Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
28 INFLATION CHAPTER.
Advertisements

© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation.
Introduction Until now, we assumed P was “stuck” in the short run, implying a horizontal SRAS curve. Now, we consider two prominent models of aggregate.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment
Macroeconomics fifth edition N. Gregory Mankiw PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich macro © 2002 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved Topic 11: Aggregate.
Monetary Policy: Goals and Tradeoffs
Chapter 28 Inflation: Causes and Consequences. Copyright © 2005 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Figure 28.1 Consumer Price Level in.
1 Chapter 21 The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment The Phillips Curve Shifts in the Phillips Curve: the role of expectations Shifts.
10. The Relationship between Unemployment and Inflation
Chapter 11 Classical Business Cycle Analysis: Market-Clearing Macroeconomics Copyright © 2012 Pearson Education Inc.
Chapter 13 Unemployment and Inflation Economics 282 University of Alberta.
The Short-Run Policy Tradeoff CHAPTER 17 When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Describe.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment Chapter 33 Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved. Requests for permission to.
Copyright © 2004 South-Western 22 The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment.
Economics 282 University of Alberta
The Short-Run Trade-off between Inflation and Unemployment
Can we have low unemployment and low inflation? Or must we pay for lower inflation with higher unemployment?
Classical Business Cycle Analysis: Market-Clearing Macroeconomics
Expectations and Macroeconomics Chapter Introduction We have put together a complete model of aggregate demand, supply and wage adjustment.
The Relationship Between Inflation and Unemployment
Quantity Theory, Inflation, and the Demand for Money
Orange Group. The natural rate of unemployment depends on various features of the labor market. Examples include minimum-wage laws, the market power of.
When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T Describe the short-run policy tradeoff between.
© 2009 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Economics Hubbard/O’Brien UPDATE EDITION. Fernando & Yvonn Quijano Prepared by: Chapter 28 Inflation, Unemployment,
Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Short Run Trade Off Between Inflation and Unemployment ETP Economics 102 Jack Wu.
Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation. I.Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? (Sec. 12.1) A)Many people think there is a trade-off between.
Matching History and Theory Keynesian Stimulus 1) Keynesian Stimulus – 1930’s 1)Fine tuning in the 1960’s.
Unemployment ● Causes of Unemployment ● The Phillips Curve ● Natural Rate of Unemployment ● Okun's Law.
ECONOMICS 5e CHAPTER 16 Inflation Michael Parkin
MACROECONOMICS © 2013 Worth Publishers, all rights reserved PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich N. Gregory Mankiw Aggregate Supply and the Short-Run Tradeoff.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 12-1 Chapter Outline Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade- Off? The Problem of Unemployment.
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Education. All rights reserved. Business Cycles Chapter 8.
© 2013 Pearson. Can we have low unemployment and low inflation?
Harcourt, Inc. items and derived items copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. The Phillips Curve In 1958, British economist A.W. Phillips wrote an article.
Lecture 4. The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment Week 12 1Pengantar Ekonomi 2.
Copyright © 2010 Cengage Learning 10 The Short-Run Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment.
Copyright © 2001 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. Slide Inflation, Aggregate Demand, and Aggregate Supply.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western. Short-Run Trade-Off between Inflation and Unemployment Unemployment and Inflation –The natural rate of unemployment depends.
Chapter 22 Quantity Theory, Inflation and the Demand for Money
Copyright © 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. Chapter 24 From the Short Run to the Long Run: The Adjustment of Factor Prices.
INFLATION 12 CHAPTER. Objectives After studying this chapter, you will able to  Distinguish between inflation and a one-time rise in the price level.
Chapter 13 Unemployment and Inflation Copyright © 2016 Pearson Canada Inc.
© 2007 Thomson South-Western, all rights reserved N. G R E G O R Y M A N K I W PowerPoint ® Slides by Ron Cronovich 22 P R I N C I P L E S O F F O U R.
16-1 Copyright © 2012 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. C H A P T E R 16 The Dynamics of Inflation and Unemployment Copyright © 2012 Pearson.
Short Run Trade Off Between Inflation and Unemployment ETP Economics 102 Jack Wu.
The Short-run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved 9-1 Chapter Outline The FE Line: Equilibrium in the Labor Market The IS Curve: Equilibrium in the Goods.
{ Monetary Policy Explored Tools, application, inflation & unemployment.
Eco 200 – Principles of Macroeconomics Chapter 15: Macroeconomic Policy.
Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation. Copyright ©2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All rights reserved.12-2 Chapter Outline Unemployment and Inflation: Is.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation.
© 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license.
Chapter The Short-Run Trade-off between Inflation and Unemployment 22.
CHAPTER OUTLINE 13 The AD /AS Model Dr. Neri’s Expanded Discussion of AD / AS Fiscal Policy Fiscal Policy Effects in the Long Run Monetary Policy Shocks.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment.
Copyright © 2005 Pearson Education Canada Inc.15-1 Chapter 15 Issues in Stabilization Policy.
Intermediate Macro: Unemployment & Inflation (the twin evils of Macro) Jeffrey H. Nilsen.
© 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation.
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment
Short Run Trade Off Between Inflation and Unemployment
The Short-Run Tradeoff between Inflation and Unemployment
Short Run Trade Off Between Inflation and Unemployment
Chapter 12 Lecture - Unemployment and Inflation
Inflation and Aggregate Supply
Presentation transcript:

