Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 1 Derivatives Performance Attribution Mark Rubinstein Paul Stephens Professor of Applied Investment Analysis.

Slides:



Advertisements
Similar presentations
Fi8000 Option Valuation I Milind Shrikhande.
Advertisements

Chapter 12: Basic option theory
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Dr. Hassan Mounir El-Sady
Valuation of Financial Options Ahmad Alanani Canadian Undergraduate Mathematics Conference 2005.
Fi8000 Option Valuation II Milind Shrikhande. Valuation of Options ☺Arbitrage Restrictions on the Values of Options ☺Quantitative Pricing Models ☺Binomial.
1 Options on Stock Indices, Currencies, and Futures Chapters
By: Piet Nova The Binomial Tree Model.  Important problem in financial markets today  Computation of a particular integral  Methods of valuation 
Options Week 7. What is a derivative asset? Any asset that “derives” its value from another underlying asset is called a derivative asset. The underlying.
Chapter 11 Binomial Trees
1 The Greek Letters Chapter Goals OTC risk management by option market makers may be problematic due to unique features of the options that are.
Spreads  A spread is a combination of a put and a call with different exercise prices.  Suppose that an investor buys simultaneously a 3-month put option.
1 16-Option Valuation. 2 Pricing Options Simple example of no arbitrage pricing: Stock with known price: S 0 =$3 Consider a derivative contract on S:
Financial options1 From financial options to real options 2. Financial options Prof. André Farber Solvay Business School ESCP March 10,2000.
Options and Speculative Markets Introduction to option pricing André Farber Solvay Business School University of Brussels.
Days 8 & 9 discussion: Continuation of binomial model and some applications FIN 441 Prof. Rogers Fall 2011.
Options An Introduction to Derivative Securities.
Pricing an Option The Binomial Tree. Review of last class Use of arbitrage pricing: if two portfolios give the same payoff at some future date, then they.
Drake DRAKE UNIVERSITY Fin 288 Valuing Options Using Binomial Trees.
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2002 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved Finance Chapter Ten Introduction to Binomial Trees.
© 2002 South-Western Publishing 1 Chapter 5 Option Pricing.
5.1 Option pricing: pre-analytics Lecture Notation c : European call option price p :European put option price S 0 :Stock price today X :Strike.
Days 8 & 9 discussion: Continuation of binomial model and some applications FIN 441 Prof. Rogers Spring 2011.
Théorie Financière Financial Options Professeur André Farber.
Class 2 September 16, Derivative Securities latest correction: none yet Lecture.
Corporate Finance Options Prof. André Farber SOLVAY BUSINESS SCHOOL UNIVERSITÉ LIBRE DE BRUXELLES.
Derivatives Introduction to option pricing André Farber Solvay Business School University of Brussels.
Financial Risk Management of Insurance Enterprises 1. Embedded Options 2. Binomial Method.
Class 5 Option Contracts. Options n A call option is a contract that gives the buyer the right, but not the obligation, to buy the underlying security.
Chapter 20 Option Valuation and Strategies. Portfolio 1 – Buy a call option – Write a put option (same x and t as the call option) n What is the potential.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives 6 th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull Chapter 18 Value at Risk.
1 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model MGT 821/ECON 873 The Black-Scholes-Merton Model.
Are Options Mispriced? Greg Orosi. Outline Option Calibration: two methods Consistency Problem Two Empirical Observations Results.
Risk Management and Financial Institutions 2e, Chapter 13, Copyright © John C. Hull 2009 Chapter 13 Market Risk VaR: Model- Building Approach 1.
Put/Call Parity and Binomial Model (McDonald, Chapters 3, 5, 10)
Binomial Option Pricing: I
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black- Scholes Chapter 12.
1 Options Option Basics Option strategies Put-call parity Binomial option pricing Black-Scholes Model.
Professor XXXXX Course Name / # © 2007 Thomson South-Western Chapter 18 Options Basics.
D. M. ChanceAn Introduction to Derivatives and Risk Management, 6th ed.Ch. 4: 1 Chapter 4: Option Pricing Models: The Binomial Model You can think of a.
Investment and portfolio management MGT 531.  Lecture #31.
Chapter 3 Discrete Time and State Models. Discount Functions.
1 Value at Risk Chapter The Question Being Asked in VaR “What loss level is such that we are X % confident it will not be exceeded in N business.
INVESTMENTS | BODIE, KANE, MARCUS Copyright © 2011 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved. McGraw-Hill/Irwin CHAPTER 18 Option Valuation.
Chapter 9 Risk Management of Energy Derivatives Lu (Matthew) Zhao Dept. of Math & Stats, Univ. of Calgary March 7, 2007 “ Lunch at the Lab ” Seminar.
Chapter 3 Arbitrage and Financial Decision Making
1 Derivatives & Risk Management: Part II Models, valuation and risk management.
Options An Introduction to Derivative Securities.
Basic Numerical Procedures Chapter 19 1 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2008.
Overview of Monday, October 15 discussion: Binomial model FIN 441 Prof. Rogers.
Copyright © 2001 by Harcourt, Inc. All rights reserved.1 Chapter 4: Option Pricing Models: The Binomial Model Models are like cars: you can have the best.
Basic Numerical Procedure
Introduction Finance is sometimes called “the study of arbitrage”
© 2010 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be scanned, copied or duplicated, or posted to a publicly accessible Web site, in whole or in part.
Financial Analysis, Planning and Forecasting Theory and Application By Alice C. Lee San Francisco State University John C. Lee J.P. Morgan Chase Cheng.
Option Valuation.
Chapter 12 Binomial Trees
13.1 Valuing Stock Options : The Black-Scholes-Merton Model Chapter 13.
Value at Risk Chapter 20 Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 7th International Edition, Copyright © John C. Hull 2008.
Chapter 16 Option Valuation Copyright © 2010 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
CHAPTER NINETEEN OPTIONS. TYPES OF OPTION CONTRACTS n WHAT IS AN OPTION? Definition: a type of contract between two investors where one grants the other.
Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 5th edition © 2002 by John C. Hull 16.1 Value at Risk Chapter 16.
Option Dynamic Replication References: See course outline 1.
© 2013 Pearson Education, Inc., publishing as Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.10-1 The Binomial Solution How do we find a replicating portfolio consisting.
Introduction to Options. Option – Definition An option is a contract that gives the holder the right but not the obligation to buy or sell a defined asset.
The Pricing of Stock Options Using Black-Scholes Chapter 12
Chapter Twenty One Option Valuation.
Théorie Financière Financial Options
Théorie Financière Financial Options
Presentation transcript:

