In the modern global economy:... each country could be economically self-sufficient (producing everything it consumes). In fact, countries tend to specialize.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Advertisements

Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
G AINS FROM T RADE ETP Economics 101 Lecturer: Jack Wu.
Interdependence and The Gains From Trade
Chapter 3 Interdependence and the Gains From Trade
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade. Copyright © 2004 South-Western Consider your typical day: You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. You.
Chapter Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 3.
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.  Consider your typical day: You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. You pour yourself orange juice made.
2 2 International Trade and Comparative Advantage No nation was ever ruined by trade. BENJAMIN FRANKLIN International Trade and Comparative Advantage No.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Consider your typical day: You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. You pour yourself orange juice made from Florida.
International Trade When individuals or countries specialize in the activity they do best, the overall economic pie increases.
Interdependence and the Gains From Trade
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade. Consider your typical day You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. You pour yourself orange juice made.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence* and the Gains from Trade Vísar til þess að þjóðfélög eru gagnkvæmt háð hvert öðru.
Chapter by Nelson, a division of Thomson Canada Limited Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade Chapter 3 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to make copies of any.
Dr. David P Echevarria1All Rights Reserved LECTURE #2: MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 3 Specialization Comparative Advantage Opportunity Costs.
Gains from Trade and Division of Labor Interdependence versus Subsistence J.F. O’Connor.
Chapter 3: Interdependence and the Gains from Trade Chapter 3: Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. Interdependence and Trade Remember, economics is the study of how societies produce.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Consider your typical day: You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. You pour yourself orange juice made from Florida.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade © 2015 Cengage Learning. All Rights.
Chapter 3 Interdependence and the Gains From Trade Ratna K. Shrestha.
Principles of Microeconomics & Principles of Macroeconomics: Ch. 3 First Canadian Edition Interdependence and Trade Economics studies how society produces.
Chapter Scarcity and Choice 2. Chapter How People Interact Principle 5: Trade can make everyone better off Trade – Specialization Allows each person/country.
Trade and Interdependence. Minutes needed to make one ounce of: Amount produced in 8 hours: MeatPotatoesMeatPotatoes Farmer60 min/oz.15 min/oz.8 oz.32.
PowerPoint Presentations for Principles of Microeconomics Sixth Canadian Edition by Mankiw/Kneebone/McKenzie Adapted for the Sixth Canadian Edition by.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Chapter 3 Exchange and Markets. Consider your typical day –You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea. –You pour yourself orange juice made from Florida.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Chapter 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Why do we trade? Comparative Advantage. Benefits of trade  Consider your typical day:  You wake up to an alarm clock made in Korea.  You pour yourself.
Ch 3: Interdependence and Gains from Trade Intro: --Satisfy your wants by: self sufficiency or specialize and trade --You rely on others around the world.
Week 1 Quick Review. The opportunity cost of meat and potatoes 1 2 Opportunity cost of: 1 oz of Meat1 oz of Potatoes Farmer Rancher 4 oz potatoes 2 oz.
Module Comparative Advantage and Trade KRUGMAN'S MACROECONOMICS for AP* 4 Margaret Ray and David Anderson.
PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University Interdependence and the Gains from Trade 1 © 2011 Cengage Learning. All Rights.
Dolan, Microeconomics 4e, Ch. 15 Survey of Economics Edwin G. Dolan and Kevin C. Klein Best Value Textbooks 4 th edition Chapter 15 Global Trade and Trade.
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade. Consider your typical day: – You wake up to an alarm clock made in ______. – You pour yourself orange juice.
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade. Consider your typical day: – You wake up to an alarm clock made in ______. – You pour yourself orange juice.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western/Thomson Learning 3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade.
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
INTERDEPENDENCE AND THE GAINS FROM TRADE
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
3 Interdependence and the Gains from Trade CHAPTER
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Chapter 3: Interdependence and the Gains From Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Look at your clothes, bag and anything you have on you
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
Interdependence and the Gains from Trade
© 2007 Thomson South-Western
Presentation transcript:

In the modern global economy:... each country could be economically self-sufficient (producing everything it consumes). In fact, countries tend to specialize and trade with others, leading to economic interdependence. Two key questions: 1. Why is interdependence the norm? (Apparently people are better off when they specialize and trade with others -- remember basic principle #5.) But why are they better off with specialization and trade?

2. What determines the pattern of production and trade? Let’s start with a simple parable: Two people (Bob and Dave) are marooned on a tropical island. Two food sources available: fish and bananas. (both required for survival)

One possibility: The economic self-sufficiency (“no-trade”) case: Each cast-away does some fishing, and some banana-picking, and each consumes the products of his own labors. Now suppose that Bob is better at fishing than Dave, and... Dave is better at banana-picking than Bob.

