stock are i.i.d. N( ,  ),  = 0.20 A 95% confidence interval for  is [Ŷ-1.96  /√n, Ŷ+1.96  /√n], where n is the number of yearly observations DATA FOR n=6147 YEARS IS NEEDED TO GET AN INTERVAL OF WIDTH 0.01!!! WE NEED MORE THAN NAÏVE STATISTICS (A common approach in the industry is to use linear models with some suitable predictors)

II. A new stock price model 1.The new model 2.Equal company risk premiums 3.Covariance and volatility 4.Examples

1. The new model Black-Scholes parameterized as continuous time n-index Arbitrage Pricing Theory model with equal risk premiums: Same for all j ”Index”

2. Equal company risk premiums One interpretation: Stocks are governed by n independent factors (indexes), each associated with a specific underlying company Since we have no additional information on any company, the risk premium  - r should be the same for all of them Equal risk premiums gives coherence between the rates of return. This is not obtained by estimating the rates of return for each stock individually

Classical Mathematical Finance: Volatility matrix  only used to model dependence between stocks We can do more: A covariance matrix does not give a unique volatility matrix Our model: Volatility matrix  decides rates of return, too The investor can incorporate her views on specific stocks in the market model: She can choose a volatility matrix which implies relations between the rates of returns that she believes to hold 3. Covariance and volatility

4. Examples: Cholesky decomposition Assume that the investor has specified ranks for the stock risk premiums (SRP) for the n stocks: The stock with the lowest SRP is assigned rank 1, the second lowest rank 2, and so on.

4. Examples: Cholesky decomposition Cholesky decomposition of the covariance matrix sorted by ranks gives a volatility matrix with clear tendency of assigning low SRP to stocks with low ranks A stock with high rank is affected by some factors that do not influence stocks with lower rank. This makes the stock ”more diversified”, hence it is likely to have higher SRP

5. Examples: Matrix square root Condition: All n companies are (approximately) equally important to each other Assumption: Stock i depends as much on what happens to corporation j, as stock j depends on what happens to corporation i Consequence: The volatility matrix should be symmetric A symmetric volatility matrix is obtained by applying the matrix square root to the covariance matrix

5. Examples: Other alternatives Any volatility matrix with a specified covariance matrix can be written as the Cholesky decomposition multiplied by an orthogonal matrix Sparse volatility matrix –Assume conditional independence between different stocks given some factors, verify with statistical analysis –Use to assign ranks to groups of stocks, similarly to Cholesky decomposition

III. The optimal strategy 1.Main goals 2.The 1/n strategy 3.An explicit solution  * to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time 4.The 1/n strategy in factors 5.Advantages 6.Increasing the number of stocks 7.Applying the strategy  * to data

1. Main goals Goal I: Optimal strategies that are robust to misspecification of model parameters Goal II: Investors can specify their unique market views through the optimal strategy without having to decide on exact numbers for the individual rates of return

2. The 1/n strategy The investor puts 1/n of her wealth in each of n available assets Advantage: No estimation of rates of return Disadvantages: –Ignores dependence between stocks: Dependence can be estimated well  We should use it –Not very low risk: Few factors determine much of dependence between stocks  1/n not really diversified

3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time We assume our new model Markowitz: Wealth: for the processes Progressively measurable and bounded Functions of 

3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time But the optimal strategy  * must be constant, deterministic, and equal for every stock j This implies that the variance subject to the growth constraint is minimized by

3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Hence, for sufficiently wide bounds on the admissible strategies the optimal strategy  * solves for all t

3. An explicit solution to Markowitz’ problem in continuous time Optimal wealth process: Equality in law

4. The 1/n strategy in factors The strategy  * Prescribes that the investor should hold 1/n of her wealth in each factor/Brownian motion. The optimal strategy  * is in this sense the most diversified strategy of all Gives the optimal expected wealth of all portfolios with the same variance   * is efficient

5. Advantages We can expect stability of the portfolio weights when we use the optimal strategy  * with parameters estimated from data. The reason is that the strategy  * is based on estimates of the volatility matrix The investor need not supply explicit estimates of rates of return to apply the optimal strategies. This is due to the natural coherence assumption that all corporations have the same company risk premiums

5. Advantages The optimal strategy  * can be applied without estimating values for the risk premium or choosing the required expected return : The investor’s views are obtained implicitly by the fraction of her wealth that she chooses to invest in the stock market. This choice corresponds also to the investor's risk-aversion No utility function has to be selected. This is often required in classical optimal portfolio theory The investor may still play a part….

6. Increasing the number of stocks The figures show that the higher expected return the investor requires, the more she will have to risk. Nonetheless, the risk will still tend to zero as the number of stocks n increases. Left: Distributions of optimal wealth at time T=1 for different n with parameters w=1, λ=0.1, μ=0.2, and r=0.03 Right: Distributions of optimal wealth at time T=1 for different n with parameters w=1, λ=0.3, μ=0.2, and r=0.03 — n=200 — n=100 — n=50 — n=25 — n=200 — n=100 — n=50 — n=25

7. Applying the strategy  * to data 48 value weighted industry portfolios consisting of each stock at NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ Data from to The covariance matrix is estimated with five years of data, and it is updated each month. The optimal strategy  * is applied out-of-sample We assume that the industry portfolios are approximately equally important to each other: We apply the matrix square root to the covariance matrix to get the volatility matrix

7. Applying the strategy  * to data Normal distributions estimated from returns: 1-   n Blue: The wealth process for the strategy  * with 1-   n =0 Red: The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Green: Industry portfolio with smallest volatility Magenta: Industry portfolio with largest volatility

7. Applying the strategy  * to data Portfolio processes: 1-   n Blue thick line: The wealth process for the strategy  * with 1-   n =0 Red thick line: The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Green thick line: The industry portfolio with smallest volatility Magenta thick line: The industry portfolio with largest volatility Colored thin lines: Individual industry portfolios

7. Applying the strategy  * to data Sharpe ratios: 1-   n Blue horizontal line: The wealth process for the strategy  * with 1-   n =0 Red horizontal line: The wealth process for the 1/N strategy Blue stars: Individual industry portfolios Memmel’s corrected Jobson & Korkie test of the hypothesis of equal Sharpe ratios between the wealth processes for the strategies  * and  = 1/N gets a p-value of <<0.0001