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 1 Derivatives Performance Attribution Mark Rubinstein Paul Stephens Professor of Applied Investment Analysis University of California at Berkeley

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 2 Decomposition of Option Returns option relative mispricing at purchase (V - C) subsequent underlying asset price changes (C t - V) Two principal sources of profit from options: C t - C -- only the first is due to the option itself, as distinct from what would be possible from an investment in the underlying asset -- important to distinguish between these two sources of profit, since the second is more likely due to luck, or at best much harder to measure +

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 3 Three Formulas n “true formula”: the option valuation formula based on the actual risk-neutral stochastic process followed by the underlying asset n “market’s formula”: the option valuation formula used by market participants to set market prices n benchmark formula: the option valuation formula used in the process of performance attribution to (1) help determine the “true relative value” of the option (2) decompose option mispricing profit into components We distinguish between these formulas and their riskless return and volatility inputs, for which there are also three estimates -- true, market, and benchmark. Essentially, by the “formula” we mean the levels of all the other higher moments of the risk-neutral distribution, where each moment may possibly depend on the input riskless return and volatility.

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 4 Decomposition of Option Returns option relative mispricing at purchase subsequent underlying asset price changes volatility profitformula profit asset profit pure option profitrealized volatility cost

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 5 The net payoff of a call (realized horizon date payoff minus purchase price) can be decomposed into 5 pieces: C t - C n Payoff from an otherwise identical forward contract: S t - S(r/d) t Positive results indicate that the investor may be good at selecting the right underlying asset. (In an efficient market with risk neutrality, asset profit will tend to be zero. Thus, if it tends to be positive or negative, either this must be compensation for risk or indicative of an inefficient asset market -- a distinction we must leave to others.) [1] Asset Profit