Chapter 12 Unemployment and Inflation

Chapter Outline Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-Off? Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve The Problem of Unemployment The Problem of Inflation Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? Many people think there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment The idea originated in 1958 when A.W. Phillips showed a negative relationship between unemployment and nominal wage growth in Britain Since then economists have looked at the relationship between unemployment and inflation In the 1950s and 1960s many nations seemed to have a negative relationship between the two variables The United States appears to be on one Phillips curve in the 1960s (Fig. 12.1)

Figure 12.1 The Phillips curve and the U.S. economy during the 1960s Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database at research.stlouisfed.org/fred2, series CPIAUCSL and UNRATE.

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? Many people think there is a trade-off between inflation and unemployment This suggested that policymakers could choose the combination of unemployment and inflation they most desired But the relationship fell apart in the following three decades (Fig. 12.2) The 1970s were a particularly bad period, with both high inflation and high unemployment, inconsistent with the Phillips curve

Figure 12.2 Inflation and unemployment in the United States Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database at research.stlouisfed.org/fred2, series CPIAUCSL and UNRATE.

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The expectations-augmented Phillips curve Friedman and Phelps: The cyclical unemployment rate (the difference between actual and natural unemployment rates) depends only on unanticipated inflation (the difference between actual and expected inflation) This theory was made before the Phillips curve began breaking down in the 1970s It suggests that the relationship between inflation and the unemployment rate isn’t stable

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The expectations-augmented Phillips curve How does this work in the extended classical model? First case: anticipated increase in money supply (Fig. 12.3) AD shifts up and SRAS shifts up, with no misperceptions Result: P rises, Y unchanged Inflation rises with no change in unemployment

Figure 12.3 Ongoing inflation in the extended classical model

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The expectations-augmented Phillips curve How does this work in the extended classical model? Second case: unanticipated increase in money supply (Fig. 12.4) AD expected to shift up to AD2,old (money supply expected to rise 10%), but unexpectedly money supply rises 15%, so AD shifts further up to AD2,new SRAS shifts up based on expected 10% rise in money supply Result: P rises and Y rises as misperceptions occur So higher inflation occurs with lower unemployment Long run: P rises further, Y declines to full-employment level

Figure 12.4 Unanticipated inflation in the extended classical model

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The expectations-augmented Phillips curve (12.1) When   e, u  When   e, u  When   e, u 

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve The Phillips curve shows the relationship between unemployment and inflation for a given expected rate of inflation and natural rate of unemployment Changes in the expected rate of inflation (Fig. 12.5)

Figure 12.5 The shifting Phillips curve: an increase in expected inflation

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve Changes in the expected rate of inflation (Fig. 12.5) For a given expected rate of inflation, the Phillips curve shows the trade-off between cyclical unemployment and actual inflation The Phillips curve is drawn such that   e when u  Higher expected inflation implies a higher Phillips curve

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve Changes in the natural rate of unemployment (Fig. 12.6) For a given natural rate of unemployment, the Phillips curve shows the trade-off between unemployment and unanticipated inflation A higher natural rate of unemployment shifts the Phillips curve to the right

Figure 12.6 The shifting Phillips curve: an increase in the natural unemployment rate