Obvious: Gains from trade are possible. Bob specializes in fishing. Dave specializes in banana-picking. Then trade. (Bob gives some fish to Dave in exchange for some bananas.) Not so obvious (but very! important to understand): Gains from trade may be possible even if... Bob is better at fishing than Dave, and... Bob is better at banana-picking than Dave.

To see why, let’s “shift gears” to another kind of parable: the text’s farmer/rancher, potato/meat example. Two producers: “farmer” and “rancher” Two goods: “potatoes” and “meat” Both producers can produce both goods, but they have different production opportunities.

Production opportunities for the farmer and the rancher

No trade (self-sufficiency) case: Farmer’s consumption possibilities are the same as his production possibilities. Same is true for rancher. Which points on ppfs will each chose to produce and consume? It depends. Assume (it doesn’t really matter) that they split their time equally between meat and potato production.

Farmer’s production possibilities potatoes (oz.day) meat (oz./day) Farmer’s production and consumption point (no-trade case)

Rancher’s production possibilities potatoes (oz.day) meat (oz./day) Ranchers’ production and consumption point (no-trade case)

Now consider an alternative case with specialization and trade:

potatoes (oz.day) meat (oz./day) Farmer’s production and consumption (with specialization and trade) Farmer’s production and consumption without trade Farmer’s production with trade 17 5 Farmer’s consumption with trade

potatoes (oz.day) meat (oz./day) Rancher’s production and consumption without trade Rancher’s production with trade Rancher’s consumption with trade Rancher’s production and consumption (with specialization and trade)

Gains from trade: Compared to the “no-trade” case, specialization and trade enables the farmer to consumer more meat and more potatoes. Same is true for the rancher. To put it another way: Specialization and trade enables both to consume beyond their production possibility frontiers. What’s the economic principle at work here?

Recall: Absolute advantage: The comparison among producers on the basis of resource cost. The producer who has the smaller resource cost (requires a smaller quantity of input to produce a given output) is said to have an absolute advantage over the other. The rancher has the absolute advantage over the farmer in the production of meat and potatoes.

Opportunity cost: The cost of an item measured in terms of what you give up to get it.

Comparative advantage: The comparison among producers of a good according to their opportunity cost. The producer who has the smaller opportunity cost is said to have a comparative advantage over the other. The rancher has the comparative advantage over the farmer in the production of meat but (!) the farmer has the comparative advantage over the rancher in the production of potatoes.

Here’s the main point: Differences in opportunity cost (comparative advantage) make possible gains from specialization and trade. Gains are realized when each party specializes in the production of the good in which he or she has a comparative advantage,... then trade. How does it work in this specific example?

Given the “terms of trade” (5 oz. of meat for 15 oz. of potatoes): “Trade price” of meat is 3 oz. of potatoes/oz. of meat... but this is lower than the farmer’s opportunity cost of meat (4 oz. of potatoes/oz. of meat) Trade (of potatoes for meat) is beneficial for the farmer. He can acquire meat more cheaply through trade than through a reallocation of his own labor effort.

But (very important “but”) before the farmer can trade, there has to be someone else willing to take the “other end of the deal.” (If I want to sell you a car... and you want to sell me a car -- No sale!) “Trade price” of potatoes is 1/3 oz. of meat/oz. of potatoes... and this is lower than the rancher’s opportunity cost of potatoes (1/2 oz. of meat/oz. of potatoes)

Trade (of meat for potatoes) is beneficial for the rancher. She can acquire potatoes more cheaply through trade than through a reallocation of her own labor effort. As long as opportunity costs differ, we can always find a “split-the-difference” trade price that makes the two parties willing to accept opposite ends of the trade. Differences in opportunity cost (comparative advantage) make mutually beneficial trade possible.

Trade price 3 oz. potatoes/ 1/3 oz. meat/ of: oz. of meat oz. of potatoes

Real-world lessons? In international trade (trade among nations),... trade can be mutually beneficial,... and the predominant pattern of trade flows should be consistent with comparative advantage. Generally speaking, countries should export products in which they have a comparative advantage, and import products in which their trading partners have a comparative advantage.

Consider the U.S. and Japan and trade in manufactured products vs. agricultural commodities. Some would argue that Japan has an absolute advantage in production of manufactured products. (more modern management techniques, more conscientious workers -- maybe) The U.S. definitely has an absolute and comparative advantage in the production of agricultural commodities. (more and better crop land, favorable climate)

So the U.S. has the comparative advantage over Japan in the production of agricultural commodities. (Japan has the comparative advantage over the U.S. in the production of manufactured goods.) Theory says we should see (mainly):... U.S. exports of agricultural commodities to Japan... and Japanese exports of manufactured products to the U.S.

Theory of comparative advantage and gains from trade is the reason why economists usually oppose “trade barriers.” From Chapter 2: “Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990s?” American Economic Review, May “Tariffs and import quotas usually reduce general economic welfare” 93% of surveyed economists agreed! (Much more on this in Chapter 9.)