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 6 n Difference in payoff of a call and a forward on the asset: [max(0, S t d -(T-t) - Kr -(T-t) ) - max(0, Sd -T - Kr -T )] - [S t - S(r/d) t ] Positive results indicate that the investor was able to achieve additional profits from using options rather than forward contracts on the underlying asset itself, if no consideration is given to the additional cost of the option due to the volatility of the underlying asset. This can also be interpreted as the profit from the option had there been zero-volatility, minus the profit from an otherwise identical forward contract. This component is model-free and under zero- volatility and an efficient market has zero present value. [2] Pure Option Profit

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 7 n Portion of net payoff of option due to realized volatility: [V - max(0, Sd -T - Kr -T )] - [C t - max(0, S t d -(T-t) - Kr -(T-t) )] This will normally be a nonnegative number since the premium over parity of an option tends to shrink to zero as the expiration date approaches. Indeed, at expiration (T = t): C t = max(0, S t - K) = max(0, S t d -(T-t) - Kr -(T-t) ) so that the realized volatility cost becomes just V - max(0, Sd -t - Kr -t ) This can be interpreted as today’s correct payment for the pure option profit. [3] Realized Volatility Cost

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 8 Decomposition of Profit due to Fortuitous Underlying Asset Price Changes In summary, we have (assessed at expiration) : [1] asset profit: S t - S(r/d) t [2] pure option profit: [C t - max(0, Sd -t - Kr -t )] - [S t - S(r/d) t ] [3] realized volatility cost: V - max(0, Sd -t - Kr -t ) [1] + [2] - [3] = C t - V If [1] > 0, good at selecting underlying asset (or compensated for risk). If [2] > 0, gained from use of an option in place of the forward, ignoring the volatility cost. If [2] - [3] > 0, unambiguous gain from use of the option, assuming it were purchased at its “true relative value”.

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 9 n Payoff attributed to difference between the realized (s) and implied volatility at purchase based on benchmark formula: C(s) - C Positive results indicate that the investor was clever enough to buy options in situations where the market underestimated the forthcoming volatility. (Although we can know that an option is mispriced, we will not be able to tell why it is mispriced if the benchmark formula used to calculate C(s) is not a good approximation of the formula used by the market to set the option price C.) [4] Volatility Profit

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 10 n Profit attributed to using a formula superior to the benchmark formula, assuming realized volatility were known in advance: V - C(s) Positive results indicate that the investor was clever enough to buy options for which the benchmark formula, even with foreknowledge of the realized volatility, undervalued the options. (Although we can know that an option is mispriced, we will not be able to tell why it is mispriced if the benchmark formula used to calculate C(s) is not a good approximation of the formula used by the market to set the option price C.) [5] Formula Profit

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 11 V  C + r -t [C t - C t (S...S t )] where: C t (S…S t ) is the amount in an account after elapsed time t of investing C on the purchase date in a self-financing dynamic replicating portfolio, where the implied volatility is used in the benchmark formula to estimate delta. C t - C t (S...S t ) measures the extent by which the benchmark formula with implied volatility fails to replicate the option. n If the benchmark formula and implied volatility were correct, then C t = C t (S…S t ) and V would equal C. n If C t > C t (S…S t ), then the replicating strategy would not start with enough money, so that V would be greater C. Definition of “True Relative Value”

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 12 V = r -t E(C t ) (assuming risk-neutrality) n One way to approximate V is to measure r -t C t. This is unbiased but will converge to V slowly. n Instead use control variate C(S…S t ). V becomes C t, C becomes C t (S…S t ) along same path instead V  r -t C t + [C - r -t C t (S…S t )] è If r -t C t > V, and C t and C t (S…S t ) are highly correlated, C t (S…S t ) > C creating an offsetting correction. Comment: We do better, the closer the benchmark is to the true formula. Comment: Under risk-aversion, r may be a reasonable discount rate. Definition of “True Relative Value” (continued)

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 13 V  r -t C t + [C - r -t C t (S…S t )] simplifying : V*  r -t C t and C*  r -t C t (S…S t ) Var(V) = Var(V*) + Var(C*) - 2 Cov(V*,C*) Suppose that Var(V*) = Var(C*), then Var(V) = 2 [Var V*] [1 -  (V*,C*)] Suppose that  (V*,C*) =.9 (a fair benchmark) then Var(V) =.2[Var(V*)] The Monte-Carlo Logic