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? Supply shocks and the Phillips curve A supply shock increases both expected inflation and the natural rate of unemployment A supply shock in the classical model increases the natural rate of unemployment, because it increases the mismatch between firms and workers A supply shock in the Keynesian model reduces the marginal product of labor and thus reduces labor demand at the fixed real wage, so the natural unemployment rate rises

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? Supply shocks and the Phillips curve So an adverse supply shock shifts the Phillips curve up and to the right The Phillips curve will be unstable in periods with many supply shocks

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve in practice Why did the original Phillips curve relationship apply to many historical cases? The original relationship between inflation and unemployment holds up as long as expected inflation and the natural rate of unemployment are approximately constant This was true in the United States in the 1960s, so the Phillips curve appeared to be stable

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve in practice Why did the U.S. Phillips curve disappear after 1970? Both the expected inflation rate and the natural rate of unemployment varied considerably more in the 1970s than they did in the 1960s Especially important were the oil price shocks of 1973–1974 and 1979–1980 Also, the composition of the labor force changed in the 1970s and there were other structural changes in the economy as well, raising the natural rate of unemployment

Unemployment and Inflation: Is There a Trade-off? The shifting Phillips curve in practice Why did the U.S. Phillips curve disappear after 1970? Monetary policy was expansionary in the 1970s, leading to high and volatile inflation Plotting unanticipated inflation against cyclical unemployment shows a fairly stable relationship since 1970 (Fig. 12.7)

Figure 12.7 The expectations-augmented Phillips curve in the United States, 1970-2011 Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database at research.stlouisfed.org/fred2, series CPIAUCSL (inflation) and UNRATE (unemployment rate); expected inflation: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Livingston Survey at www.philadelphiafed.org; natural rate of unemployment: Congressional Budget Office, www.cbo. gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10014/Mar09Web_Tbl_potential.xls.

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve Can the Phillips curve be exploited by policymakers? Can they choose the optimal combination of unemployment and inflation? Classical model: NO Keynesian model: YES, temporarily

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve Can the Phillips curve be exploited by policymakers? Classical model: NO The unemployment rate returns to its natural level quickly, as people’s expectations adjust So unemployment can change from its natural level only for a very brief time Also, people catch on to policy games; they have rational expectations and try to anticipate policy changes, so there is no way to fool people systematically

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve Can the Phillips curve be exploited by policymakers? Keynesian model: YES, temporarily The expected rate of inflation in the Phillips curve is the forecast of inflation at the time the oldest sticky prices were set It takes time for prices and expected prices to adjust, so unemployment may differ from the natural rate for some time

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve In touch with data and research: The Lucas critique When the rules of the game change, behavior changes For example, if batters in baseball were called out after two strikes instead of three, they’d swing more often when they have one strike than they do now Lucas applied this idea to macroeconomics, arguing that historical relationships between variables won’t hold up if there’s been a major policy change

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve In touch with data and research: The Lucas critique The Phillips curve is a good example—it fell apart as soon as policymakers tried to exploit it Evaluating policy requires an understanding of how behavior will change under the new policy, so both economic theory and empirical analysis are necessary

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve The long-run Phillips curve Long run: the u  for both Keynesians and classicals The long-run Phillips curve is vertical, since when   e, then (Figure 12.8)

Figure 12.8 The long-run Phillips curve

Macroeconomic Policy and the Phillips Curve The long-run Phillips curve Changes in the level of money supply have no long-run real effects; changes in the growth rate of money supply have no long-run real effects, either Even though expansionary policy may reduce unemployment only temporarily, policymakers may want to do so if, for example, timing economic booms right before elections helps them (or their political allies) get reelected

The Problem of Unemployment The costs of unemployment Loss in output from idle resources Workers lose income Society pays for unemployment benefits and makes up lost tax revenue Using Okun’s Law (each percentage point of cyclical unemployment is associated with a loss equal to 2% of full-employment output), if full-employment output is $17 trillion, each percentage point of unemployment sustained for one year costs $340 billion

The Problem of Unemployment The costs of unemployment Personal or psychological cost to workers and their families Especially important for those with long spells of unemployment There are some offsetting factors Unemployment leads to increased job search and acquiring new skills, which may lead to increased future output Unemployed workers have increased leisure time, though most wouldn’t feel that the increased leisure compensated them for being unemployed