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 14 (1) V  r -t C t vs (2) V  r -t C t + [C - r -t C t (S…S t )] In an inefficient asset market, we hope that V will still serve to separate volatility and formula profit from asset profit. Definition (1) does not do this. But definition (2) does. To see this, if S (or r) is too low, then C t will tend to include asset mispricing effects and be high. But C t (S…S t ) will also be high (since it requires buying the asset and borrowing). This will tend to offset leaving V - C unchanged. An Additional Benefit

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 15 Adding-Up Constraint ( at expiration ) C t - C = [1] S t - S(r/d) t (asset profit) + [2] C t - max(0, Sd -t - Kr -t ) - (S t - S(r/d) t ) (pure option profit) - [3] V - max(0, Sd -t - Kr -t ) (realized volatility cost) + [4] C(s) - C (volatility profit) + [5] V - C(s) (formula profit) V  C + r -t [C t - C t (S...S t ] For correctly priced and benchmarked options: C = E[V] (= r -t E(C t )) E[C(s) - C] = E[V - C(s)] = 0

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 16 Simulation Tests nCommon features of all simulations: l European call, S = K = 100, t = 60/360, d = 1.03 l True annualized volatility = 20%, true annualized riskless rate = 7% l Performance evaluated on expiration date l Benchmark formula: standard binomial formula l 10,000 Monte-Carlo paths nEfficient (risk-neutral) market simulations: ¶ “continuous” correct benchmark trading · “discrete” correct benchmark trading ¸ wrong benchmark formula nInefficient (risk-neutral) option market simulations: ¹ market makes wrong volatility forecast but uses “true formula” º market uses wrong formula but makes true volatility forecast » market uses wrong formula and wrong volatility forecast nInefficient (risk-averse) asset and option market simulation: ¼ market uses wrong asset price, wrong volatility and wrong formula

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 17 Generalized Binomial Simulation n Step 0: buy  shares of the underlying asset and invest C - S  dollars in cash, where (u,d) is not known in advance n Step 1u (up move): portfolio is then worth uS  + (C - S  )r  C u ; next buy  u shares and invest (C u - uS  u ) dollars in cash, where (u u, d u ) is not known in advance, or n Step 1d (down move): portfolio is then worth dS  + (C - S  )r  C d ; next buy  d shares and invest (C d - dS  d ) dollars in cash, where (u d, d d ) is not known in advance n Step 2: depending on the sequence of up and down moves, the replicating portfolio will be worth either: up-up:uu u S  u + (C u - uS  u )r  C uu (  max[0, uu u S - K]) up-down:ud u S  u + (C u - uS  u )r  C ud (  max[0, ud u S - K]) down-up:du d S  d + (C d - dS  d )r  C du (  max[0, du d S - K]) down-down:dd d S  d + (C d - dS  d )r  C dd (  max[0, dd d S - K])

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 18 ntrue, market and benchmark formula: standard binomial ntrue and market volatility/riskless rate = 20%/7% nbenchmark formula uses “continuous” trading [1] asset profit-0.05 (8.21) [2] pure option profit 2.96 (4.37) [3] realized volatility cost 2.91 (0.00) [4] volatility profit 0.00 (0.00) [5] formula profit 0.00 (0.00) option value/price = $3.54 Simulation Test 1 ( efficient risk-neutral market with “continuous” and correct benchmark trading )

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 19 ntrue, market and benchmark formula: standard binomial ntrue and market volatility/riskless rate = 20%/7% nbenchmark formula uses “discrete” trading (once a day) move every 1/2 day move every 1/8 day [1] asset profit-0.10 (8.15) 0.08 (8.28) [2] pure option profit 2.98 (4.39) 2.95 (4.38) [3] realized volatility cost 2.92 (0.25) 2.93 (0.33) [4] volatility profit (0.21) (0.28) [5] formula profit (0.15) (0.17) option value/price = $3.54 Simulation Test 2 ( efficient risk-neutral market with “discrete” but correct benchmark trading )

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 20 Alternative Risk-Neutral Distributions