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate The changing natural rate How do we calculate the natural rate of unemployment? CBO’s estimates: 6% today, similar to 1970s and 1980s; much higher than it was in 1960s, 1990s, and 2000s

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate The changing natural rate In the 1980s and 1990s, demographic forces reduced the natural rate of unemployment (Fig. 12.9) The proportion of the labor force aged 16–24 years fell from 25% in 1980 to 16% in 1998 Research by Shimer showed this is the main reason for the fall in the natural rate of unemployment

Figure 12.9 Actual and natural unemployment rates in the United States, 1960–2011 Sources: Actual unemployment rate, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED database at research.stlouisfed.org/fred2, series UNRATE; natural rate of unemployment: Congressional Budget Office, www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/100xx/doc10014/Mar09Web_Tbl_potential.xls.

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate The changing natural rate Some economists think the natural rate of unemployment was 4.5% or even lower in the 1990s and 2000s The labor market became more efficient at matching workers and jobs, reducing frictional and structural unemployment Temporary help agencies became prominent, helping the matching process and reducing the natural rate of unemployment

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate The changing natural rate Increased labor productivity may increase the natural rate of unemployment If increases in real wages lag changes in productivity, firms hire more workers and the natural rate of unemployment will decline temporarily Ball and Mankiw found evidence supporting this hypothesis in the 1990s

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate Measuring the natural rate of unemployment Policymakers need a measure of the natural rate of unemployment to use the unemployment rate for setting policy Economists disagree about how to measure the natural rate of unemployment and the CBO has often revised its measure

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate Measuring the natural rate of unemployment Staiger, Stock, and Watson found that the natural rate cannot be measured precisely with econometric methods, as the confidence interval is very large

The Problem of Unemployment The long-term behavior of the unemployment rate Measuring the natural rate of unemployment What should policymakers do in response to uncertainty about the natural rate of unemployment? They may wish to be less aggressive with policy than they would be if they knew the natural rate more precisely Research (Orphanides-Williams) suggests that the rise of inflation in the 1970s can be blamed on bad estimates of the natural rate

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation Perfectly anticipated inflation No effects if all prices and wages keep up with inflation Even returns on assets may rise exactly with inflation Shoe-leather costs: People spend resources to economize on currency holdings; the estimated cost of 10% inflation is 0.3% of GNP Menu costs: the costs of changing prices (but technology may mitigate this somewhat)

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation Unanticipated inflation ( – e) Realized real returns differ from expected real returns Expected r  i – e Actual r  i –  Actual r differs from expected r by e –  Numerical example: i  6%, e  4%, so expected r  2%; if   6%, actual r  0%; if   2%, actual r  4%

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation Unanticipated inflation ( – e) Similar effect on wages and salaries Result: transfer of wealth From lenders to borrowers when   e From borrowers to lenders when   e So people want to avoid risk of unanticipated inflation They spend resources to forecast inflation

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation Unanticipated inflation ( – e) Loss of valuable signals provided by prices Confusion over changes in aggregate prices vs. changes in relative prices People expend resources to extract correct signals from prices

The Problem of Inflation In touch with data and research: Indexed contracts People could use indexed contracts to avoid the risk of transferring wealth because of unanticipated inflation Most U.S. financial contracts are not indexed, with the exception of some long-term contracts like adjustable-rate mortgages and inflation-indexed bonds issued by the U.S. Treasury beginning in 1997 Many U.S. labor contracts are indexed by COLAs (cost-of-living adjustments) Indexed contracts are more prevalent in countries with high inflation

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation The costs of hyperinflation Hyperinflation is a very high, sustained inflation (for example, 50% or more per month) Hungary in August 1945 had inflation of 19,800% per month Zimbabwe had annual rates of inflation of 1017% in 2006, 10,453% in 2007, and 55.6 billion percent in 2008, before dropping to 6.5% in 2009

The Problem of Inflation The costs of inflation The costs of hyperinflation There are large shoe-leather costs, as people minimize cash balances People spend many resources getting rid of money as fast as possible Tax collections fall, as people pay taxes with money whose value has declined sharply Prices become worthless as signals, so markets become inefficient

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations If rapid money growth causes inflation, why do central banks allow the money supply to grow rapidly? Developing or war-torn countries may not be able to raise taxes or borrow, so they print money to finance spending Industrialized countries may try to use expansionary monetary policy to fight recessions, then not tighten monetary policy enough later

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Disinflation is a reduction in the rate of inflation But disinflations may lead to recessions An unexpected reduction in inflation leads to a rise in unemployment along the Phillips curve The costs of disinflation could be reduced if expected inflation fell at the same time actual inflation fell

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Rapid versus gradual disinflation The classical prescription for disinflation is cold turkey—a rapid and decisive reduction in money growth Proponents argue that the economy will adjust fairly quickly, with low costs of adjustment, if the policy is announced well in advance

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Keynesians disagree with rapid disinflation Price stickiness due to menu costs and wage stickiness due to labor contracts make adjustment slow Cold turkey disinflation would cause a major recession The strategy might fail to alter inflation expectations, because if the costs of the policy are high (because the economy goes into recession), the government will reverse the policy

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations The Keynesian prescription for disinflation is gradualism A gradual approach gives prices and wages time to adjust to the disinflation Such a strategy will be politically sustainable because the costs are low

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations In touch with data and research: The sacrifice ratio When unanticipated tight monetary and fiscal policies are used to reduce inflation, they reduce output and employment for a time, a cost that must be weighed against the benefits of lower inflation

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations In touch with data and research: The sacrifice ratio Economists use the sacrifice ratio as a measure of the costs The sacrifice ratio is the number of percentage points of output lost in reducing inflation by one percentage point Ball’s study: U.S. inflation fell by 8.83 percentage points in the early 1980s, with a loss in output of 16.18 percent of the nation’s potential output Sacrifice ratio = 16.18/8.83 = 1.832

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations In touch with data and research: The sacrifice ratio Ball studied the sacrifice ratios for many different disinflations around the world in the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s The sacrifice ratios varied substantially across countries, from less than 1 to almost 3 One factor affecting the sacrifice ratio is the flexibility of the labor market Countries with slow wage adjustment (for example, because of heavy government regulation of the labor market) have higher sacrifice ratios Ball also found a lower sacrifice ratio from cold turkey disinflation than from gradualism

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations In touch with data and research: The sacrifice ratio Ball’s results should be interpreted with caution, since it isn’t easy to calculate the loss of output and because supply shocks can distort the calculation of the sacrifice ratio

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Wage and price controls Pro: Controls would hold down inflation, thus lowering expected inflation and reducing the costs of disinflation Con: Controls lead to shortages and inefficiency; once controls are lifted, prices will rise again

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Wage and price controls The outcome of wage and price controls may depend on what happens with fiscal and monetary policy If policies remain expansionary, people will expect renewed inflation when the controls are lifted If tight policies are pursued, expected inflation may decline The Nixon wage-price controls from August 1971 to April 1974 led to shortages in many products; the controls reduced inflation when they were in effect, but prices returned to where they would have been soon after the controls were lifted

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations Credibility and reputation Key determinant of the costs of disinflation: how quickly expected inflation adjusts This depends on credibility of disinflation policy; if people believe the government and if the government carries through with its policy, expected inflation should drop rapidly Credibility can be enhanced if the government gets a reputation for carrying out its promises Also, having a strong and independent central bank that is committed to low inflation provides credibility

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations The U.S. disinflation of the 1980s and 1990s Fed chairmen Volcker and Greenspan gradually reduced the inflation rate in the 1980s and 1990s They sought to eliminate inflation as a source of economic instability They wanted people to be confident that inflation would never be very high again

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations The U.S. disinflation of the 1980s and 1990s To judge the Fed’s success, we look at inflation expectations (Fig. 12.10) Inflation expectations were erratic before 1990 Inflation expectations fell gradually from 1990 to 1998 and have been stable since then

Figure 12.10 Expected inflation rate 1971–2012 Sources: Survey of Professional Forecasters, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, available at www.philadelphiafed.org.

Fighting Inflation: The Role of Inflationary Expectations The U.S. disinflation of the 1980s and 1990s Inflation expectations were slow to decline initially (in the late 1970s and early 1980s) because Volcker and the Fed lacked credibility But as inflation continued to fall, the Fed’s credibility increased, and inflation expectations declined gradually To solidify those expectations, the Fed declared a 2% long-run inflation target in 2012