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 21 ntrue and market formula: implied binomial tree l skewness = and kurtosis = 4.86 ntrue and market volatility/riskless rate = 20%/7% nbenchmark formula: standard binomial (“continuous” trading) [1] asset profit-0.13 (8.07) [2] pure option profit 2.67 (4.66) [3] realized volatility cost 2.52 (0.26) [4] + [5] mispricing profit (0.26) value (V) 3.27 (0.26) payoff (r -t C t ) 3.27 (5.01) option value/price = $3.25 Simulation Test 3 ( efficient risk-neutral market with wrong benchmark formula )

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 22 ntrue, market and benchmark formula: standard binomial ntrue and market riskless rate = 7% ntrue volatility = 20% market volatility = 15%/25% market vol = 15% market vol = 25% [1] asset profit-0.04 (8.12) (8.30) [2] pure option profit 2.92 (4.36) 3.03 (4.37) [3] realized volatility cost 2.92 (0.32) 2.92 (0.30) [4] volatility profit (0.00) (0.00) [5] formula profit (0.32) (0.30) value (V) 3.55 (0.33) 3.55 (0.29) payoff (r -t C t ) 3.48 (5.08) 3.53 (5.19) option value = $3.54 and option price = $2.74/$4.34 Simulation Test 4 ( inefficient risk-neutral option market because market uses wrong volatility )

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 23 Simulation Test 5 ( inefficient risk-neutral option market because market uses wrong formula ) ntrue formula: implied binomial tree l skewness = and kurtosis = 4.86 ntrue and market volatility/riskless rate = 20%/7% nbenchmark and market formula: standard binomial [1] asset profit-0.24 (7.99) [2] pure option profit 2.63 (4.64) [3] realized volatility cost 2.63 (0.33) [4] volatility profit (0.53) [5] formula profit (0.27) value (V) 3.26 (0.33) payoff (r -t C t ) 3.25 (4.96) option value = $3.25 and option price = $3.54

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 24 Simulation Test 6 ( inefficient risk-neutral option market because market uses wrong volatility/formula ) ntrue formula: implied binomial tree l skewness = and kurtosis = 4.86 ntrue and market riskless rate = 7% ntrue volatility = 20% market volatility = 15%/25% nbenchmark and market formula: standard binomial market vol = 15% market vol = 25% [1] asset profit-0.13 (8.03) (8.19) [2] pure option profit 2.64 (4.75) 2.69 (4.75) [3] realized volatility cost 2.62 (0.25) 2.63 (0.54) [4] volatility profit (0.54) (0.53) [5] formula profit (0.53) (0.36) value (V) 3.25 (0.25) 3.25 (0.54) payoff (r -t C t ) 3.25 (4.90) 3.34 (5.10) option value = $3.25 and option price = $2.74/$4.34

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 25 Simulation Test 7 ( inefficient risk-averse market because market uses wrong asset price, volatility, formula ) ntrue formula: implied binomial tree l skewness = and kurtosis = 4.86 ntrue volatility = 20% market volatility = 25% ntrue riskless rate = 7% market riskless rate = 5%/9% nbenchmark and market formula: standard binomial riskless rate = 5% riskless rate = 9% [1] asset profit 0.38 (8.03) (8.04) [2] pure option profit 2.63 (4.64) 2.69 (4.77) [3] realized volatility cost 2.77 (0.50) 2.49 (0.58) [4] volatility profit (0.54) (0.54) [5] formula profit (0.24) (0.28) value (V) 3.09 (0.50) 3.42 (0.58) payoff (r -t C t ) 3.29 (4.99) 3.22 (4.89) option value = $3.25 ($3.07/$3.44) and option price = $4.19/$4.50

Derivatives Performance Attribution C=f(S,t) u d 26 Summary nBasic attribution: profit due to underlying asset price changes vs profit due to option mispricing l robust to discrete trading and wrong benchmark formula l low standard error for option mispricing by using Monte-Carlo analysis with dynamic replicating portfolio as control variate nDecompose option mispricing into volatility and formula profits l requires benchmark formula similar to market’s formula l low standard errors nUnbiased estimate of asset profit in a risk-averse or inefficient asset pricing market l can not distinguish between risk aversion and market inefficiency l high standard error